Economics of Energy Efficiency in a CO 2 Constrained World



Similar documents
Renewable Choice Energy

D DAVID PUBLISHING. Voluntary Carbon Market in Turkey. 1. Introduction. Fehiman Ciner 1 and Aydemir Akyurek 2

Levelized Cost of New Electricity Generating Technologies

Why are developing countries exempt from the emissions targets?

How to Earn the LEED Green Power Credit

FACTS ABOUT CLIMATE CHANGE

Economic Development and the Risk of Global Climate Change

Annex 5A Trends in international carbon dioxide emissions

COST OF GREENHOUSE GAS MITIGATION [21jun, 10jul 1pm]

The Energy Savings and Emission Reduction Benefits Delivered by the State of Maryland Energy Performance Contracts

Submission by Norway to the ADP

Shipping, World Trade and the Reduction of

Google s Green PPAs: What, How, and Why

NEW ZEALAND S RESPONSE TO CLIMATE CHANGE

Six greenhouse gases covered by the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and its Kyoto Protocol are:

Fixing the Leaks: What Would it Cost to Clean Up Natural Gas Leaks?

Portfolio Manager and Green Power Tracking

The Kyoto Protocol Accomplishments and Failures. By Michael Chavez

Scope 1 describes direct greenhouse gas emissions from sources that are owned by or under the direct control of the reporting entity;

Greenhouse Gas Offsets and Renewable Energy Certificates: Distinct Commodities in an Evolving Market The Climate Trust

Shipping, World Trade and the Reduction of

BBC Learning English Talk about English Insight plus Part 3 Global Warming

Shipping, World Trade and the Reduction of

Questions and Answers Emissions Reductions Needed to Stabilize Climate

A Proposal for Solar Energy Power in the city of Boulder, Colorado

Corporate Carbon Neutral Plan

Communicating Your Commitment: Your Guide to Clean Energy Messaging

GLOBAL WARMING : THE SIGNIFICANCE OF METHANE

Kyoto Protocol MEMO/04/43. What is the Kyoto Protocol? Bruxelles, 4 March 2004

Energy Projections Price and Policy Considerations. Dr. Randy Hudson Oak Ridge National Laboratory

CRM Sample Questions

EU energy and climate policies beyond 2020

Tackling Climate Change in the U.S.

Calculating Greenhouse Gas Emissions

Greenhouse Gas Emissions: Trouble Brewing or a Golden Opportunity? Texas Association of Clean Water Agencies April 3, 2009

Implications of Abundant Natural Gas

MAGAZINE OF THE GRAPHIC ARTS TECHNICAL FOUNDATION VOL. 20 NO. 3 JUNE 2008 $15.00

Climate Change Mini-Simulation: Background Guide

A Summary of the Kyoto Protocol and the Marrakesh Accords By James G. Derouin Fredric D. Bellamy David R. Nelson Mark E. Freeze 1

Newsletter. August Featured. Welcome to our newsletter for August

Carbon Credits: An Opportunity for Forest Landowners. Hughes Simpson Texas Forest Service

Energy [R]evolution vs. IEA World Energy Outlook scenario

The Science and Ethics of Global warming. Global warming has become one of the central political and scientific issues of

GHG Emission Reductions Quantification Report

ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN POWER PLANTS

Comprehensive emissions per capita for industrialised countries

ANALYSIS OF THE ADMINISTRATION S PROPOSED TAX INCENTIVES FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY AND THE ENVIRONMENT

MT - Economic Development Track 2 Southeast Solar Summit Oak Ridge National Laboratory October 2007

Climate Change: A Local Focus on a Global Issue Newfoundland and Labrador Curriculum Links


Introduction to Non- Conventional Energy Systems

climate change is happening. This April produced the record for the first month in human history

The Role of Offsets in a Greenhouse Gas Emissions Cap-and-Trade Program: Potential Benefits and Concerns

Carbon Offsets and Renewable Energy Certificates (RECs)

Module 1: Introduction to Industrial Energy Management

The solution to the climate crisis: a just transition to 100% renewable energy for all by 2050

John Byrme Director, Center for Energy and Environmental Policy University of Delaware

GREENHOUSE EFFECT & GLOBAL WARMING - The internet as the primary source of information

climate science A SHORT GUIDE TO This is a short summary of a detailed discussion of climate change science.

showing you all the benefits of solar thermal and helping you pick a system that is right for your business.

