The Baby Boom and Economic Growth. Peter S. Yoo



Similar documents
Effects of the Baby Boom

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Generational Aspects of Medicare. David M. Cutler and Louise Sheiner * Abstract

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey

Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey

The Real Business Cycle Model

SAMA Working Paper: POPULATION AGING IN SAUDI ARABIA. February Hussain I. Abusaaq. Economic Research Department. Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

@%C+DE !"#$%&'( 1)*L4=#*+.C+2))3)& .)$)&+/&#0* /4&)$5+67"' 87)9+:%;#*'%*

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. et Ph.D.

Better Guidance on Matters of Life and Death

Does Immigration Benefit a Regional Economy With An Aging Population?: Simulation Results from the Chicago CGE Model

Economic Growth. Chapter 11

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

The Japanese Saving Rate

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions in Dynamic Models

West Bank and Gaza: Labor Market Trends, Growth and Unemployment 1

Demographic Implications for Capital Markets Euromoney Conference 2005 Rome, September 6

LIFE EXPECTANCY AND SOCIAL SECURITY: WHY LONGEVITY INDEXING THE PAYROLL TAX RATE MAKES GOOD ECONOMIC SENSE. Abstract

Money and Public Finance

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

Technology and Economic Growth

Chapter 4 Technological Progress and Economic Growth

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Securing Social Security: Sensitivity to Economic Assumptions and Analysis of Policy Options

Finance Solutions to Problem Set #3. Year Real GDP Real Capital Employment

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

welfare costs of business cycles

Real Business Cycle Models

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

The Global Impact of Chinese Growth

Chapter 3 Productivity, Output, and Employment

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

JAPAN. Past trends. Scenario I

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

A Static Version of The Macroeconomics of Child Labor Regulation

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

The Real Business Cycle model

THE IMPACT OF FUTURE MARKET ON MONEY DEMAND IN IRAN

Transfers, Capital, and Consumption over the Demographic Transition

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Health Insurance Reform and Economic Growth: Simulation Analysis in Japan

Wharton Financial Institutions Center Policy Brief: Personal Finance. Measuring the Tax Benefit of a Tax-Deferred Annuity

Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth

Why Did House Prices Drop So Quickly?

Using Policy to Stabilize the Economy

Chapters 7 and 8 Solow Growth Model Basics

Chapter 9 Aggregate Demand and Economic Fluctuations Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Heterogeneous firms and dynamic gains from trade

Debt and the U.S. Economy

PROJECTION OF THE FISCAL BALANCE AND PUBLIC DEBT ( ) - SUMMARY

A LIFE-CYCLE AND GENERATIONAL PERSPECTIVE ON THE WEALTH AND INCOME OF MILLENNIALS

I d ( r; MPK f, τ) Y < C d +I d +G

Practice Problems on the Capital Market

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

COMMUNICATION THE BOARD OF TRUSTEES, FEDERAL OLD-AGE AND SURVIVORS INSURANCE AND FEDERAL DISABILITY INSURANCE TRUST FUNDS

Agenda. Productivity, Output, and Employment, Part 1. The Production Function. The Production Function. The Production Function. The Demand for Labor

THE U.S. HOUSEHOLD SAVINGS RATE AND CONSUMPTION 3 March 2009, additions 4 March see

Aging and International Capital Flows

Figure 1: Real GDP in the United States

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Update using 2006 preliminary estimates)

Annuity market imperfection, retirement and economic growth

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Note on growth and growth accounting

The size and impact of the current

Long Run Economic Growth Agenda. Long-run Economic Growth. Long-run Growth Model. Long-run Economic Growth. Determinants of Long-run Growth

Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In

The U.S. Social Security System: What Does Political Sustainability Imply?

WILL REVERSE MORTGAGES RESCUE THE BABY BOOMERS?

Chapter 12. Aggregate Expenditure and Output in the Short Run

The Effect on Housing Prices of Changes in Mortgage Rates and Taxes

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008

The EU Enlargement, and Immigration from Eastern Europe

Long run v.s. short run. Introduction. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Economic inequality and educational attainment across a generation

Economic Research Division

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

No Smoking at the Slot Machines: The Effect of a Smoke-Free Law on Delaware Gaming Revenues

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Economic Growth and Government Size. Mark Pingle Professor of Economics University of Nevada, Reno. and

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts.

