THE REVENUE EFFECT OF CHANGING ALCOHOL DUTIES



Similar documents
THE PETROL TAX DEBATE

Alcohol Consumption in Ireland A Report for the Health Service Executive

relating to household s disposable income. A Gini Coefficient of zero indicates

Contribution of the Scotch Whisky Industry to the Scottish Economy

10. European Union. (a) Past trends

Value of production of agricultural products and foodstuffs, wines, aromatised wines and spirits protected by a geographical indication (GI)

General Excise Duties (Tobacco and Alcohol Products)

How To Understand Factoring

What if BAU would come true?

VALUE ADDED TAX ANALYSIS AND SOME CURRENT ISSUES

// BRIEF STATISTICS 2014

There is help on form VAT1 itself but these notes provide extra help with some of the questions.

Greece Country Profile

NERI Quarterly Economic Facts Summer Distribution of Income and Wealth

Planned Healthcare in Europe for Lothian residents

Beer statistics edition. The Brewers of Europe

Information Sheet: VAT on private pleasure craft

Excise Taxation Customer Bulletin 6. Occasional Importation of Products Subject to Excise Duty. Temporary registered consignee

Norwegian-Swedish cross-border trade in alcoholic beverages

The wine market: evolution and trends

International Trade. Business Advice Open Day

Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax ratio fell to 39.3% of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

What Proportion of National Wealth Is Spent on Education?

NORDIC ALCOHOL STATISTICS

Car CO2 taxation and it s impact on the British car fleet

Hong Kong s Health Spending 1989 to 2033

IS ENERGY IN ESTONIA CHEAP OR EXPENSIVE?

FEDERATION EUROPEENNE DES MEDECINS SALARIES EUROPEAN FEDERATION OF SALARIED DOCTORS

What Is the Total Public Spending on Education?

Annex 2C International comparisons of gas and electricity prices

Energy prices in the EU Household electricity prices in the EU rose by 2.9% in 2014 Gas prices up by 2.0% in the EU

EUROPE 2020 TARGETS: RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT

HOW IMPORTANT IS BUSINESS R&D FOR ECONOMIC GROWTH AND SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT SUBSIDISE IT?

The Debt Challenge in Europe. Alan Ahearne and Guntram Wolff October 2011

Effects of economic factors on alcohol consumption in 14 European countries

187/ December EU28, euro area and United States GDP growth rates % change over the previous quarter

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

The Contribution made by Beer to the European Economy

99/ June EU28, euro area and United States GDP growth rates % change over the previous quarter

Kym Anderson. Revised December 2009

Customs and tax treatment of gifts received from outside Finland

EU study on company car taxation: presentation of the main results

The Economic Impact of Cloud Computing in the EU

Operational Companies VAT Indirect Taxes. Why Luxembourg: VAT advantages for commercial companies*

VOLUNTARY HEALTH INSURANCE AS A METHOD OF HEALTH CARE FINANCING IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

The Tax Burden of Typical Workers in the EU Edition. James Rogers & Cécile Philippe May (Cover page) Data provided by

PUBLIC DEBT SIZE, COST AND LONG-TERM SUSTAINABILITY: PORTUGAL VS. EURO AREA PEERS

How to Efficiently Recover Merchant Fees Using ATPCO s Ticketing Fees Solution. 6 August 2013

How To Calculate Tax Burden In European Union

Co-ordinated versus uncoordinated European carbon tax solutions analysed with GEM-E3 1 linking the EU-12 countries

EU Lesson Plan. Name of Teacher: Sharon Goralewski School: Oakland Schools Title of Lesson Plan: The European Union: United in Diversity

GDP per capita, consumption per capita and comparative price levels in Europe

THE PERFORMANCE - OF THE UK INLAND MAILS BUSINESS OF CONSIGNIA

Business Plan Calls Tariff The Choice for Business Telecoms

Wind energy scenarios for A report by the European Wind Energy Association - July Wind energy scenarios for 2020

Taxation of tobacco products in the European Union. Frank Van Driessche DG Taxation and Customs Union May 2006

Financial market integration and economic growth: Quantifying the effects, Brussels 19/02/2003

