Do faculty salaries rise with job seniority?



Similar documents
Is MIT an Exception? Gender Pay Differences in Academic Science

Does Science Discriminate against Women? Evidence from Academia, Donna K. Ginther. Working Paper February Working Paper Series

FGCU Faculty Salary Compression and Inversion Study

Faculty compensation is a vital issue,

CHAPTER 8. Practise Problems

The value of apprenticeships: Beyond wages

APPOINTMENT TO AND PROMOTION OF ACADEMIC STAFF

Estimating the returns to education using the newest current population survey education questions

NINE DECLINING FACULTY WAGE PREMIUMS: ANALYSIS OVER TIME BY GENDER IN THE PUBLIC AND PRIVATE SECTORS. Frederick G. Floss i

Wage Differentiation Among University Professors: Evidence from UNI s College of Business Administration

Rates for Vehicle Loans: Race and Loan Source

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

Gender Differences in Employed Job Search Lindsey Bowen and Jennifer Doyle, Furman University

Gender salary and promotion gaps in Japanese academia: Results from science and engineering

STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF UBC FACULTY SALARIES: INVESTIGATION OF

Double your major, double your return?

Characteristics and Attitudes of Instructional Faculty and Staff in the Humanities

German Language Teaching and Teacher Training at Colleges and Universities in the US

USING ANALYTICS TO MEASURE THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE REFERRAL PROGRAMS

Health Coverage among 50- to 64-Year-Olds

Changing Faculty Employment at Four-Year Colleges and Universities in the United States

Economics of Strategy (ECON 4550) Maymester 2015 Applications of Regression Analysis

THE EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT OF THE WORKFORCE

THE UTILIZATION OF PART-TIME FACULTY IN BUSINESS SCHOOLS: ARE THEY DIFFERENT?

We begin by presenting the current situation of women s representation in physics departments. Next, we present the results of simulations that

ECON 443 Labor Market Analysis Final Exam (07/20/2005)

Performance Pay and Productivity: The Moderating Role of a High Wage Policy. Uwe Jirjahn. Research Papers in Economics No. 4/15

LABOR UNIONS. Appendix. Key Concepts

A Survey of Needs and Services for Postsecondary Nontraditional Students

SalarieS of chemists fall

Does Science Promote Women? Evidence from Academia

Persistence of Women and Minorities in STEM Field Majors: Is it the School That Matters?

The Earnings of University Faculty in Health Administration: What Characteristics Influence Pay?

The Effects of AACSB Accreditation on Faculty Salaries and Productivity

Research Note: Assessing Household Service Losses with Joint Survival Probabilities

CHAPTER 14 ORDINAL MEASURES OF CORRELATION: SPEARMAN'S RHO AND GAMMA

Future of the Professoriate: How Must We Change?

Special Survey on Vacant Faculty Positions for Academic Year (Pennsylvania)

APPENDIX A FACULTY SALARY SCHEDULES. FULL TIME FACULTY SALARY SCHEDULE FY Effective July 1, Doctoral Stipend Included in TRACK V

Chapter 6 MULTIPLE-CHOICE QUESTIONS

Microeconomics Instructor Miller Practice Problems Labor Market

The Changing Faculty and Student Success

Journal of College Teaching & Learning July 2008 Volume 5, Number 7

The System categorizes positions into the following groups:

Business Week Full time

Determining Future Success of College Students

Association Between Variables

ONE IT Organization, Staffing, and Planning

Estimation of. Union-Nonunion Compensation Differentials. For State and Local Government Workers

Online Appendix. for. Female Leadership and Gender Equity: Evidence from Plant Closure

FACULTY RESEARCH GRANT/HEALEY ENDOWMENT GRANT. University of Massachusetts

GUIDELINES FOR PROGRAM REVIEW AND ACADEMIC PLANNING

Factors Affecting the Salary of Different Professors

The 1995 NRC Ratings of Doctoral Programs: A Hedonic Model

Students Wage and Employment Expectations. Andrew J.A Dyck Supervisor: Ehsan Latif Thompson Rivers University

Dodging Judgments: The Plight of Online Graduates. Abstract

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

AN INVESTIGATION OF THE DEMAND FACTORS FOR ONLINE ACCOUNTING COURSES

How do Labor Market Conditions Affect the Demand for Law School? January Jeffrey Greenbaum. Massachusetts Institute of Technology

AN ANALYSIS OF UNEMPLOYMENT TRENDS AMONG IEEE U.S. MEMBERS. Laura Langbein, Ph.D.

