NET PRESENT VALUE VERSUS INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN



Similar documents
NPV Versus IRR. W.L. Silber We know that if the cost of capital is 18 percent we reject the project because the NPV

Evaluating Investment Profitability and Business Controlling Methods

Net Present Value (NPV)

1. a. (iv) b. (ii) [6.75/(1.34) = 10.2] c. (i) Writing a call entails unlimited potential losses as the stock price rises.

Resolving Conflicts in Capital Budgeting for Mutually Exclusive Projects with Time Disparity Differences

The Current Role of Accounting Information Systems

Understanding Financial Management: A Practical Guide Guideline Answers to the Concept Check Questions

WHAT IS CAPITAL BUDGETING?

ANALYSIS OF WORKING CAPITAL MANAGEMENT OF LEADING COMPANIES IN THE HUNGARIAN DAIRY SECTOR BETWEEN 2008 AND 2012

STRESS TEST YOUR LIFE INSURANCE & AVOID THE ATTRACTIVE IMPOSSIBILITY by Gordon Schaller and Dick Weber

Why Use Net Present Value? The Payback Period Method The Discounted Payback Period Method The Average Accounting Return Method The Internal Rate of

Risk and Uncertainty. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e

Introduction to Discounted Cash Flow and Project Appraisal. Charles Ward

Measure for Measure Decision-Making in Life (Re)Insurance

Economic Analysis and Economic Decisions for Energy Projects

CHAPTER 8 CAPITAL BUDGETING DECISIONS

The Financial Accounting System within the Current Economic Context

Introduction to Real Estate Investment Appraisal

The Real Options Attached to an Investment Project

Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

On the Rate of Return and Valuation of Non-Conventional Projects

hp calculators HP 17bII+ Net Present Value and Internal Rate of Return Cash Flow Zero A Series of Cash Flows What Net Present Value Is

Investment Decision Analysis

ENGINEERING ECONOMICS AND FINANCE

RISK MANAGEMENT IN THE INVESTMENT PROCESS

The Hidden Cost of Poor Advice: A Review of Investment Decision-Making and Governance in Local Government Pension Schemes ( LGPS ) Part 1

Managing the downside risk of portfolio diversification

Valuation of debt instruments

Common Sense Economics Part 4: Twelve Key Elements of Practical Personal Finance Practice Test

Dr. István ZÁDOR PhD: Rita MARKOVITS-SOMOGYI: Dr. Ádám TÖRÖK PhD: PhD, MSc in Transportation Engineering, KOGÁT Ltd.

Relative value analysis: calculating bond spreads Moorad Choudhry January 2006

CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS

Paper P1 Performance Operations Post Exam Guide March 2011 Exam. General Comments

Research on the Income Volatility of Listed Banks in China: Based on the Fair Value Measurement

Cost Benefits analysis

Daily vs. monthly rebalanced leveraged funds

The Reinvestment Assumption Dallas Brozik, Marshall University

Operating Maintenance Model for Modern Printing Machines

A Methodology for Calculating the Opportunity Cost of Layered Sovereign DRFI Strategies

Session #5 Capital Budgeting - II Damodaran - Chapter 9: 6,12,16,18 Chapter 10: 2,10,16(a&b) Chapter 11: 6,12,14

Characteristics of the Participants

GREENE VALUATION ADVISORS, LLC

MANAGEMENT OPTIONS AND VALUE PER SHARE

Common Sense Economics Part IV. Twelve Key Elements of Practical Personal Finance Practice Test Multiple Choice Questions

VALUATION OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES. Presented By Sade Odunaiya Partner, Risk Management Alliance Consulting

One Period Binomial Model

Global Financial Management

2016 Wiley. Study Session 2: Quantitative Methods Basic Concepts

Solutions to Problems

Use of fixed income products within a company's portfolio

FINANCIAL AND RISK ANALYSIS WITH RETSCREEN SOFTWARE. SLIDE 1: Financial and Risk Analysis with RETScreen Software

: Corporate Finance. Financial Decision Making

CHAPTER 9 PROJECT FINANCE AND CONTRACT PRICING

The Net Present Value Rule in Comparison to the Payback and Internal Rate of Return Methods

During the analysis of cash flows we assume that if time is discrete when:

Cash flow before tax 1,587 1,915 1,442 2,027 Tax at 28% (444) (536) (404) (568)