MASTER IN ENGINEERING AND TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT

Transcription:

WORKING PAPER SERIES The Baby Boom and Economic Growth Peter S. Yoo Working Paper 1994-001B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/1994/94-001.pdf FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Research Division 411 Locust Street St. Louis, MO 63102 The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Photo courtesy of The Gateway Arch, St. Louis, MO. www.gatewayarch.com

THE BABY BOOM AND ECONOMIC GROWTH December 1994 ABSTRACT This paper presents a model of economic growth based on the life-cycle hypothesis to determine the path of capital accumulation and economic growth as the baby boom passes through the U.S. economy. The model predicts that a baby boom causes a temporary decline of the capital-labor ratio. The temporary drop of the capital-labor ratio requires a decrease in consumption per capita but as the baby boom generation nears retirement, capital intensity increases, which raises output per worker and per capita consumption. Furthermore, and perhaps counter intuitively, the model predicts that the saving rate of the economy falls during the period of increasing consumer welfare. These results suggest that consumer welfare may increase as the baby boom generation begins to retire near the turn of the century. Thus the retirement of the baby boom generation need not necessarily be a cause ofconcern. KEYWORDS: baby boom, simulation, growth, life-cycle, demographics, aging JEL CLASSIFICATION: D91, E17, E21, E22, Jll Peter S. Yoo Economist Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 411 Locust Street St. Louis, MO 63102 I would like to thank Jim Bullard, Ben Friedman, Greg Mankiw, Mike Pakko, Joe Ritter, Jim Thomson and David Weil for their helpful comments and suggestions. All remaining errors are mine. A4

I. Introduction Between 1946 and 1960, the U.S. population grew at an average annual rate of 1.8%, a rate that was significantly higher than the average annual rates of 1% for the twenty years preceding 1946 and 1.1% for the twentyeight years following 1960. Although the demographic changes associated with the baby boom are not especially large by historical standards 1 much effort has been put forth to understand its impact on the U.S. economy. 2 Moreover, the relevance of such demographic shifts goes beyond the borders of the United States. Japan and other OECD countries have a large portion of their population near retirement. One often stated concern about the baby boom is the impact of its retirement on capital accumulation and the subsequent declines in the growth of the economy and the standard of living. Since the eventual retirement of the baby boom generation is central to most people s concerns, this paper presents a model of economic growth based on the life-cycle hypothesis to determine the path of capital accumulation and economic growth. Unlike standard neoclassical growth models, a growth model based on the life-cycle hypothesis is well suited to an examination of the effects of a large retired population because retirement is an integral part of the life-cycle hypothesis. Using the life-cycle hypothesis as the basis for an individual s saving decision, I incorporate general equilibrium considerations to determine the relationship between demographic changes and capital accumulation. The model predicts that a baby boom causes a temporary decline of the capital-labor ratio. The temporary drop of the capital-labor ratio requires a decrease in consumption per capita but as the baby boom generation nears retirement, capital intensity increases, which raises output per worker and per capita consumption. Furthermore and perhaps counter-intuitively, the model predicts that the saving rate of the economy falls during the period of increasing consumer welfare. In the long run the welfare of individuals is no greater than it was before the entrance of the baby boom despite a period of lower saving in the economy. These results suggest that consumer welfare may increase as the baby boom generation begins to retire near the turn of the century. Thus if the individuals of the baby boom generation are fundamentally similar in their individual economic behavior and motivation 1 The nineteenth century contains much larger fluctuations due to changing birth rates and immigration. 2 See Auerbach, Kotlikoff, Hagemann and Nicoletti [1989], Auerbach and Kotlikoff [1990], and Auerbach, Cai and Kotlikoff [1991] 1