Workforce Training Results Report December 2008

Gender Equity in the Academic Labor Market: An Analysis of Academic Disciplines

EDUCATION NEWS. Salaries, Recruitment, and Retention for CRNA Faculty Part 1

Psychology Faculty Salaries for the Academic Year

A Sloan Work & Family Research Network Fact Sheet

GRADUATE STUDENT SATISFACTION WITH AN ONLINE DISCRETE MATHEMATICS COURSE *

Topic 1 - Introduction to Labour Economics. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370. What is Labour Economics?

Marginal Person. Average Person. (Average Return of College Goers) Return, Cost. (Average Return in the Population) (Marginal Return)

Developing Statistical Based Earnings Estimates: Median versus Mean Earnings

YOUR GROUP INSURANCE PLAN BENEFITS EDUCATIONAL SERVICE UNIT #13 CLASS 0004 AD&D, LIFE

The Work Environment for Tenure-Track/Tenured Faculty at the University of Maryland. ADVANCE Research and Evaluation Report for CMNS

Adult Apprenticeships

Florida Gulf Coast University Sabbatical Guidelines Approved November 18, 2011

DOES GOVERNMENT R & D POLICY MAINLY BENEFIT SCIENTISTS AND ENGINEERS?

COMPUTER SCIENCE PROGRAMS

FACULTY RETIREMENT PLANS: THE ROLE OF RETIREE HEALTH INSURANCE

2009 Income and Employment Survey Results for. the Society for Industrial and Organizational Psychology. Charu Khanna and Gina J.

Barriers & Incentives to Obtaining a Bachelor of Science Degree in Nursing

What colleges do for local economies: A direct measure based on consumption

Is Economics a Good Major for Future Lawyers? Evidence from Earnings Data

Part-Time Faculty At Community Colleges: A National Profile

Equality Act 2010: Equality of Terms

Student Loan Market Trends Is College Worth It. Presenter: Kelly Savoie, Director Business Development April 2016

Update. Part-Time Faculty: A Look at Data and Issues RESEARCH CENTER NEA HIGHER EDUCATION

Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System Human Resources Data Quality Study Methodology Report

CLOSE THE GAP WORKING PAPER GENDER PAY GAP STATISTICS. April 2015 INTRODUCTION WHAT IS THE GENDER PAY GAP? ANNUAL SURVEY OF HOURS AND EARNINGS

Relative Wages and the Market for Nursing Instructors

Political Science Assistant Professor

The AP-Viacom Survey of Youth on Education March, 2011

With state legislatures squeezing higher education

The Best Jobs of 2014

Implementation Committee for Gender Based Salary Adjustments (as identified in the Pay Equity Report, 2005)

Compensation Analysis

Faculty Handbook

High-Impact Practices and Experiences from the Wabash National Study

Disseminating Research and Writing Research Proposals

Determining Future Success of College Students

Introducing Market Pricing and Broad Bands

A Partial Picture: The representation of equity-seeking groups in Canada s universities and colleges

Transcription:

Economics Letters 58 (1998) 39 44 Do faculty salaries rise with job seniority? * Debra A. Barbezat, Michael R. Donihue Economics Department, Colby College, Waterville, ME 04901, USA Received 7 October 1995; received in revised form 9 September 1997; accepted 1 October 1997 Abstract Previous research suggests that academic salaries fall with greater job seniority. Using a 1988 national survey, we find that the return to seniority is positive over a lengthy employment period. Tenure status and academic rank also affect the return to seniority 1998 Elsevier Science S.A. Keywords: Faculty; Salary; Seniority JEL classification: J31; J44 1. Introduction The availability of national faculty data bases containing detailed information on salaries and productivity measures has helped fuel a growing literature on academic salaries. The importance of the academic labor market increases to the extent researchers can extrapolate results to the markets for other professional workers for whom similar data are not as readily available. Recent findings, however, might cause us to question the similarity between faculty salary determination and the salaries of workers outside academe. In his article Seniority and monopsony in the academic labor market Ransom uses data from 1 three national faculty surveys to illustrate what he views as a labor market anomoly: an inverse relationship between seniority and academic salaries (Ransom, 1993). Ransom suggests that the explanation lies in the monopsony power that university employers derive from the relatively large *Corresponding author. Tel.: 1 1 07 87 3154; fax: 1 1 07 87 363; e-mail: dabarbez@colby.edu 1 Ransom s data are from: the Carnegie Commission National Survey of Higher Education: Faculty Study 1969; the American Council on Education s 1973 survey; and the 1977 Survey of the American Professoriate. Ransom is not the first researcher to find a negative seniority wage premium among academics. Siow (1994) uncovered a negative wage premium using the 1969 Carnegie Faculty Survey, one of Ransom s data bases. Using faculty data from two universities, Hoffman (1976) also reported an inverse relationship between seniority and salary. Siow attributes the negative correlation to implicit peer review. Academics who move will have higher wages than non-movers, controlling for labor market experience. Due to moving costs, professors with outside offers who do not move, usually stay for lower counter bids than rejected outside offers. (p. 3). In Raids and Offer Matching, Lazear (1986) predicted a similar scenario. 0165-1765/ 98/ $19.00 1998 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PII S0165-1765(97)007-3