Chapter 9 Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria Chapter Organization

Value creation problems of Hungarian. organizations Miklós Stocker Paris,

EFFECTIVE STRATEGIC PLANNING IN MODERN INFORMATION AGE ORGANIZATIONS

Concentrated Stock Diversification Analysis

Application of sensitivity analysis in investment project evaluation under uncertainty and risk

Overview of Financial Management

Capital budgeting & risk

SUMMARY. a) Theoretical prerequisites of Capital Market Theory b) Irrational behavior of investors. d) Some empirical evidence in recent years

Duration and Bond Price Volatility: Some Further Results

Inflation Risk and the Private Investor: Saving is often not the best decision

Prospect Theory Ayelet Gneezy & Nicholas Epley

KEY PERFORMANCE INDICATORS (KPIS): DEFINE AND ACT

6 Investment Decisions

The private equity J-Curve: cash flow considerations from primary and secondary points of view

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

COMBINING THE METHODS OF FORECASTING AND DECISION-MAKING TO OPTIMISE THE FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE OF SMALL ENTERPRISES

Key Concepts and Skills. Net Present Value and Other Investment Rules. rwjch5v3overview.pdf.

Adding and Subtracting Positive and Negative Numbers

Questions 1, 3 and 4 gained reasonable average marks, whereas Question 2 was poorly answered, especially parts (b),(c) and (f).

MEASURING INDUSTRY CONCENTRATION OF EQUITY INVESTMENT FUNDS IN THE REPUBLIC OF CROATIA

FINANCIAL PLANNER METHODOLOGY

Project Management - The Axioms and Principalship

Financial Assets Behaving Badly The Case of High Yield Bonds. Chris Kantos Newport Seminar June 2013

Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9. Section A. Mean growth in earnings per share = 100 x [(35 7/30 0) 1/3 1] = 5 97% or 6%

Margin Calculation Methodology and Derivatives and Repo Valuation Methodology

Setting the scene. by Stephen McCabe, Commonwealth Bank of Australia

2. CAPITAL BUDGETING TECHNIQUES

1.1 Introduction. Chapter 1: Feasibility Studies: An Overview

Capital Investment Appraisal Techniques

INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF PART-TIME WORK

Private Equity Performance Measurement BVCA Perspectives Series

FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING: VISIONARY THINKING OR OXYMORON? Aswath Damodaran

International Valuation Guidance Note No. 9 Discounted Cash Flow Analysis for Market and Non-Market Based Valuations

STRATEGIC CAPACITY PLANNING USING STOCK CONTROL MODEL

The minimum set of leased lines retail market

MODULE 2. Capital Budgeting

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications

The State of SEO within Retail Ecommerce Research Report

TD is currently among an exclusive group of 77 stocks awarded our highest average score of 10. SAMPLE. Peers BMO 9 RY 9 BNS 9 CM 8

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

Finance 581: Arbitrage and Purchasing Power Parity Conditions Module 5: Lecture 1 [Speaker: Sheen Liu] [On Screen]

P r. Notes on the Intrinsic Valuation Models and B-K-M Chapter 18. Roger Craine 9/2005. Overview on Intrinsic Asset Valuation

CIS September 2012 Exam Diet. Examination Paper 2.2: Corporate Finance Equity Valuation and Analysis Fixed Income Valuation and Analysis

Transcription:

Lajos Juhász 46 Lajos Juhász, Net Present Value Versus Internal Rate of Return, Economics & Sociology, Vol. 4, No 1, 2011, pp. 4653. Lajos Juhász Institute of Corporate Economics Faculty of Economics University of West Hungary lajosjuhasz@ktk.nyme.hu Received: March, 2011 1st Revision: April, 2011 Accepted: July, 2011 NET PRESENT VALUE VERSUS INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN ABSTRACT. The economic professional literature which deals with investment decisions can be characterised in general that the net present value shows objective picture for the decision maker while the internal rate of return not even mentioning other competitors have numerous mistakes therefore its expressiveness is limited. The net present value determined by the minimally expected yield (calculated interest rate) shows that how amount of wealth growth have been accumulated by the investment during its duration, but it does not inform about the real profitability of capital investment. However the investment s internal rate of return informs the decision maker that how works the real yield of long capital investment. As every investment economic method, the adaptation of internal rate of return could also have barriers. The barriers usually derive that the method is adapted in such model conditions where it is impossible to provide reliable information. This paper analyses that which method gives more relevant information for the manager either of two most often used investment methods. JEL Classification: M21, G11, G17, D24, D81 Keywords: business economics, portfolio choice; investment decisions, financial forecasting and simulation, production; cost; capital, total factor, and multifactor productivity; capacity, criteria for decisionmaking under risk and uncertainty Introduction The results based on the calculations using the net present value and the inner rate of return are often competing in the technical literature of investmentprofitability calculations. Decisions are usually made based on excess profits above the rate of return requirements calculated by the net present value principle, especially in cases showing the dominance of financial approach (BrealeyMyers, 1992). However, in reality since profitability approaches got priority the situation is that pieces of information that were calculated based on the inner rate of return or the net present value can be used for making decisions about investments and they complement each other well. The net present value determined by using the calculative rate of interest (capital profit sacrifice cost) the minimum required yield, the value of which can be derived from the market shows the amount of the increase in assets that was created by the investment during

