Bank Branch Expansion and Poverty Reduction: A Comment. Arvind Panagariya * August, 2006



Similar documents
Effects of CEO turnover on company performance

Bridging the rural urban banking divide: what s been done and what needs to be.

A Model of Housing Prices and Residential Investment

Aide-Mémoire. Impact of Currency Exchange Fluctuations on UNHCR s Operations

Public Housing and Public Schools: How Do Students Living in NYC Public Housing Fare in School?

In recent years, fiscal policy in China has been prudent. Fiscal deficits

China s experiences in domestic agricultural support. Tian Weiming China Agricultural University

Some examples of what the author and his institution have experienced in the past ten years, are as below;

Objectives for Chapter 9 Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

1 Annex 11: Market failure in broadcasting

A Rational Savings Bank Deposit Interest Rate in India

General Certificate of Education Advanced Level Examination January 2010

Evolution of informal employment in the Dominican Republic

Florida s Plan to Ensure Equitable Access to Excellent Educators. heralded Florida for being number two in the nation for AP participation, a dramatic

BANKING SECTOR IN GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE

Infrastructure Development in India's Reforms

Regression Analysis of Small Business Lending in Appalachia

BEPS ACTIONS Revised Guidance on Profit Splits

Public Authority Debt Structure and New York s Future Generations

REVIEW OF THE SURVEY OF ENTERPRISES ON BUSINESS FINANCING. Second half

Rating Criteria for Finance Companies

HAS FINANCE BECOME TOO EXPENSIVE? AN ESTIMATION OF THE UNIT COST OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION IN EUROPE

Measuring the Impact of Tax and Expenditure Limits on Public School Finance in Colorado

ates on er 1958 sloan er 1959

Chapter 2. Education and Human Resource Development for Science and Technology

CONSULTATION QUESTIONS

Supply and Demand in the Market for Money: The Liquidity Preference Framework

New Insights into the Impact of the Doha Round on the Indian Economy Results of a Recent CUTS Study

WRITING A CRITICAL ARTICLE REVIEW

LIMITING GOVERNMENT: THE FAILURE OF STARVE THE BEAST William A. Niskanen

Education Funding in South Carolina

PROPOSED GUIDELINES FOR PERFORMANCE-RELATED INCENTIVE SCHEME (PRIS) DRAFT FOR DISCUSSION ONLY

Changes in Educational Spending in Kentucky Since KERA and HB1

Deficits as far as the eye can see

Why is the Greek economy collapsing?

Creating a Streamlined Service Center for California s Health Subsidy Programs

Recent Developments in Interest Rates on Bank Lending

Amendments To Accounting Standards For Direct Loans and Loan Guarantees. In Statement of Federal Financial Accounting Standards No.

Ádám Banai, Zsuzsanna Hosszú, Gyöngyi Körmendi and Bence Mérő: Impact of base rate cuts on bank profitability*

Analysis of Special Education Enrollments and Funding in Pennsylvania Rural and Urban School Districts

Overtime Pay Mandates Are No Boon for Employees

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

GAO. STUDENT LOAN PROGRAMS Lower Interest Rates and Higher Loan Volume Have Increased Federal Consolidation Loan Costs

The Impact of Interstate Banking and Branching Reform: Evidence from the States Susan McLaughlin

GAO STUDENT LOAN PROGRAMS. As Federal Costs of Loan Consolidation Rise, Other Options Should Be Examined. Report to Congressional Requesters

Meeting Urban Development Challenges

Economic Planning in China by Gregory C. Chow, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 219 June 2011

The economics of the Export-Import Bank: a teaching note

Savings bank accounts- interest ing issues

A Methodology for Calculating the Opportunity Cost of Layered Sovereign DRFI Strategies

Small Business Lending At Tenth District Banks

By eliminating jobs and/or reducing employment growth,

Response to Critiques of Mortgage Discrimination and FHA Loan Performance

CENTURY ENERGY LTD. FORM F1 MANAGEMENT DISCUSSION AND ANALYSIS FOR THE YEAR ENDED AUGUST 31, 2014

II. Tying LRAPs to Federal Loan Forgiveness and Repayment Programs

The Treatment of Tax Credits in the National Accounts

REPORT 2014/078 INTERNAL AUDIT DIVISION

Final Assessment 1 of Spain's eligibility for an EFSF/ESM loan to recapitalize certain financial institutions