as individuals of other generations, their impending retirement should not be a cause of concern. While this paper addresses some issues covered by Cutler, et al. [1990], the results of this paper are at odds with their predictions. Their model modifies the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans, infinitely lived agent model by incorporating an aggregate dependency ratio. They then solve the model from a social planner s viewpoint. The social planner maximizes a utility function that weights equally all individuals alive at any given time. Due to the modification of the objective function used by Cutler, et al., the capital-labor ratio in their framework is not at all responsive to changes in the population growth rate. Consequently, consumption must adjust for all changes in the dependency ratio. They predict that per capita consumption will increase until it reaches its maximum in 2010, and decrease slightly thereafter until middle of the twenty-first century. Unlike Cutler, et al., the model presented in this paper solves a decentralized problem. The model first solves for an individual s utility maximization problem and then aggregates the individual s solution to determine the impact of the baby boom on the U.S. economy. The difference in methodology implies a slow response of the capital-labor ratio to changes in the labor force, which in turn implies that per capita consumption will continue to decrease until the turn of the century and increase thereafter. The remainder of the paper is divided into three parts. The first section solves the individual s utility maximization problem. The second section incorporates the life-cycle hypothesis based capital accumulation model in a general equilibrium framework. The third section examines the likely impact of the baby boom generation on the U.S. economy by simulating the model presented in section two. The final section presents a few concluding thoughts along with some implications of the results for the U.S. economy as the baby boom generation ages. II. Consumer s Maximization Problem The life-cycle hypothesis states that an individual s lifetime path of accumulated assets reflects his saving and dissaving for retirement, gradually increasing while working and then declining once retired. This implies that an individual s age is an important determinate of how much wealth he has. If the growth rate of the population fluctuates over time, the age distribution of the population fluctuates as well. Consequently, the desired holdings 2

of wealth of the population will vary with the age distribution of the population. For simplicity, I assume that each consumer works and lives for T and T years, respectively, from his time of birth, t. 3 The consumer maximizes his lifetime utility subject to the budget constraint that in each period his consumption and net saving must equal his total income. I assume lifetime utility is additively separable and isoelastic with constant relative risk aversion. subject to the lifetime budget constraint T i p max ~ (1 + 6)1_s Ct+ _l, 8 8 (1) s=1 T ç~ Wt+s_1,s ~ Ct~fs_1,s,i ~s 1+ at,o z...,~ ~s i (2) s=i k.l+rt) 81 ~i+rt) c~, 5 and wt, 8 are consumption and labor income in period t of an agent s periods old, respectively, and at,o is the endowment received by a new entrant to the economy. 6 is the subjective discount rate. rt is the rate of return to assets in period t. The optimal consumption and saving paths are ct+s_1,s = us (1)t_8 + (1 + rt) at+s_2~s_i] (3) f (1 + rt) at+ 8 2, 8 1 + wt+si,s ct+si,s if s~ S. 4 (1 + rt) at+ 3..2,s_1 ct+s_1,s if s > T where 83= and at, 8 is the end of period wealth held by an individual s years old in period t. Finally, I assume that labor productivity varies with an individual s 3 The model can accommodate uncertainties about life expectancy and the duration of labor force participation. However such complications add little insight into the economic impact of the baby boom generation. 3

age, so that productivity increases until the worker reaches middle age and declines thereafter. Given plausible values for the parameters in equation (4), the pattern of asset accumulation over an individual s lifetime reflects the familiar humped shaped asset profile of the life-cycle hypothesis. III. Equilibrium Effects of a Baby Boom Starting at steady state, where equilibrium interest rate, wage, and age wealth profile are stable, I first calculate the initial aggregate capital stock. I next calculate the size of the labor force. Given some production function, aggregate capital and labor yield aggregate output and capital-labor ratio, as well as equilibrium interest rates and wages. Once I know the interest rate and wage, I can then calculate the consumers consumption from equation (3).4 Given each individual s consumption, I then calculate equilibrium asset holdings for each individual using (4). Aggregating the savings of individuals determines the size of aggregate capital for the following period. The labor force in each period t, equals the sum of the population age distribution from 0 to T. Lt~cat(s) (5) where S t(s) is the age distribution of the population in period t. Given the asset profile of individuals, aggregate capital is merely the sum of all assets of every individual present in the economy. As before let at, 8 be quantity of assets held by an individual aged sinperiod t. The aggregate level of capital equals T Kt = at, 5~ pt(s) (6) If the aggregate production function has constant returns to scale and markets are competitive, the equilibrium rate of return of capital is rt=f (kt) (7) 4 To simplify the simulation, I assume static expectations by the consumers, i.e., each consumer assumes that current interest rates and wages will persist into the future. 4