Lajos Juhász 47 its life span of use, but does not give any information about the actual profitability of the capital investment. On the other hand, the inner rate of interest supplies the decision maker with information about the way the real yield of the longterm engrossed capital is created (Illés, 2008). Like every investmentprofitability method, the application of the inner rate of return can also have its limits. However, the limits usually originate from the fact that the method is applied in such model conditions which cannot give any reliable information. 1. Comparison of applied methods According to the technical literature, the limits mostly occur in three areas (Illés Iné, 2002): a) The ranking of investment proposals of diverse sizes, excluding each other mutually; b) The evaluation investments that have nonconventional cashflows; c) The adjudication of investments excluding eachother mutually and having timediffering structured cashflows. We carry out the analysis of problematic areas with the help of numerable data. Example a) A producer can choose from two investments and there is a significant two and a half fold difference between the starting capital investments. The minimum required profit need of the investments is 12%. The useful lifespan is 4 years. The first investment version can be realised by a 50 million HUF capital engrossment and results in an average net yield of 21.2 million HUF every year. The second investment version needs a 125 million HUF capital investment and results in the realisation of an average net yield of 48.3 million HUF every year. Evaluate the investment variations excluding eachother mutually based on the inner rate of return and the net present value. Table 1. Comparisons of investment versions Unit: million HUF Investment H B variations (n = 4 years) D t = 0 IRR B 1 50.0 21.2 34.8 25% > 12% +14.4 > 0 B 2 125.0 48.3 68.2 20% > 12% +21.7 > 0 q 1 = 21.2 50.0 = 0.424 q 1 4year = 0.4234 25% 50 + (21.2 / 0.4234) = 50 + 50 = 0 1 = 50 + (21.2 3.037) = 50 + 64.4 = + 14.4 q 2 = 48.3 125.0 = 0.3864 q 1 4year = 0.3863 20% 125 + (48.3 / 0.3863) = 125 + 125 = 0 2 = 125 + (48.3 3.037) = 125 + 146.7 = +21.7

Lajos Juhász 48 Both investment variations can be considered profitable based on the inner rate of return as well as based on the net present value. However, it is interesting that the first version is more favourable based on the inner rate of return while the second variation is more favourable based on the net present value. In this case the different results of the two methods can be explained by the significant difference in the cashflows of the two investment versions (Incidentally we have to note that between the investment versions excluding each other mutually there are hardly any big differences in size in practice so the decision maker rarely faces this problem). The technical literature suggests in similar cases that we should make a decision based on the absolute value of the net present value since the inner rate of interest is insensitive to the dimension of investments so the relative efficiency (rate) can mislead the investor. Before making a decision, we delineate the values of the and the inner rate of return characteristic for the two investment versions in a frame of reference (Diagram 1). (million HUF) 100 75 B 2 50 Fischerintersection B 1 25 Diagram 1. Comparisons of investment versions The Fisherintersection shows the discount rate in the frame of reference at which the two investment alternatives have a similar consideration based on the sum of the net present values. This is the socalled neutral discount rate which is 16.5% in the present case. In order to see clearly and to make a good decision we have to analyse the net present values of the investment alternatives at discount rates of 12, 16.5 and 19%. Table 2. Analysis of investment versions in case of diverse rates of discount Unit: million HUF on 1 Investment HUF capital IRR alternative (12%) (16.5%) (19%) (HUF) 50+(21.2 2.77049) 50+(21.2 2.639) B 1 +14.4 0.29 25% B 2 +21.7 0.17 10 16,5 20 30 Discount rate(%) +8.7 125+(48.3 2.77049) +8.8 +6.0 125+(48.3 2.639) +2.5 20%