40 D.A. Barbezat, M.R. Donihue / Economics Letters 58 (1998) 39 44 3 distances between universities as well as the individualized nature of faculty pay. Hallock (1995) tries to replicate Ransom s results using 1989 data from the University of Massachusetts at Amherst (UMASS). Unlike Ransom, Hallock found a positive return to seniority for at least the first 15 years of seniority. Unable to reconcile his results with Ransom s, Hallock suggested that collective bargaining at UMASS or an abundance of local employment options may have reduced the university s monopsony power. We agree that UMASS may have special characteristics that reduce 4 the representativeness of Hallock s results. By contrast, our estimates of the effect of seniority on salary are based on a recent national faculty survey (National Survey of Postsecondary Faculty and 5 National Center for Education Statistics, 1988). Like Hallock, we find that the marginal effect of seniority is positive until a relatively advanced level of seniority.. The seniority profile for faculty subgroups Ransom estimated the effect of experience, seniority, and several professional and demographic characteristics on logarithm of faculty member s salary. Because he used several faculty surveys with different survey items, Ransom s definition and measurement of some of these variables, including seniority, varied somewhat across data sets. Ransom presented results for a sample of faculty from 6 All universities and colleges as well as High-quality, or research universities. He found that when his regression included measures of experience, experience-squared, seniority, and senioritysquared, the coefficients on experience and seniority-squared were positive, but the coefficients on experience-squared and seniority were negative. When he used interval data for experience and seniority, Ransom found that the seniority variables were negatively correlated with salary by the second year for 1969 and the effect of seniority was negative by the 11th year for 1977. By contrast, Hallock found that the coefficients were positive on continuous experience and seniority variables, but negative on the quadratic terms using UMASS data. According to Hallock s estimates, the marginal return to seniority was positive for the first 15 years and the average return remained positive until approximately 9 years of seniority. For comparability with these earlier studies, we control for the same basic set of independent variables: degree type, race, gender, and academic discipline (represented by 15 dummy variables), as well as a continuous experience variable, a continuous seniority variable and the quadratic form of 7 both these variables. Following Ransom s work, seniority is defined as the number of years employed 3 Ransom s model is also described in Monopsony in the Labor Market (Boal and Ransom, 1997). 4 For example, according to a representative from the Massachusetts Society of Professors, the UMASS union, faculty salary increases were strong under the Dukakis administration (1980 88), but an era of freezes and cuts began in 1989, the year Hallock collected his data. Also, UMASS lacks some of the features that tend to raise the return to seniority at unionized campuses, such as a step system for salary increases. 5 NSOPF-88 was conducted by the National Center for Education Statistics. A total of 838 faculty members from 44 academic institutions participated in the survey. 6 Ransom does not report whether he examined full-time faculty only or part-time employees as well. Hallock s data base included full-time faculty in the full, associate, and assistant ranks only. 7 Unlike earlier faculty data tapes, the NSOPF-88 contains no regional variables, which distinguishes our regressions from Ransom s work.