Fossil fuels and climate change: alternative projections to 2050

Ontario Hydro. September 28, 1995

On June 28, 2011, the Municipal Services Committee recommended that the City Council adopt the recommendations stated in the subject agenda report.

REPUBLIC OF TURKEY INTENDED NATIONALLY DETERMINED CONTRIBUTION

Finding Ways to Postpone Climate Tipping Points Using Updated Metrics

Systems Thinking and Modeling Climate Change Amy Pallant, Hee-Sun Lee, and Sarah Pryputniewicz

Understanding the Changes to Global Warming Potential (GWP) Values

ENERGY EFFICIENCY EXPERTS. MCW's. Environmental Record. Green Design REDUCING OUR CLIENTS' ENVIRONMENTAL FOOTPRINT

Rainwater Harvesting

Nuclear power is part of the solution for fighting climate change

From Carbon Subsidy to Carbon Tax: India s Green Actions 1

Common Boiler Excess Air Trends and Strategies to Optimize Efficiency

The European Chlor-Alkali industry: an electricity intensive sector exposed to carbon leakage

Tax Credit Incentives for Residential Solar Photovoltaic in Hawai i

CDP7 and OneReport Comparison

Latin America and COP20

How to implement renewable energy and energy efficiency options

Egypt & Climate Change

Are Humans Responsible for Global Warming?

Shipping, World Trade and the Reduction of CO 2 Emissions

Going Green: Installing Solar Panels around the Campus of Widener University

Pre-lab Homework Lab 10: Global Warming Prior to lab, answer the following questions to help you become prepared for the lab.

Keeping below 2 degrees

e7/ppa Workshop on Renewable Energy - TEST ANSWER -

Calculating Carbon Intensity: Implications of Projection Horizon and Future Land Use Prepared for the Renewable Fuels Association

JACKSON HOLE ENERGY EFFICIENCY ACTION PLAN FALL Page 1 of 9

Report to the Legislative Assembly

THE CURRENT BALANCE. The Role of Cost, Reliability, and Environmental Impact in the Massachusetts Electricity Market

New Jersey Farm Bureau

Derisking Renewable Energy Investment

Methane emissions trading

EXAMPLES OF SUCCESSFUL POLICY TOOLS FOR EMISSION REDUCTION

To approve Intended Nationally Determined Contributions of the Republic of Armenia under the UNFCCC according to the following Annex.

CLEAN TECHNOLOGY FUND CRITERIA FOR FINANCING LOW-CARBON OPPORTUNITIES IN COAL AND GAS POWER INVESTMENTS

degrees Fahrenheit. Scientists believe it's human activity that's driving the temperatures up, a process

Natural Gas & Energy Efficiency: Keys to Reducing GHG Emissions

The Solubility of Calcium Carbonate

Tokyo Steel s Views to Global Warming revised on June 25, 2010 with the latest data

CRS Report Summaries WORKING DRAFT

Transcription:

Economics of Energy Efficiency in a CO 2 Constrained World Daniel Trombley and Kelly Kissock, University of Dayton John Seryak, Go Sustainable Energy ABSTRACT Greenhouse gas emission trading programs have been initiated in the European Union, Canada and the United States in an effort to harness market forces to efficiently reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Three major methods for reducing or offsetting greenhouse gas emissions are purchasing greenhouse gas emission reduction credits, purchasing renewable energy certificates, and improving energy efficiency on site. This paper investigates the economics of energy efficiency in comparison to purchasing renewable energy certificates or CO 2 emission reduction credits. The analysis considers three legislative scenarios: the current case with no CO 2 taxes or mandatory CO 2 emission reductions, a tax on CO 2 emissions, and mandatory CO 2 emission reductions with emission credit trading. A relation to quantify the cost of energy efficiency in terms of dollars per tonne of avoided CO 2 is proposed. Results show that at current prices, energy efficiency will remain more cost effective than purchasing renewable energy certificates or CO 2 emission reduction credits as long as the simple payback is less than the life of the energy efficiency project. Introduction Over the last 400,000 years, atmospheric temperature and greenhouse gas concentrations have been highly correlated, and Figure 1 shows that today s greenhouse gas concentrations are the highest ever recorded. This increase in atmospheric concentration of greenhouse gasses is a result of the exponential growth of fossil fuel use since the industrial revolution (Hansen 2005a; IPCC 2001). Because the mechanism of global warming is increasingly well understood, scientists predict that the earth s temperature will continue to rise in the 21 st century (Hansen, et al. 1997). 1-35