Lajos Juhász 49 A t 4 year, 16.5%= 1 1 0.165 0.165(1.165) 4 = 6.06061 3.29012 = 2.77049 A t 4 year, 19%= 2.639 We can determine from the results of the calculations that at a calculative rate of interest lower than the neutral discount rate determined by the Fischerintersection investment version B 2 shows a higher. This capital demanding topic realises 7.3 million HUF more excess profit, not because it is more efficient but because its starting capital engrossment is much higher. If we consider the net present value on 1 HUF of capital, version B 1 looks more favourable. The average profitability on capital is 5% higher which also shows an advantage of alternative B 1. The principle considers the two investment alternatives equal in the Fischerintersection. However, it is obvious that version B 1 is more favourable. On the one hand, its specific is higher; on the other hand, the creation of the same excess profit at a capital engrossment of 40 % lower level is an incomparably better result. In case of a minimum yield need greater than the neutral discount rate (19%) the advantage of version B 1 is reflected in the. We can draw the conclusion from the abovementioned data that the absolute value of the net present value can be misleading in making economic decisions. On the one hand, it is because the cannot be independent from the value of the capital engrossment the comparison of the investment variations is impossible without a common denominator, on the other hand, the amount of the excess profit created is undeterminable without the knowledge of the useful lifespan. In summary we can say that we should not make investment decisions based on the absolute value of the net present value suggested widely in the technical literature but we should take into consideration the tendencies happening in the economic environment, the relations of the neutral discount rate and the calculative rate of interest, the entrepreneurial and bank requirements about profitability and the value of the capital engrossment and its duration. Example b) We know from the relevant professional literature that the results of dynamic investmentprofitability calculations are not reliable in the case of nontypical, that is not conventional, cashflows. In the case of a typical investment there is only one internal rate of interest. If the cashflows change signs several times during the useful lifespan of the investment, more IRR values are created while the is zero. This problem makes the work of the decision making financial expert more difficult since the known IRR values cannot be compared with the profit need of the company in many cases. Some experts suggest using the net present value principle to solve this problem. The starting cashflow of an investment is 1.6 million HUF. We can calculate with 10 million HUF net yields in the first year and with 10 million HUF net yields in the second year. Can an investment that gives a huge yield in the long run but causes great costs in a longer time period be acceptable from an economic perspective? (The calculative rate of interest of the business enterprise is 20%). x x 2 = 1.6 / x 2 1 + IRR = x IRR = x 1

Lajos Juhász 50 10 x 10 = 1.6x 2 1.6x 2 10x + 10 = 0 x 1,2 = 10+ 10064 10+ 36 = 3.2 3.2 x 1 = x 2 = 10+6 3.2 106 3.2 = 5 400% = 1.25 25% From an economic perspective, the rate of 400 % is unreal. However, an IRR value of 25% is imaginable. 400 = 1.6 + 25 = 1.6 + 5 25 1.25 1.5625 = 1.6 + 2 0.4 = 0 = 1.6 + 8 6.4 = 0 At the inner rates of return (25%, 400%) the turned out to be zero. Calculate the at average risk rate with the help of the calculative rate of interest. 20 = 1.6 + 1.20 1.44 = 1.6 + 8.3 6.9= 0.2 M Ft Calculate the in the case of a very risky capital engrossment if the calculative rate of interest is 30%. 30 = 1.6 + 1.3 1.69 = 1.6 + 7.7 5.9 = + 0.2 M Ft We get a very surprising net present value at the given calculative rates of interest. At a calculated asset need of 20% including the smaller risk offset, according to the net present value principle, the investment has to be rejected since the is negative. If we can engross our capital permanently at a very high risk rate the calculative rate of interest is 30%, the is positive so the investment can be considered profitable. It is not hard to see reason that the abovementioned investment must not be realised at a calculative rate of interest of 30%. We can establish, using the data we got, that neither the inner rate of return nor the net present value calculations help the economic discernment in case of nontypical investments. Example c) From the aspect of investmentprofitability calculations the situation in which the investments excluding each other mutually can be characterised by significantly different structures of cashflow in time can be seen as a problematic area. According to the suggestions in the technical literature we have to make investment decisions using the net present value principle.