where kt is the capital-labor ratio and f (k,~)is the net production function of the economy. Under the same conditions equilibrium wages equal wt=f(kt) f (kt)kt (8) In addition the economy grows at some exogenous rate ~ywhich augments aggregate labor productivity. To close the model, I assume a simple Cobb- Douglas production function with labor augmenting productivity growth for the economy. f(kt)=(i+y) t k~ (9) where a is capital s share of output and y is labor productivity growth. IV. Simulating the U.S. Baby Boom Figure 1 shows the impact of the baby boom on the growth of the U.S. population, the growth of the population aged 18-64 and the dependency ratio as defined by the ratio of the total population to the working-age population. It clearly shows a period some fifteen years of noticeably faster population growth in the population immediately after the end of World War II. Before I simulate the impact of the baby boom on the U.S. economy, I make the following simplifying assumption about the baby boom: initially the population grows at rate n until period t = 0 when the growth rate changes to n +, where c > 0 and indicates the magnitude of the baby boom. The new growth rate persists for i- periods and then the population growth rate returns to n. 5 Table 1 presents the parameters used in the simulation. 6 Figure 2 shows the path of output per worker and the path of the capitallabor ratio as the baby boom passes through the economy. Initially the baby boom enters the economy without sufficient capital so that the capital-labor ratio decreases. kt continues to decline at an increasing rate until the entire 5 The actual baby boom had a period of increasing birth rate followed by a gradual decline to a rate below the pre-baby boom era. The simplified baby boom is calibrated to the average annual population growth rate during the baby boom. 6 The subjective discount rate, coefficient of relative risk aversion, and the Cobb- Douglas parameters are equal to the values used by Auerbach and Kotlikoff [1987]. I also specify the same productivity profile over an individual s lifetime, which equals exp(4.47 + 0.O33age 0.00067age 2 ). 5

baby boom generation has entered the economy. Once the entire baby boom is within the economy, the rate of decrease of the capital-labor ratio diminishes, and after thirty years the saving of the baby boom reaches its lowest point, some four percent lower than the economy without a baby boom. Thereafter the capital-labor ratio begins to increase at an ever increasing rate, especially so as the baby boom generation begins to retire. At this point the retirement rate from the labor force is higher than the entry rate, therefore every person still in the labor force sees an increase in the capital per labor unit. The net effect increases the capital-labor ratio at even a faster rate. Eventually the dissaving of the retiring baby boomers decreases the available capital stock and the rate of increase in the capital-labor ratio slows, and as the baby boom generation dies, the growth of the capital-labor ratio slows even further, eventually returning to the capital-labor ratio to the old steady state level. Since output per worker is a simple transformation of the capital-labor ratio, the path of output per worker is very similar to that of the capital-labor ratio. Figure 3, panel A shows the path of interest rates implied by equations (7) and (9) and figure 2, panel B. The decrease in the capital-labor ratio generated by the temporary increase in the population growth rate causes interest rates to increase, until it reaches its maximum some ten basis points higher than the baseline economy. Thereafter interest rates decrease returning to its original level after the baby boom has completely passed through the economy. In contrast to interest rates, real wages follow the paths outlined by the capital-labor ratio, decreasing as the capital-labor ratio decreases and increasing as the capital-labor increases. The faster rate of entry of individuals into the labor force diminishes their marginal product as capital is slow to respond to the sudden increase in the growth rate. With decreasing marginal product of labor, wages decrease. The drop in real wages continues until thirty years has passed and real wages reaches its minimum, some 0.05 percent lower rate of growth than the economy without the baby boom. The decrease in wages reverses itself once the quantity of capital held by the baby boom generation becomes sufficient to reverse the decline in the capital-labor ratio. Figure 4, panel A shows the implications of the baby boom for consumer welfare. The decline in labor productivity diminishes per capita consumption. 7 The decline in the growth of per capita consumption lasts 7 Not all consumers suffer a drop in consumption. Individuals who are retired or are 6

for thirty years, dropping as much as 0.15 percent relative to the baseline economy. As real wages returns to the old steady state level, per capita consumption returns to its steady state value. National saving rate, shown in figure 4, panel B, reflects in part the relative size of the young, working population to the older, retired population. As the baby boom enters the economy the number of young saving for retirement increases, thereby increasing the national saving rate. The saving rate continues to increase as the baby boom generation is within the labor force increasing to a rate some three percent higher than the steady state rate of saving. As the baby boom generation begins to retire, the saving rate decreases until it returns to the pre-baby boom level, soon after the entire baby boom generation has died. V. Implications for the U.S. Economy The model presented in this paper suggests that the influence of the baby boom on the U.S. economy is transitory. While capital intensity and wages suffer initially, the transitory nature of the baby boom implies that the decline in the capital-labor ratio will reverse itself. Given that the baby boom started in 1946 and assuming that economic life begins at twenty, the baby boom began to enter the labor force in 1965. Therefore capital-labor ratio should reach its trough in near the turn of the century. This suggests that the U.S. economy should soon see an increase in labor productivity and faster economic growth. The model also predicts that concerns about economic hardships once the baby boom generation retires need not occur. As figures 2 and 4 show, the increase the capital-labor ratio accompanying the maturation of the baby boom generation reverses the drop in the average standard of living as measured by consumption per capita. Furthermore the generation currently entering the labor market should enjoy increasing wages relative to the baby boom generation. The model also predicts that the increase in consumption per capita and capital intensity do not require an increase in the saving rate of the working generation. As figure 4 clearly demonstrates, national saving relative to output decreases while the capital-labor ratio, consumption per capita and near retirement enjoy greater consumption as the returns to their saving increases. This suggests that perhaps income and wealth distributions favor individuals who hold their wealth as physical capital rather than human capital. 7