Figure 1. Long Term and Recent Global Temperature and Greenhouse Gas Concentrations Source: Hansen 2005b Expected impacts of global warming include mass extinctions, sea level rise, melting of the polar ice caps, and increasingly severe weather and droughts (IPCC 2001). In response to these threats, almost 90% of the countries in the world have ratified the Kyoto Protocol in an attempt to limit greenhouse gas emissions (UN 2007). The largest greenhouse gas emitter that did not ratify Kyoto is the United States. However, growing awareness of the threat of climate change is likely to spur the United States to take action to reduce CO 2 emissions. Possible actions include a CO 2 emission tax or mandatory CO 2 emission reductions with a carbon trading system. The European Union has already enacted a carbon trading system called the Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS 2007). In the EU ETS, carbon reductions are mandatory. Emission reduction credits were once as high as $40 per tonne, but have fallen because of excessive allowances granted for calculating baseline emissions. Currently the only emission reduction and carbon trading system operable in the United States is the Chicago Climate Exchange (CCX 2007). Membership in the CCX is voluntary; however, all commitments are legally binding. Current members include Ford, Dow, Dupont, 1-36

and IBM. Member companies commit to reducing greenhouse gas emissions from a year 2000 baseline. Emission reduction targets start at 1% in 2003 and grow to 6% by 2010. Excess reductions beyond the specified targets can be sold as credits. Shortages in emission reductions can be compensated for by buying emission reduction credits from other companies. Six greenhouse gasses are traded: CO 2, Methane, Nitrous Oxide, Hydro- Fluorocarbons, Per-Fluorocarbons, and Sulfur Hexafluoride. To provide a common metric, the greenhouse warming potential of each gas is converted to the warming potential of CO 2, and the price is set in terms of dollars per tonne (1 tonne = 2,205 lbs). This paper investigates how the economics of energy efficiency might change if a carbon trading system or CO 2 emission tax were instituted. It begins by quantifying the CO 2 intensity of electricity and natural gas using average prices for the industrial sector. Next, the representative economics of three major options for reducing CO 2 emissions are discussed. The options are emission reduction credits, tradable renewable certificates, and energy efficiency. The economics of energy efficiency in comparison to emission reduction credits and tradable renewable certificates are then explored for three possible legislative scenarios: the current case with no CO 2 taxes or mandatory CO 2 emission reductions, a tax on CO 2 emissions, and mandatory CO 2 emission reductions with emission credit trading. CO 2 Intensity of Electricity and Natural Gas In 2005, the average cost of electricity for the industrial sector was $0.057 /kwh and the average cost of natural gas for the industrial sector was $8.48 /mmbtu (EIA 2005). Average 2005 CO 2 emissions from the 100 largest power producers in the United States were 1.34 lb- CO 2 /kwh, and average CO 2 emissions from natural gas were 117 lb-co 2 /kwh (NRDC 2006). Using these values, electricity has a carbon dioxide content of 0.011 tonnes-co 2 /$ and natural gas has a carbon dioxide content of 0.0063 tonnes-co 2 /$ (2,205 lb/tonne). Thus, on a unit cost basis, electricity results in almost twice the CO 2 emissions as natural gas. Options for Reducing CO 2 Emissions The three major options for reducing or offsetting greenhouse gas emissions are purchasing greenhouse gas emission reduction credits, purchasing renewable energy certificates, and improving energy efficiency on site. Each of these options, and the approximate cost of each option, is discussed below. CO 2 Emission Reduction Credits In a carbon trading system, companies would be obligated to reduce their CO 2 emissions. Companies that reduce emissions below the required level could sell the difference as CO 2 emission reduction credits. These credits could be purchased by another company to meet its emission requirements. Thus, the purchase of emission reduction credits subsidizes emission reduction efforts in other companies, and is a viable mechanism for reducing CO 2 emissions. Historically, the cost of CO 2 emission reduction credits has ranged from about $4 /tonne, which is the current price on the Chicago Climate Exchange (CCX 2007), to about $40 /tonne, which was the peak price for emission reduction credits on the European Union Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS 2007). 1-37