Lajos Juhász 51 An entrepreneur has to choose from two investment alternatives. The investments concerned exclude each other mutually but have significantly diverse structures of cashflow in time. The calculative rate of interest is 12%. Table 3. Cash flows of investment versions Years B1 B2 0 25,000 25,000 1 18,000 1,500 2 13,000 2,540 3 3,000 15,500 4 1,815 27,000 Unit: thousand HUF Which investment variation should the entrepreneur realise? Make your decision based on the and the IRR values. By way of introduction, we have to mention that in the case of investments carried out for the same reason, it is very rare that an investor should face two cashflows moving in the opposite direction in their tendencies. The abovementioned case will hardly ever happen in practice so it only has a theoretical importance. Table 4. Net present value () of investment versions Unit: thousand HUF Years B 1 B 2 Discount B 1 present B 2 present Cashflow (0%) Cashflow (0%) factor (12%) value value 0 25,000 25,000 25,000 25,000 1 18,000 1,500 0.89286 16,071,5 1,339.3 2 13,000 2,540 0.79719 10,363.5 2,024.9 3 3,000 15,500 0.71178 2,135.3 11,032.6 4 1,815 27,000 0.63552 1.153.5 17,159.0 +10,815 +21,540 +4,724 +6,555.8 Table 5. Internal rate of return (IRR) of investment versions Unit: thousand HUF Year B 1 B 2 Discount B 1 present B 2 discount B 2 present Cashflow Cashflow factor (25%) value factor (20%) value 0 25,000 25,000 25,000 25,000 1 18,000 1,500 0.80000 14,400 0.83333 1,250 2 13,000 2,540 0.64000 8,320 0.69444 1,763 3 3,000 15,500 0.51200 1,536 0.57870 8,970 4 1,815 27,000 0.40960 743 0.48225 13,020 ~ 0 ~ 0 As we can see from the results, version B 2 can be considered more favourable based on the while version B 1 is more favourable based on the inner rate of return (Tables 4 and 5). In order to compare the two versions, let us analyse the value of the neutral discount rate.

Lajos Juhász 52 (million HUF) 25 20 B 2 15 10 B 1 Fischerintersection 5 10 17 20 30 Discount rate (%) Diagram 2. and IRR values of investment versions The Fischerintersection shows that at a discount rate of approximately 17% the two investment versions produce a nearly equal net present value. Table 6. Comparing the results of investment versions Investment (thousand HUF) on 1 HUF capital (thousand HUF) versions (12%) (HUF) (17%) IRR B 1 +4,724.0 0.19 +2.73 25% B 2 +6,555.8 0.26 +2.23 20% If the calculative rate of interest of 12% reflects the offset of the risks in connection with the investment very well, the realisation of version B 2 in more feasible since the net yields created during usage mean greater asset increase and their reengrossment at 12% can be provided with great certainty. If the risk of investment is growing because of the economic environment this, of course, comes along with the increase in the value of the calculative rate of interest, we have to prefer version B 1 since the backflow and the reengrossment of the greater net yields near the date of activation is more favourable, even at a yield rate above the calculative rate of interest. Conclusions The main conclusions that can be drawn after the analysis of the abovementioned problematic areas: The results of the decision made based on the absolute amount of can differ according to the values of the calculative rate of interest. The decision made based on the can be misleading because, on the one hand, the net present value cannot be independent from the value of the capital engrossment; on

Lajos Juhász 53 the other hand, the excess profit above the rate of return need cannot be interpreted without taking the useful lifespan into consideration. The determination of the socalled neutral discount rate is inevitable in order to make a relevant decision. In summary we can determine that the investmentprofitability decisions need the knowledge of the expressing the measure of asset growth during the useful lifespan as well as the knowledge of the IRR value reflecting profitability on capital. The two pieces of information together guarantee the making of relevant decisions. References BrealeyMyers (1992), Modern vállalati pénzügyek 1 (Modern Corporate Finance 1). Panem Kft., Budapest. Illés Iné (2002), Társaságok pénzügyei (Finances of Companies), Saldo, Budapest. Chikán, A. (2008), Vállalatgazdaságtan (Company Economics), Aula Kiadó, Budapest. Illés, M. (2008), Vezetői gazdaságtan (Managerial Economics), Kossuth Kiadó, Budapest.