EBA REPORT ON THE BENCHMARKING OF DIVERSITY PRACTICES. EBA-Op July 2016

Payments Package: Questions and Answers

Exercise 39. The Euro. At the end of this exercise you will:

- Assessment of the application by Member States of European Union VAT provisions with particular relevance to the Mini One Stop Shop (MOSS) -

SEPA. Changes in the Payment System Implementation of the European SEPA Regulations for Kuna and Euro Payments

PRE-BUDGET REPORT: REVIEW OF CHARITY TAXATION

CIVIL SERVICE NATIONALITY RULES GUIDANCE ON CHECKING ELIGIBILITY

I. Introduction to Taxation

Crystal Clear Contract Services Limited Application Form CIS/Sole Trader

International aspects of taxation in the Netherlands

The impact of increased efficiency in the use of energy: A computable general equilibrium analysis for Spain

INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF PART-TIME WORK

Notes to help you apply for VAT registration checklist where to send your application Glossary About Corporate body the business

Global Forum on Competition

BLUM Attorneys at Law

Fantasy Budget Competition

Briefing on Personnel Leasing in the European Union

INTERNATIONAL TRACKED POSTAGE SERVICE

A new ranking of the world s most innovative countries: Notes on methodology. An Economist Intelligence Unit report Sponsored by Cisco

Report on impacts of raised thresholds defining SMEs

The Role of Banks in Global Mergers and Acquisitions by James R. Barth, Triphon Phumiwasana, and Keven Yost *

Electricity, Gas and Water: The European Market Report 2014

ERASMUS+ MASTER LOANS

4 Distribution of Income, Earnings and Wealth

UTX Europe V2 - Enhancements

Tourism trends in Europe and in Mediterranean Partner Countries,

Taxing Drinking and Smoking in Europe

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2015: Different Developments

10TH EDITION MERGER CONTROL VADEMECUM FILING THRESHOLDS AND CLEARANCE CONDITIONS IN THE 29 EUROPEAN JURISDICTIONS

Lisa Evers (ZEW), Christoph Spengel (University of Mannheim and ZEW), Julia Braun (ZEW)

Country note China. More than 255 million people in OECD and G20 countries have now attained tertiary education (Table A1.3a).

Do Currency Unions Affect Foreign Direct Investment? Evidence from US FDI Flows into the European Union

Labour Force Survey 2014 Almost 10 million part-time workers in the EU would have preferred to work more Two-thirds were women

UK INVESTMENT: HIGH, LOW, RISING, FALLING?

Panel: How broadband policy can contribute to deploy secured and universal broadband access. Presentation:

The Tax Burden of Typical Workers in the EU Edition

ING Bank N.V. (NL) 4Y EUR Euro Stoxx 50 Autocallable Note

NEWS FROM NATIONALBANKEN

NEW PASSENGER CAR REGISTRATIONS BY ALTERNATIVE FUEL TYPE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION 1 Quarter

Should We Stay or Should We Go? The economic consequences of leaving the EU. Swati Dhingra, Gianmarco Ottaviano and Thomas Sampson

The European Union s Economic and Monetary Union

Transcription:

THE REVENUE EFFECT OF CHANGING ALCOHOL DUTIES Zoë Smith THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES Briefing Note No. 4

Published by The Institute for Fiscal Studies 7 Ridgmount Street London WC1E 7AE Tel 020 7291 4800 Fax 020 7323 4780 mailbox@ifs.org.uk www.ifs.org.uk Institute for Fiscal Studies, November 1999 ISBN 1-903274-05-2 Published online at http://www.ifs.org.uk