The Budget Surplus: A Public Choice Explanation *

COLLEGE RETIREMENT EQUITIES FUND RULES OF THE FUND

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector

BANKING ON SOMETHING NEW: THE EB-5 ALTERNATIVE TO TRADITIONAL BANK FINANCING

Large and Small Companies Exhibit Diverging Bankruptcy Trends

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA

Policy Brief June 2010

Adjusting to a Changing Economic World. Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. It s a pleasure to be with you here in Montréal today.

Urban Planning System in China

Interaction of global and national income inequalities. Branko Milanovic and John E. Roemer 1

DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA COURT OF APPEALS. No. 98-CV Appeal from the Superior Court of the District of Columbia

Growth and Employment in Organised Industry

FEDERAL GOVERNMENT WILL PICK UP NEARLY ALL COSTS OF HEALTH REFORM S MEDICAID EXPANSION By January Angeles and Matthew Broaddus

Center for Effective Organizations

Nominal, Real and PPP GDP

Province of Newfoundland and Labrador. Public Accounts. Volume I. Consolidated Summary Financial Statements. For The Year Ended 31 March 2004

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

The (mis)allocation of capital

TAX EXPENDITURE IN CROATIA: PERSONAL INCOME, CORPORATE INCOME, REAL ESTATE TRANSFERS AND VALUE ADDED TAX

What s Wrong with the Airline Industry? Diagnosis and Possible Cures. Statement of

TSE-Listed Companies White Paper on Corporate Governance TSE-Listed Companies White Paper on Corporate Governance 2015

Common Sense Economics Part III: Economic Progress and the Role of Government Practice Test

Gao Peiyong* * Gao Peiyong, Professor, Renmin University, Beijing, China. gaopy@263.net.

CHAPTER ONE: DEMOGRAPHIC ELEMENT

2. UK Government debt and borrowing

THE EFFECT OF NO-FAULT ON FATAL ACCIDENT RATES

Open Architecture in Bancassurance

THE REPURCHASE OF SHARES - ANOTHER FORM OF REWARDING INVESTORS - A THEORETICAL APPROACH

Chapter 6. Commodity Forwards and Futures. Question 6.1. Question 6.2

With lectures 1-8 behind us, we now have the tools to support the discussion and implementation of economic policy.

Segmentation: Foundation of Marketing Strategy

Economic Research Division

The Relationship between the Fundamental Attribution Bias, Relationship Quality, and Performance Appraisal

Over the past several years, the issuance of small business loan securitizations

Locational Banking Statistics in Ireland: Introducing the Enhanced Quarterly Statistics

Chapter 12: Gross Domestic Product and Growth Section 1

Poverty Rates and Spending on Public Education at the K-12 Level: Is There a Correlation? Copyright 2007 University of Wisconsin Board of Regents

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

CLIENT UPDATE BROKER-DEALERS AFFILIATED WITH BANKS MEET THE LCR: FIVE KEY POINTS

Marginal Costing and Absorption Costing

Benefit Analysis Guidebook

Transcription:

Bank Branch Expansion and Poverty Reduction: A Comment Arvind Panagariya * August, 2006 * The author is a Professor of Economics & Bhagwati Professor of Indian Political Economy at Columbia University. Without implicating, he wishes to express his gratitude to Dr. Janakraj of the Reserve Bank of India for providing the history of the regulations governing the ratio of the rural and semi-urban bank branches to urban and metropolitan branches. He also wishes to thank Anjini Kochar, Pravin Krishna, Devashish Mitra, Ashoka Mody and T.N. Srinivasan for extremely helpful discussions and comments.