Tradable Renewable Certificates Another option that reduces global CO 2 emissions is to invest in electrical power production from renewable energy technologies such as solar photovoltaic collectors or wind turbines. Currently, both solar and wind power are relatively expensive to install on site. However, it is now possible to purchase Tradable Renewable Certificates (TRC) that subsidize wind and solar power plants (Green-e 2006). The net effect is to displace traditional power from fossil fuels with power from non-co 2 emitting renewable sources. Thus, through the purchase of TRCs, companies could completely offset all CO 2 emissions from electricity. The current price for TRCs is about $0.015 /kwh for small purchases, and less for large purchases (Green-e 2006). This cost is paid as a premium, in addition to the cost of electricity. Thus, a $0.015 /kwh TRC would raise the average industrial cost of electricity by 26%. At this price and a carbon content of 1.34 lb-co 2 /kwh, the value of TRCs in dollars per tonne of avoided CO 2 emissions is $25 /tonne. Energy Efficiency Finally, perhaps the most direct method for companies to reduce CO 2 emissions is to invest in energy efficiency projects within the company. The cost of energy efficiency varies by project, but many industrial energy savings opportunities pay back within a just a few years. For example, U.S. Department of Energy funded Industrial Assessment Centers conduct one day energy assessments for mid-sized industries across the United States. Over 25 years, IACs have performed over 13,000 assessments and made over 99,000 individual energy saving recommendations (IAC 2007). On average, $110,000 per year of savings opportunities are identified at each plant with an average simple payback of 1.3 years. This represents an average of 19% of each plant s total energy use. About 50% of the 99,000 recommendations have been implemented. A simple payback of 1.3 years represents an annual rate of return of about 77%, which dwarfs the rate of return of almost any alternative investment. Thus, energy efficiency is one of the most cost-effective investments that most companies can make, and a highly cost effective way to reduce CO 2 emissions. In addition to simple payback, another important factor for energy efficiency projects is the measure life. Measure life is defined as the median number of years that a measure is installed and operational (ERS 2005). Figure 2 shows measure lives for common energy efficiency retrofit projects, as determined by multiple sources. The average measure life of energy efficiency projects reported in Figure 6 is about 13 years. 1-38

Figure 2. Measure Life for Common Energy Efficiency Measures Source: ERS 2005 Summary The three options discussed above are considered for three scenarios of Carbon legislation: no CO 2 emission taxes or mandatory reductions, a CO 2 emission tax, and mandatory reductions with a carbon credit market. 1-39