The revenue effect of changing alcohol duties 1 Zoë Smith Introduction Since the completion of the Single European Market in 1992, it has become easier for people in the UK to take advantage of lower-priced goods across the border. Alcohol is one good where there has been particular concern about the level of cross-border shopping because of differences in tax rates between the UK and France. HM Customs and Excise estimated that in 1998, 290 million of revenue from beer, wine and spirits was lost through cross-border shopping. 2 This contrasts with 10.86 billion of total duty and VAT receipts 3 collected on alcohol. If the Chancellor cut duty, the volume of cross-border shopping could be reduced and more revenue would be collected from any increase in domestic sales, but less revenue would be collected from each unit that is currently sold. If the Chancellor wants to reduce the amount of cross-border shopping by cutting duty, the important policy question is whether, overall, these two effects on revenue would be positive or negative. Alcohol tax rates and revenues Two indirect taxes are charged on alcohol in the UK. All alcohol is subject to the standard rate of value added tax (17.5 per cent). In addition, excise duties are levied at different rates according to the type of alcohol. Duty on beer and spirits is charged at different rates according to alcoholic content. The rate of duty on wine is applied to the volume of wine and the same duty rate is applied to wine within a range of strengths. Table 1. Alcohol taxes, January 1999 Duty on typical unit Implied duty per litre of pure alcohol Duty + VAT as % of final price Beer 25p per pint 11.50 30% Wine 1.12 per 75cl bottle 14.56 51% Spirits 5.48 per 70cl bottle 19.56 62% Note: Typical units are defined as follows: for beer it is a pint of bitter at 3.9% abv, bought on licensed premises; for wine it is a 75cl bottle of table wine at 10.25% abv; and for spirits it is a 70cl bottle of whisky at 40% abv. Note that for beer and wine, the implied duty per litre of pure alcohol does not depend on the strength used to calculate duty on a typical unit. Source: HM Customs and Excise, Annual Report 1998 1999, The Stationery Office, London, November 1999. Table 1 shows the duty on a typical unit of beer, wine and spirits. Since duty is imposed on different drinks in different ways, it not immediately clear how the rates on different drinks compare. The last two columns in the table show two alternative ways of comparing duty across different drinks in a meaningful way. Whether we compare duty per litre of pure alcohol or duty plus VAT as a percentage of final price, spirits are taxed much more heavily than beer or wine. In terms of duty per litre of pure alcohol, spirits are taxed more than 70 per cent more heavily than beer and nearly 35 per cent more heavily than wine. 1 This is a shorter version of I. Crawford, Z. Smith and S. Tanner, Alcohol taxes, tax revenues and the Single European Market, Fiscal Studies, vol. 20, no. 3, pp. 287 304, 1999. 2 Pre-Budget Report, November 1999. Note that in our analysis we do not need to measure the level of crossborder shopping directly to estimate the effect on tax revenues of excise duty changes. 3 Total receipts are calculated from figures on duty receipts taken from HM Customs and Excise, Annual Report 1998 1999, The Stationery Office, London, November 1999, plus an amount for VAT based on consumer expenditure on alcohol taken from Office for National Statistics, Consumer Trends, 1999.

Table 2. EU duty rates on alcohol as at 1 September 1999 Country Beer/pint @5% abv (pence) Wine/75cl @11% abv ( ) Spirits/70cl @40% abv ( ) Austria 7 nil 1.41 Belgium 8 0.25 3.23 Denmark 18 0.49 7.20 Finland 56 1.23 9.81 France 5 0.02 2.82 Germany 4 nil 2.54 Greece 6 nil 1.79 Ireland 39 1.43 5.41 Italy 7 nil 1.26 Luxemburg 4 nil 2.03 Netherlands 8 0.25 2.93 Portugal 6 nil 1.58 Spain 3 nil 1.34 Sweden 31 1.53 10.53 UK 33 1.12 5.48 Source: Wine and Spirits Association. These rates of duty are among the highest in the European Union. Table 2 compares the duty rates in different EU countries for beer, wine and spirits and shows, for example, that the duty on beer is more than six times higher in the UK than in France. (Note that this is for beer at 5 per cent abv, not 3.9 per cent abv which is the strength used in Table 1.) VAT is also levied on alcohol but this is not reflected in the table. The VAT rate in France, for example, is 20.6 per cent compared with 17.5 per cent in the UK, so this would narrow the gap between total tax rates to some extent. The large differences in duty provide a financial incentive for UK consumers to shop across the border. One way to reduce this incentive would be to cut duty in the UK. But would this enable the Chancellor to recoup some of the revenue that he is losing to cross-border shopping or would it result in further revenue losses? Decreasing the tax rate would increase domestic sales but less revenue would be collected on each unit sold. Whether the overall result would be an increase or decrease in revenue depends on the balance between these two effects. Figure 1. Revenue maximisation R* Tax revenue, R τ* Tax rate, t Figure 1 represents the idea that there is a non-linear relationship between the tax rate and tax revenue. If the tax rate is zero, then revenue is also zero. There will also be a tax rate that is so high that no one would buy the good so no revenue would be collected. Somewhere in