Bank Branch Expansion and Poverty Reduction: A Comment Arvind Panagariya * In a recent paper, Burgess and Pande (2005, p. 781) study the effects of bank branch expansion on poverty in India. They begin with the following observation: We show The timing and nature of these trend that between 1977 and 1990 rural branch expansion was relatively higher in financially less developed states. The reverse was true before 1977 and after 1990.reversals point to their being caused by the introduction and removal of the 1:4 branch licensing policy Our research design assumes that other state-specific economic and policy variables which affect poverty outcomes did not exhibit similarly timed trend reversals. [Emphasis added.] The authors summarize their key finding as follows: This paper s main finding is that branch expansion into rural unbanked locations in India significantly reduced rural poverty. We show that this effect was, at least partially, mediated through increased deposit mobilization and credit disbursement by banks in rural areas. Quantitatively, evaluated at the sample average, the authors find that that rural branch expansion in India can explain a 17 percent reduction in the headcount ratio. Alternatively, opening a bank branch in an additional rural location per 100,000 persons lowers aggregate poverty by 4.10 percentage points. * The author is a Professor of Economics & Bhagwati Professor of Indian Political Economy at Columbia University. Without implicating, he wishes to express his gratitude to Dr. Janakraj of the Reserve Bank of India for providing the history of the regulations governing the ratio of the rural and semi-urban bank branches to urban and metropolitan branches. He also wishes to thank Anjini Kochar, Pravin Krishna, Devashish Mitra, Ashoka Mody and T. N. Srinivasan for extremely helpful discussions and comments. 1

This is an intriguing set of conclusions. Can a simple rule linking the number of rural branches to the number of urban branches yield so significant a reduction in poverty? Prima-facie, the result seems implausible. A careful scrutiny of the policy as well as actual branch expansion points in the same direction. The recent paper by Kochar (2005) adds further to the doubts about the authors findings. 1 The History of the Ratio Rule of Rural Branch Expansion The first question we must ask is whether the period 1977-90, singled out by the authors because of what they describe as 1:4 branch licensing policy, was truly exceptional in terms of the branch expansion policy. The answer is in the negative. My detailed description below explains that what the authors call a 1:4 rule was actually a 1:2 rule. But more importantly, a more demanding rule in terms of rural branch expansion had existed between February 1970 and September 1971 and a slightly less demanding one continued until January 1, 1977 when the 1:2 rule was adopted. Though Burgess and Pande give a general description of the efforts by the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) at rural bank branch expansion following the bank nationalization in 1969, they seem unaware that India has had a policy of linking urban branch expansion to rural branch expansion starting well before the bank nationalization. 1 They also view the policy introduced on January 1, 1977 as something fundamentally new. To quote them (p. 781), 1 Burgess and Pande seem to view rural bank branch expansion program as an entirely postnationalization phenomenon. Thus they state, Nationalization in 1969 brought the 14 largest commercial banks under the direct control of the Indian Central Bank. Following this, the Central Bank launched an ambitious branch expansion program, which sought both to expand the rural bank branch network and equalize individual access to banks across Indian states. [Emphasis added.] (p. 781) 2

To ensure that targeted rural unbanked locations received bank branches, the Central Bank introduced a new branch licensing policy in 1977. It mandated that a bank can obtain a license to open a branch in an already banked location only if it opened branches in four unbanked locations. This 1:4 licensing policy was aimed at forcing banks wishing to expand in already banked locations to open branches in unbanked locations. [Emphasis added.] Yet, in reality, the link between rural and urban branches in India had existed as far back as the early 1960s. Recognizing the urgent need for the extension of banking services to areas not served by any commercial banks, the RBI began to require the Indian commercial banks to observe a ratio of 2:1 between banked and unbanked branches beginning in July 1962. Later, following its poor showing in the 1967 elections, the Congress adopted a 10-point program that included seizing the social control of the banks. A key element in this policy was to ensure an even expansion of the available credit over different areas and income strata of the population. As a consequence, the branch licensing policy came up for discussion at the first meeting of the National Credit Council in April 1968. The earlier norm of 2:1 between banked and unbanked center was modified to 1:1. Later, in considering the program of expansion of branches in urban centers, the RBI kept in view the need to distribute more equitably the burden on banks of opening branches between the rural and semi-urban centers on the one hand and the urban centers on the other. Accordingly, in February 1970, the RBI decided to adopt a rule of 1:2 between banked and unbanked centers in the case of banks that had more than 60% of 3