Scenario I: No CO 2 Emission Taxes or Mandatory Reductions Currently, in order to maximize return on investment, companies consider energy efficiency projects only if the ROI for energy efficiency project is higher than for alternative investments. This view will not change if there remains no CO 2 emission tax or mandatory reductions. While there are other significant factors that impact the economics of energy efficiency, such as new methods, productivity improvements (Worrell et al. 2003), and learning curves (Laitner and Sanstad 2004), the method of calculating the economics of energy efficiency will remain the same. The energy, waste, and productivity savings generated by the energy efficiency project will be measured against the cost, and the project will be executed if the ROI is favorable. Although current market forces do generate energy efficiency projects, many economists believe that most companies under-invest in energy efficiency. This tends to slow overall CO 2 emission reductions (CERA 2007). While energy efficiency projects clearly provide direct economic incentives, purchasing TRCs results in less direct incentives. For example, purchasing TRCs may help a company market itself as green, which could help increase sales. Moreover, in the long term, purchasing TRCs reduces global warming and other pollution problems, which sustains an environment for long term business success. Scenario II: CO 2 Emission Tax Any fossil fuel energy used leads directly to CO 2 emissions. Therefore, if a CO 2 emission tax were enacted, the effect would be to increase the price of energy. However, the method of calculating the economics of energy efficiency would remain the same: an energy efficiency project would be considered only if the ROI was higher than the ROI of an alternative investment. The economic incentives for purchasing TRCs discussed above would still be in effect, but a CO 2 tax could drastically change the overall economics of purchasing TRCs, depending on the price of the tax. In order to estimate the impact of a CO 2 emission tax on energy prices, consider costs similar to that of CO 2 emission reduction credits, which range from $4 /tonne to $40 /tonne. At $4 /tonne, a CO 2 tax adds $0.0024 /kwh to the average cost of electricity, which is an increase of 4.7%. At $40 per tonne, a CO 2 tax adds $0.024 /kwh, which is an increase of 47%. At $4 per tonne, a CO 2 tax adds $0.21 /mmbtu to the average cost of natural gas, which is an increase of 2.5%. At $40 per tonne, a CO 2 tax adds $2.1 /mmbtu to the average cost of natural gas, which is an increase of 25%. The increased cost of energy would result in increased savings from energy efficiency projects, and hence shorter payback periods. Thus, a CO 2 emission tax would improve the economics of energy efficiency projects. These estimates suggest that CO 2 emission taxes could produce a wide range of relative impacts on energy costs. While a 5% increase in utility bills may be manageable, a 50% increase would have a more significant impact on most company s finances. However, it should also be noted that the average fraction of energy costs to total sales for U.S. industry is 2% (EIA 2002). Thus, even a 50% increase of 2% of total revenue only increases energy costs to 3% of total sales. Similarly, a CO2 tax could affect the incentive to purchase TRCs. As discussed earlier, TRCs cost about $25 /tonne of avoided CO 2. For a CO 2 tax of $4 /tonne, the economic incentives for purchasing TRCs would be the same as discussed previously, but the cost of the 1-40

TRCs would be subsidized by the $4 /tonne tax, so the cost of TRCs would only be $21 /tonne. For a CO 2 tax of $40 /tonne, the economics change completely. Without changing its electricity consumption, a company could avoid a $40 /tonne charge by paying only $25 /tonne, for a net gain of $15 /tonne. Scenario III: Mandatory CO 2 Reductions and Carbon Trading In this scenario, it is useful to quantify the cost per tonne of CO 2 emission reductions from the three options listed above. As stated previously, the cost of CO 2 emission reduction credits ranges from $4 to $40 per tonne, and the cost per tonne of TRCs at $0.015 /kwh is $25 per tonne. Cost per Tonne of Energy Efficiency When carbon is sold on the open market, the price will be set according to levels of supply and demand. As shown above, the most viable alternative to buying CO 2 reduction credits is energy efficiency. No company would purchase CO 2 credits if they could achieve the same CO 2 reductions for less money with energy efficiency projects. Therefore, as markets such as the Chicago Climate Exchange develop, the maximum market price that a company would pay for CO 2 reduction credits will be largely dictated by the cost of energy efficiency for that company, as shown in the equation below: Cost of CO 2 Emission Reduction Credits Cost of Energy Efficiency Project MMP ($/tonne) x CO2 (tonne/year) x ML (years) = IC ($) CS ($/year) x ML (years) (1) Where MMP is the maximum market price that a company would pay for CO 2 emission reduction credits instead of the energy efficiency project being considered, CO2 is the amount of carbon dioxide saved by the energy efficiency project, ML is the measure life of the project, which describes how long the savings from the project will last, IC is the implementation cost of the energy efficiency project, and CS is the annual cost savings of the energy efficiency project. This can be simplified further if these individual terms are further defined in terms of CC (the carbon content of the fuel in tonnes/kwh or tonnes/mmbtu), ES (the energy savings in kwh/year or mmbtu/year), SP (the simple payback of the project in years), and EC (the energy cost in either $/kwh or $/mmbtu): CO2 (tonne/year) = CC (tonnes/energy) x ES (energy/year) (2) IC ($) = SP (years) x ES (energy/year) x EC ($/energy) (3) CS ($/year) = ES (energy/year) x EC ($/energy) (4) Combining Equations 1-4 and solving for the maximum market price yields, MMP ($/tonne) = EC / CC x [SP/ML 1] (5) Inspection of Equation 5 yields several useful observations about the cost of energy efficiency and the market price of CO 2 emission reduction. First, this equation shows that the economics of energy efficiency projects can be converted from standard energy efficiency 1-41