between these two extremes there will be a rate that maximises revenue. Increasing the tax rate from zero will lead to increases in revenue, but only up to a tax rate of τ*. If the tax rate is less than τ*, then cutting duty will lead to a fall in total revenue because the revenue loss on each unit sold outweighs the gain from increased sales. At a tax rate of τ*, tax revenue is at a maximum. It is only if the tax rate is greater than τ* that cutting duty will lead to an increase in revenue. At tax rates above τ*, the loss per unit sold from a reduction in the rate is outweighed by the gain from increased sales. For any particular good, the relationship between the tax rate and tax revenue depends on total expenditure on the good, the current tax rates and how responsive consumers are to a change in the price of the good (the price elasticity of demand). Other things being equal, the more responsive people are to a change in the price of a good, the more likely it is that a cut in duty will lead to an increase in revenue. This is because, for a given fall in price after a tax cut, the more responsive people are, the larger the increase in sales, so the more likely it is that the extra revenue from the increase in sales will outweigh the loss per unit sold. It is also important to consider the effect that cutting duty on one type of alcohol would have on the demand for, and therefore the revenue from, other types of alcohol and all other goods. A change in the price of, say, beer will lead to a reallocation of spending between beer and all other goods. The effect is likely to be greatest on the demand for other types of alcohol because of the similarity between different types of alcohol. If beer and wine are complements to each other, then when the price of beer falls (following a tax cut) people buy more beer and also more wine. This means there will be an increase in revenue from wine, so we are more likely to see an increase in total tax revenue following a tax cut on beer. If beer and wine are substitutes for each other, a fall in the price of beer will lead to an increase in sales of beer but a fall in sales of wine. The result would be a fall in revenue from wine, so we are less likely to see an increase in total revenue following a tax cut on beer. The responsiveness of demand for one good with respect to a change in the price of another good is called the cross-price elasticity of demand. Also important for the total revenue effect is the rate at which the complement or substitute is taxed. The more heavily the complement or substitute is taxed relative to the good itself, the more likely the change in revenue from the complement or substitute will outweigh any opposite effect on revenue from the good itself. This is because, for a given change in demand, the higher the tax rate, the greater the change in revenue. Results In order to determine whether cutting duty would lead to an increase or a decrease in revenue, we need to know expenditure, current tax rates and own- and cross-price elasticities. We know current tax rates and expenditure and we use data from the Family Expenditure Survey from 1979 96 (about 120,000 households) to estimate elasticities. We evaluate the elasticities for the period after the completion of the Single European Market. We might expect the elasticity in the south-east to be different from that for the UK as a whole since the fixed cost of crossing the border is lower, so we compare elasticities for the UK with those for the south-east. However, we find no significant difference between the two. We also might expect the elasticities for the period after the completion of the Single Market to differ from those before, since consumers now have an additional way in which to respond