their offices in rural and semi-urban centers; in the case of other banks the ratio was set at 1:3. In September 1971, the requirement of banks to open the requisite number of offices in rural or semi-urban areas to get an entitlement for opening urban offices including those at metropolitan and port towns, was relaxed so that more offices in metropolitan/ port towns might be opened. According to the revised norms, a bank that had 60% or more of its offices in rural and semi-urban areas was eligible for opening one office each in an urban and a metropolitan port town for every two offices opened in rural and semi-urban areas; and in other cases it would be for every three offices in rural and semi-urban centers. This changed the rule to (1+1):2 for banks with 60 percent branches in the rural and semi-urban areas and (1+1):3 for other banks. On January 1, 1977, the RBI adopted the rule whereby a bank had to open 4 offices in unbanked rural centers to get an entitlement to open one office in a metropolitan / port town and one office in a banked center. The RBI was open, however, to banks asking for an entitlement of a banked center in lieu of an entitlement to metropolitan / port town. Thus, the 1:4 rule mentioned by Burgess and Pande was actually a (1+1):4 rule and no more demanding than the 1:2 and 1:3 rule in place between February 1970 and September 1971. The (1+1):2 and (1+1):3 rule in place between September 1971 and January 1, 1977 was only slightly less demanding. The bottom line is that contrary to the assumption made by Burgess and Pande, January 1, 1977 did not represent as sharp a break from the prior period in terms of the branch expansion rule. 4

2 The Actual Branch Expansion During 1972-05 The next question we must ask is whether the actual branch expansion followed the rules adopted by the RBI at various points. For if the branch expansion itself exhibited a drastically different pattern than would be dictated by the rules, something else is perhaps at work and the rules cannot be credited with the outcomes including that relating to poverty. If the RBI rules on branch expansion were effective at the level of the bank, they should surely be effective at the aggregate level. Therefore, the natural starting point for addressing the question is the national branch expansion data. The data on the branch expansion by the scheduled commercial banks, which account for 90 percent or more of the bank branches, are readily available from the RBI website for the period 1972-05. Using these data, I compute the incremental ratio of rural plus semi-urban branches to urban plus metropolitan branches for the years 1973-05. These ratios are shown in Figure 1. From the figure, the actual ratio of rural plus semi urban branches to urban and metropolitan branches bears virtually no relationship to the prescribed ratios in virtually any period except perhaps 1973-76. This period was subject to the 2:(1+1) and 3:(1+1) rule and the observed ratios ranged from 1.7 to 2.2. After the RBI switched to the 4: (1+1) rule on January 1, 1977, the ratio climbed up steadily to 10 in 1980, fluctuated between 5 and 10 from 1980 to 1985 and then fluctuated even more wildly. During 1977-90, with the exception of 1986 when the ratio fell to 0.2, it remained above the prescribed limit throughout. Of course, the ratio collapsed in 1991 and rose above 1 only once (to 1.4 in 1994) during the fourteen-year period from 1992 to 2005. 5

Figure 1: Ratio of rural plus semi urban branches to urban plus metropolitan branches 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0-5 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 It is, thus, evident that the bank-branch expansion far exceeded the prescribed ratio of (1+1):4 during 1977-90. There are two possible explanations for this outcome. First, banks saw large profit opportunities in rural banking and went after rural branch expansion well beyond what would have been required by the (1+1):4 rule. But given that the ratio entirely collapsed after the RBI withdrew its various interventions aimed at branch expansion in 1991, this explanation is unlikely to be valid. Additionally, the fact that the health of the banks in the early 1990s was quite poor undercuts this hypothesis. Second, the government and the RBI had additional objectives that required a far faster expansion of the rural and semi-urban branches than its own stipulated ratio would have yielded and, therefore, it actively sought to expand the network. This is indeed a plausible explanation. 6