economic terms, such as initial cost in dollars and cost savings per year, into terms of CO 2 prices ($/tonne). This makes it easy to compare energy efficiency with CO 2 emission reduction credits or TRCs when a certain reduction in CO 2 emissions must be met. For example, if the actual market price for CO 2 emission reduction credits is greater than the MMP for a certain energy efficiency project, then it is more economic to proceed with the energy efficiency project. This equation also quantifies the relationship of simple payback to measure life. If the simple payback is less than the measure life, then the maximum market price is negative. This means a company would only favor CO 2 emission reduction credits over the energy efficiency project if someone paid them to take the credits. If an energy efficiency project pays back sooner than the measure life, it is always better to pursue the energy efficiency project. This provides a net monetary gain for the company. If the simple payback is greater than the measure life, then the maximum market price for CO 2 will be positive and determined by the equation above. The energy efficiency project will not recover the initial cost, but it still may be more economical than purchasing CO 2 emission reduction credits or TRCs. By reworking the above equation, it can calculate the simple payback or simple payback to measure life ratio of an energy efficiency project that breaks even with a known market price for CO 2 emission reduction credits or TRCs. Using the average values for energy price and CO 2 content, the SP/ML ratio is shown in Table 1 for different energy sources and alternative CO 2 reduction prices. Table 1. Ratio of Simple Payback to Measure Life to Produce Equivalent Costs for CO 2 Emission Credits and TRCs SP/ML Alternative Market, Low TRC Market, High Price: $4/tonne $25/tonne $40/tonne Electricity 1.04 1.27 1.43 Natural Gas 1.03 1.16 1.25 When the alternative CO 2 reduction price is low, the benefits of energy efficiency drop off quickly as the simple payback becomes greater than the measure life. However, when the alternative CO 2 reduction price approaches the market s historic high, energy efficiency will still be comparable to the alternatives even when the simple payback is 40% and 25% higher than the measure life for electricity and natural gas, respectively. Ideally, companies that purchase CO 2 emission reduction credits do not have energy efficiency opportunities with simple paybacks less than the measure life. However, the data suggests that not many companies should soon find themselves in this position, since the average simple payback for the first 19% of total a company s energy use is about 1.3 years and measure lives are typically about 13 years. This suggests that there should not be many companies initially seeking to purchase CO 2 emission credits and the market price of the credits should fall as a result. However, as CO 2 emission reduction targets increase, it will be harder to find energy efficiency projects with a maximum market price that is negative, or at least less than the actual CO 2 emission market price or the price of TRCs. At that point, emission credits, TRCs, and other CO 2 emission reduction strategies will be necessary to achieve necessary CO 2 emission reductions. 1-42