to an increase in price. We test whether the elasticities for the two periods are different, but again we find no significant difference. Table 3. Estimated elasticities for the UK, 1993 96, ε ˆsm ji j = Beer Wine Spirits Beer 0.76 (0.094) 0.60 (0.282) 0.59 (0.329) i = Wine 0.17 (0.087) 1.69 (0.464) 0.66 (0.449) Spirits 0.20 (0.120) 0.77 (0.525) 0.86 (0.763) Note: Figures in parentheses are standard errors. Since the elasticities are not significantly different in the south-east or in the different time periods, the elasticities that we use to determine the revenue effect of cutting duty are those for the whole of the UK after the completion of the Single Market. The elasticities are reported in Table 3, with standard errors in parentheses. The numbers in the table show the change in the quantity demanded of the drinks in each column with respect to changes in the price of the drinks in each row. The diagonal elements are the own-price elasticities. For example, the own-price elasticity of beer is 0.76. This means that if the price of beer falls by 1 per cent, there will be a 0.76 per cent rise in the quantity of beer demanded. Of these three types of alcohol, beer is the least price-responsive and wine is the most, although the results are not significantly different from each other. Equally important are the cross-price elasticities. For example, the number in the first row of the wine column shows the change in the quantity of wine demanded with respect to a change in the price of beer. Since this number is negative, it tells us that an increase in the price of beer would lead to a fall in the demand for wine, so beer and wine are complements. The amount by which demand for wine would fall for a 1 per cent increase in the price of beer is 0.6 per cent. The fact that beer and wine are complements means that, if duty on beer were cut, demand for wine would rise, so there would be an increase in revenue from wine. Since the cross-price elasticity of spirits and beer is negative, these drinks are also complements, whereas the cross-price elasticity of spirits and wine is positive, which means they are substitutes. Table 4. The effect of cutting duty on alcohol Cut in beer duty Cut in wine duty Cut in spirits duty Sales Revenue Sales Revenue Sales Revenue Beer Increase Decrease Increase Increase Increase Increase Wine Increase Increase Increase Increase Decrease Decrease Spirits Increase Increase Decrease Decrease Increase Increase Overall Decrease Decrease At maximum Table 4 summarises the effect that cutting duty on one type of alcohol would have on its own sales and revenue and on the sales and revenue of the other types of alcohol. A cut in beer duty will lead to an increase in sales of beer, but beer is not very priceresponsive and so the increase in sales is not enough to outweigh the fall in duty on each unit sold. Thus a cut in beer duty would lead to a fall in revenue from beer. But we also have to take into account the effect that a cut in beer duty would have on wine and spirits revenue. Beer is a complement to wine, so a cut in beer duty would lead to an increase in sales of wine and so an increase in revenue from wine. Beer is also a complement to spirits, so again a cut in beer duty will lead to an increase in sales of spirits and this means an increase in revenue from spirits. The increase in revenue from wine and spirits would offset the loss of beer revenue, but not completely. Overall, we find that a cut in beer duty would lead to a fall in indirect tax revenue.

A cut in wine duty will lead to an increase in sales of wine. Wine is the most price-responsive of the three types of alcohol and, unlike beer, we find that the increase in sales following a tax cut is sufficient to outweigh the loss of revenue per unit sold, meaning that a cut in wine duty would lead to an increase in revenue from wine. Beer and wine are complements, so there would also be an increase in sales of beer and an increase in revenue from beer. However, the effect on spirits works in the other direction. A cut in wine duty would decrease sales of spirits (since wine and spirits are substitutes) and so reduce revenue from spirits. Since spirits are taxed the most heavily, this effect is relatively large and it offsets the increase in revenue from wine and beer. Overall, we find that, as for beer, a cut in wine duty would lead to a fall in indirect tax revenue. This shows the importance of taking the cross-price effects into account. A cut in duty on spirits would lead to an increase in revenue from spirits. Beer is a complement to spirits, so a cut in spirits duty would lead to an increase in beer sales and an increase in beer revenue. But, since wine is a substitute for spirits, a cut in spirits duty would lead to a fall in sales of wine and this means a fall in revenue from wine. Overall, we find that we cannot reject that the duty rate on spirits is at the revenue-maximising rate. This means that there is little scope for the Chancellor to increase indirect tax revenue by raising or cutting duty on spirits, since at the current tax rate he is already getting the maximum amount of revenue. Conclusion The Chancellor faces a dilemma. If he cuts duty on beer, wine or spirits, he would probably reduce the amount of cross-border shopping but the result would be further revenue losses. Our results suggest, in fact, that the Chancellor could get more revenue by increasing the tax rates on beer and wine. Spirits are different, however, because there is little scope to increase indirect tax revenue by increasing the tax rate. Our research addressed the very specific issue of whether the Chancellor would lose or gain revenue by cutting duty on alcohol. The results do not mean that there are no reasons for cutting duties to reduce the volume of cross-border shopping, but they do mean that such cuts are likely to cost the Chancellor revenue.