Kochar (2005) offers a detailed discussion of the efforts by the Government of India and the RBI during the 1980s to expand rural branches as a means of bringing credit to the rural areas. Her discussion makes it clear that the bank branch expansion was but one part of the government s wide-ranging anti-poverty program. A key anti-poverty program known as the Integrated Rural Development Program (IRDP), which had been pilot tested in 1978-79, was extended to all the blocks of the country in October 1980. The program aimed at increasing the asset base of the rural poor through the instrumentality of subsidized credit. The budget allocations under the IRDP during the Sixth Five Year Plan (1980-85) exceeded that on general education as well as health. The government probably realized that the (1+1):4 rule could only guarantee the rural-urban mix of the bank branches, not their rapid expansion. Indeed, in so far as the rural branches were unprofitable, they could reduce the incentive to expand even urban branches and in many cases turn the banks away from opening new branches altogether. Therefore, alongside the IRDP, the government also launched what is called the Bank Licensing Program (BLP) whose objective was to bring the population per branch in each district to a specified target (Kochar 2005). This program had three phases. In the first BLP spanning January 1979 to December 1981, the population target per branch was set at 20,000. For the second and third BLPs, implemented between April 1982 and March 1985 and between April 1985 and March 1990 respectively, the target was lowered to 17,000. Implementation of the program involved states identifying deficit districts districts with higher population per branch than the specified target and then drawing up a detailed district-by-district program of branch expansion for each state in consultation 7

with the RBI. Later in April 1989, the government introduced a new Service Area Approach (SAA) aimed at the consolidation of banking. The SAA assigned each block of 15 to 25 villages to a bank. Adding this requirement to the population target raised the number of branches to be opened under the third BLP from 5,360 to 6,814. Figure 2: Growth Rates of Branches of Scheduled Banks by Region 18.0 16.0 14.0 12.0 10.0 8.0 6.0 Rural Semi-urban Urban Metropolitan 4.0 2.0 0.0 1973-76 1977-85 1986-90 1991-05 But this is not the end of the story of the 4: (1+1) rule. Though the observed incremental ratios of rural plus semi urban branches to urban plus metropolitan branches suggest something special about the 1980s (though not precisely about 1977-90, which is the period Burgess and Pande regard as special), growth in the rural bank branches tells an altogether different story. This is shown in Figure 2, which depicts the annual average growth rates of rural, semi urban, urban and metropolitan bank branches during four different periods: 1973-76, 1977-85, 1986-90 and 1991-05. A quick look at this figure reveals that the 12.4 percent growth in the rural branches during 1973-76 more closely resembled the growth during 1977-85 than 1991-05. Moreover, the period 1986-90, 8

which Burgess and Pande include in their period of rapid expansion of the rural branches, more closely resembles the period 1991-05. In comparison to 16.5 percent annual growth during 1977-85, rural branches grew only 2.9 percent during 1986-90. This is not drastically different from the average annual growth of 1.2 percent during 1991-05. The key results of Burgess and Pande rest on their observation that between 1977 and 1990 rural branch expansion was relatively higher in financially less developed states while the reverse was true before 1977 and after 1990. But it is the period 1972-85 that was characterized by rapid branch expansion. That is, the period of rapid branch expansion does not fully coincide with the period of rapid expansion in financially less developed states or with the period of rapid reduction in poverty. At one end, we have 1972-76 as the period of rapid overall branch expansion with relatively slower expansion in financially less developed states and no perceptible reduction in poverty. At the other end, we have 1986-90 as the period of very slow overall branch expansion with relatively faster expansion in financially less developed states and substantial reduction in poverty. 3 The Identification Issue Kochar (2005, p. 2) raises serious questions about the identification strategy of Burgess and Pande arguing that it is flawed because the expansion of the banking network during this period went hand-in-hand with the government s broader antipoverty programs, including the IRDP, making it impossible to distinguish the effect of the expansion of the banking network from that of government subsidies and other IRDP inputs. Kochar also presents evidence showing a close correlation between the real total expenditures on the IRDP and the expansion of the banking infrastructure between 1980 and 1990. Because of their very nature, both programs focused more heavily on the 9