Decision Making If mandatory CO 2 emission reductions are put in place in the U.S. and a carbon trading system is implemented, there are three primary ways to meet the reduction requirements: purchasing CO 2 emission reduction credits on the open market, purchasing Tradable Renewable Certificates to ensure electricity comes from non-co 2 emitting renewable fuel, or investing in energy efficiency projects. Even though these three methods vary greatly in how they accomplish the task, they can be easily compared in terms of dollars per tonne of CO 2 reduced. A company need only use the methodology developed in this paper to determine the current cost of each option. CO 2 emission reduction credits on open markets range from $4 /tonne to $40 /tonne. Purchasing TRCs at $0.015 /kwh is equivalent to paying $25 /tonne to reduce CO 2 emissions. Finally, the company must assess energy saving opportunities and use the formula derived in this paper to calculate the price in $/tonne that a given energy efficiency project would cost. Then it is as simple as choosing the least expensive option. Conclusion Growing awareness of the threat of climate change is likely to spur the United States to take action to reduce CO 2 emissions. Possible actions include a CO 2 emission tax or mandatory CO2 emission reductions with a carbon trading system. Knowing how to effectively deal with these actions is vital for U.S. industries if they are to remain competitive in a global economy. This analysis quantifies the various options for reducing CO 2 emissions in the common metric of $ per tonne of CO 2 emissions avoided. It shows that the cost effectiveness of energy efficiency at reducing CO 2 emissions is a function of the project simple payback to measure life. It also shows that energy efficiency projects are currently the most economical way to reduce CO 2 emissions under any CO 2 management scenario, and are likely to remain so as long as the simple payback is less than the measure life. Thus, this analysis provides a baseline from which to understand market prices for tradable renewable certificates and greenhouse gas emission reduction credits, and provides guidance to industries who may be considering options for reducing greenhouse gas emissions. References [CERA] Cambridge Energy Research Associates. 2007. Meeting the Power Conservation Investment Challenge. http://www.cera.com/aspx/cda/public1/news/ [CCX] Chicago Climate Exchange. 2007. Welcome to the Chicago Climate Exchange. http://www.chicagoclimatex.com/ [EIA] Energy Information Agency. 2002. Manufacturing Energy Consumption Survey. U.S. Department of Energy. http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/mecs/contents.html [EIA] Energy Information Agency. 2005. Annual Energy Review 2005. U.S. Department of Energy. http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/aer/overview.html 1-43

[ERS] Energy and Resource Solutions. 2005. Measure Life Study: Prepared for The Massachusetts Joint Utilities. www.ers-inc.com [EU ETS] European Union Emission Trading Scheme. 2007. Emission Trading Scheme. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission.htm Green-e. 2006. Renewable Energy for Your Business. www.green-e.org/ Hansen, J., et al. 1997. Forcings and chaos in interannual to decadal climate change. J. Geophys. Res. 102 (D22): 25,679 25,720. Hansen, J. 2005a. Is There Still Time to Avoid Dangerous Anthropogenic Interference with Global Climate? American Geophysical Union. http://www.columbia.edu/~jeh1/keeling_talk_and_slides.pdf Hansen, J. 2005b. A slippery slope: How much global warming constitutes dangerous anthropogenic interference? Climatic Change. 68 (3): 269-279. [IAC] Industrial Assessment Center. 2006. IAC Database. http://iac.rutgers.edu/database/index.php [IPCC] Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. 2001. Summary for Policymakers. http://www.ipcc.ch/pub/un/syreng/spm.pdf Laitner, John A. "Skip" and Alan H. Sanstad. 2004. Learning by Doing on Both the Demand and the Supply Sides: Implications for Electric Utility Investments in a Heuristic Model. International Journal of Energy Technology and Policy, 2004, 2(1/2): 142-52. [NRDC] National Resources Defense Council. 2006. Benchmarking Air Emissions of the 100 Largest Electrical Power Producers in the United States. http://www.nrdc.org/air/pollution/benchmarking/default.asp#toc [UN] United Nations. 2007. Kyoto Protocol Status of Ratification. http://unfccc.int. http://unfccc.int/files/kyoto_protocol/background/status_of_ratification/application/pdf/k p_rat_131206.pdf Worrell, Ernst, John A. Laitner, Michael Ruth, and Hodayah Finman. 2003. Productivity Benefits of Industrial Energy Efficiency Measures. Energy, 2003 (28): 1081-98. Acknowledgement This work was graciously supported by the U.S. Department of Energy Industrial Technologies Program through its support of the Industrial Assessment Center program. 1-44