real wages increase. This is a result of the larger than average size of the generation near their peak lifetime wealth. As the baby boom generation s retirement progresses, they wifi eventually consume the large stock of capital they have accumulated. 8

References Auerbach, A.; Cai, J.; and Kotlikoff, L. J. U.S. Demographics and Saving: Predictions of Three Saving Models. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 4(1991): 135-156. Auerbach, A.; Kotlikoff, L. J.; Hagemann, R. P.; and Nicoletti, G. The Economic Dynamics of an Aging Population: The Case of Four OECD Countries. Working Paper no. 62. Paris: OECD, 1989 Auerbach, A., and Kotlikoff, L. J. Dynamic Fiscal Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987. Demographics, Fiscal Policy, and U.S. Saving in the 1980 s and Beyond. Tax Policy and the Economy 4(1990): 73-101. Clark, R.; Kreps, J.; and Spengler, J. Economics of Aging: A Survey. Journal of Economic Literature 16(1978): 919-962. Cutler, David M.; Poterba, James; Sheiner, L. M.; and Summers, L. H. An Aging Society: Opportunity or Challenge? Brookings Paper on Economic Activity 1(1990): 1-73. Fair, R. C., and Dominguez, K. M. Effects of the Changing U.S. Age Distribution on Macroeconomic Equations. American Economic Review 81(1991): 1276-1294. Mankiw, N. G., and Weil, D. N. The Baby Boom, the Baby Bust and the Housing Market. Regional Science and Urban Economics 19(1989): 235-258. Wascher, W. L.~Burch, S. W.; and Goodman, J. L., Jr. Economic Implications of Changing Population Trends. Federal Reserve Bulletin 72(1986): 815-826. Yoo, P. S. The Economics of a Changing Age Distribution. Ph.D. dissertation. Cambridge: Harvard University, 1993. * Boom or Bust? The Economic Effects of the Baby Boom. The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 76(1994): 13-22. 9

Table 1: Model Parameters parameters value T lifespan 60 T working life 45 n initial pop. growth rate 0.01 e size of baby boom 0.01 i- duration of baby boom 15 6 subjective discount rate 0.015 p coefficient of relative risk aversion 4 a capital s share of output 0.25 ~y labor productivity growth 0.02

Figure 1: U.S. Population Characterisitcs Growth Rate (percent) Dependency Ratio 2.5- -2 Total Population 1.95 2-1.5- Working Age Population Dependency Ratio -1.9-1.85-1.8 ~ ~ 1.75 I ~ ~ I c_/~,;, ~,,I - * 0.5 1 0 / 1.65 / / II / I, I I -J -1.6 / -1.55-0.5- I I I I I -1.5 1945 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 2025 2035 2045

Figure 2: Output per Worker, Capital-labor Ratio Panel A - outputper worker growth rate (percent) 2.06 2.04 2.02 2 1.98 1.96 1.94 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 2025 2035 2045 2055 1.92 Panel B - Capital -labor rallo growth rate (percent) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 2025 2035 2045 2055 solid - baby boom economy, dotted - no baby boom economy

Figure 3: Returns to Capital, Real Wages panel A - real rates of return to capital 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 2025 2035 2045 2055 panel B - real wages growth rate (percent) 06 2.04 2.02 1.98 1.96 1.94 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 2025 2035 2045 2055.92 solid - baby boom economy, doffed - no baby boom economy

Figure 4: per capita Consumption, Saving Rate panel A - per 1 capita consurrplion growth rate (percent) 1 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 2025 2035 2045 2055 panel B - saving rate 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 2025 2035 2045 2055 solid - baby boom economy, dotted - no baby boom economy