initially poor states. Kochar concludes that it is almost impossible to separate the effect of the expansion of the banking infrastructure on outcomes such as poverty from that of the Government s anti-poverty programs, since the branch expansion program was designed to go hand-in-hand with the IRDP program. Surprisingly, Burgess and Pande make no mention of the IRDP. Kochar adopts an alternative identification strategy and studies the relationship between poverty reduction and banking infrastructure at the level of the district, which is also the level at which the bank expansion strategy (as opposed to the rural-urban mix of the branches) was implemented under the BLP. Contrary to Burgess and Pande, Kochar (2005, p. 2) reports her key results as follows: The IV [instrumental variable] and IV-FE [fixed effect] results are broadly consistent. They reveal that an increase in the number of banks benefited the nonpoor, with little significant effect on the poor. This result remains robust across all the different classifications of the poor, with the sole exception of the positive and significant effect of banks on scheduled castes in the IV regressions. The IV-FE regression, however, suggests no significant effect of the number of banks on scheduled castes, despite their significant effect on members of other castes. 4 Policy Implications The arguments presented above raise very serious doubts about the validity of the positive link between bank branch expansion and poverty reduction claimed by the Burgess and Pande. But even if we were to accept their conclusion at its face value, there remains the issue whether it offers an argument in favor of a return to the 1980s strategy 10

of rural bank branch expansion to eradicate poverty. There are at least two reasons why such a conclusion is not warranted. First, we must still ask precisely what led to the growth in the bank branches. To be sure the ratio rule was not behind it. I have argued that it is also unlikely that the expansion was driven by profitability. Instead, it was probably the BLP, itself a part of the IRDP and other anti-poverty programs, which drove the expansion. Assuming this latter to be the case, we must take into account the extra cost of branch expansion beyond what would have been justified on grounds of profitability and compare this cost to the cost of the best alternative policy available for the same poverty reduction to arrive at the optimal poverty reduction strategy. In other words, we must still ask if an alternative strategy would not have yielded the same poverty reduction at a lower cost. For example, would the same poverty reduction not have been more sustainable and less costly if the bank branch expansion policies had been directed at maximizing growth and the immediate relief to the poor had been brought through direct fiscal measures? In so far as such reduction came from credits that were eventually defaulted, the eventual outcome was indeed a fiscal transfer. But branch expansion was surely a costly vehicle for affecting such transfers. Moreover, poverty reduction so achieved may not have been sustainable. Second, even if we accept the unlikely conclusion that the bank branch expansion provided the least costly strategy for poverty reduction in the 1980s, it is highly doubtful that we can achieve the same outcome in the future. The returns to increased density of bank branches are bound to diminish rapidly. After a point, new branches would get business only by taking away customers from the existing branches and raises costs 11

without yielding extra poverty reduction. Now that a substantial network of bank branches in the rural as well as urban areas already exists, it makes even more sense to let the bank branch expansion and credit respond to profit opportunities and subsidize these activities only highly selectively when a clear need for them is identified. The recognition of very low returns to further branch expansion was probably the reason the government decided to discontinue its branch expansion programs starting in the early 1990s despite the fact that it continued its priority-sector lending program. Contrary to the figures presented in Burgess, Pande and Wong (2005, Figure 1), according to the Reserve Bank of India (2005, Charts 3-5) priority sector lending has continued to account for 40 percent or more of the net bank loans for the domestic public and private sector banks and for 32 percent or more of the net bank credit for foreign banks, as per RBI regulations. References Burgess, Robin and Rohini Pande. 2005. "Can Rural Banks Reduce Poverty? Evidence from the Indian Social Banking Experiment," American Economic Review 95 (3), pp. 780-795. Burgess, Robin and Rohini Pande and Grace Wong, 2005, Banking for the Poor: Evidence from India Journal of European Economic Association 3, 268-78. Kochar, Anjini, 2005, Social Banking and Poverty: A Micro-empirical Analysis of the Indian Experience, Stanford Center for International Development, Stanford University, mimeo. Reserve Bank of India, 2005, Draft Technical Paper by the Internal Working Group on Priority Sector Lending, Bombay. 12

13