D.A. Barbezat, M.R. Donihue / Economics Letters 58 (1998) 39 44 41 at one s current institution. Our experience measure reflects the number of years since receipt of highest degree. This definition is equivalent to Hallock s and Ransom s experience measure for the 1973 data set. The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of basic institutional salary in 1987 88. Our sample is restricted to full-time faculty from all types of universities and liberal arts colleges. To be consistent with Ransom s findings, we would need to find a positive estimated coefficient for experience, a negative coefficient on experience-squared, a negative coefficient on seniority and a positive coefficient on seniority-squared (see Ransom, Tables 3, 5, and 6). As shown in the first column of Table 1, our estimated coefficients for seniority and seniority-squared have the opposite sign as Ransom s and both are statistically significant at the 1% level. Ransom noted that, in cross-section data, faculty members with greater seniority may have lower productivity, on average, resulting in a negative return to seniority. However, the addition of 1 dummy variables representing the number of books, monographs, and articles published does not change the positive coefficient on seniority (see column ). Ransom concludes that among faculty at large research-oriented universities individuals with high seniority are paid less, on average, than individuals with less seniority. For Ransom s sample of all university and college faculty, the coefficient estimates for most seniority variables are also negative using 1969, 1973, and 1977 data (see Ransom, Tables 4). In Table 1 we present our results for a sample of university faculty only (columns 3 and 4) and another subsample of faculty at research 1 and universities as defined by the Carnegie classification system (columns 5 and 6). Again, we do not find negative seniority coefficients as did Ransom. Table facilitates comparison between our results and those of previous studies. The marginal effect of an additional year of seniority is given at specific points in time using regression coefficients Table 1 Selected regression coefficients by institutional type: 1988 NSOPF data (dependent variable 5 logarithm of annual salary) Variable 1 3 4 5 6 Name University and University and University University Top Top College College Faculty Faculty Research Research Faculty Faculty (with Faculty Faculty (with Publications) (with Publications) Publications) Experience 0.078*** 0.017*** 0.083*** 0.05*** 0.0405*** 0.037*** (0.0031) (0.0031) (0.0030) (0.0030) (0.0039) (0.0040) (Experience) 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.0004*** 0.0004*** (0.8E-04) (0.8E-04) (0.7E-04) (0.8E-04) (0.9E-04) (0.9E-04) Seniority 0.0134*** 0.0139*** 0.013*** 0.0137*** 0.0051 0.0044 (0.003) (0.0031) (0.0031) (0.0031) (0.0040) (0.0039) (Seniority) 0.0004*** 0.0003*** 0.0004*** 0.0003*** 0.0003*** 0.000** (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) Sample size 5,011 5,011 4,693 4,693 1,938 1,938 Adjusted R 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.34 0.37 Notes: Standard errors are given in parentheses. Regressions include degree type, race, gender, and academic discipline. Asterisks denote statistical significance at the one (***), five (**), and ten (*) percent level.

4 D.A. Barbezat, M.R. Donihue / Economics Letters 58 (1998) 39 44 Table Marginal returns to experience and seniority over time Study Variable Sample 1 year 5 years 10 years 15 years 0 years Barbezat Donihue (1988 NSOPF) Experience University 1 College 0.074 0.058 0.038 0.018 0.0198 University Only 0.079 0.063 0.043 0.03 0.003 Top Research 0.0397 0.0365 0.035 0.085 0.045 Seniority University 1 College 0.016 0.0094 0.0054 0.0014 0.006 University Only 0.014 0.009 0.005 0.001 0.008 Top Research 0.0045 0.001 0.0009 0.0039 0.0069 Hallock (1989 UMASS) Experience Sample with Field (Col. 4) 0.0306 0.076 0.038 0.0 0.016 Sample with Dept. (Col. 5) 0.0308 0.078 0.039 0.001 0.016 Seniority Sample with Field (Col. 4) 0.0114 0.0078 0.0034 0.0011 0.0056 Sample with Dept. (Col. 5) 0.011 0.0079 0.0038 0.000 0.0043 Ransom (197 73 ACE) Experience University 1 College 0.0377 0.037 0.064 0.001 0.0138 Research Only 0.0436 0.038 0.031 0.04 0.017 Seniority University 1 College 3.3E-4.6E-4 1.7E-4 7.4E-5 1.8E-5 Research Only 0.0036 0.003 0.006 0.001 0.0015 8 from this study, the Hallock study and Ransom s 1993 paper. We also include the marginal effect of an additional year of experience across all three studies. For our samples, the return to an additional year of seniority is positive until 0 years of seniority, with the exception of faculty at top research universities who experience a negative return at 10 years. Our results may support Ransom s assertion that the positive effects of seniority do not last as long at research universities, or, at least, top research universities. Still, among these three studies, only Ransom finds a negative return to seniority at early career stages. 3. Discussion of results As Ransom notes, the idea that long-term employment relationships in academia might be associated with lower salaries is astonishing given economists current theories regarding the relationship between pay and seniority. Our results using national survey data for 1988 call into question the generality of Ransom s findings. For our sample of colleges and universities, increased seniority raises salary over a relatively lengthy period, although this period appears to be shorter at top research universities. Ransom explains his finding of a negative return to seniority by noting that 8 The marginal effect of seniority at a given number of years is calculated by adding the estimated seniority coefficient to the coefficient on seniority squared multiplied by two times the number of years.

D.A. Barbezat, M.R. Donihue / Economics Letters 58 (1998) 39 44 43 Table 3 Selected regression coefficients by tenure status and rank: 1988 NSOPF data (dependent variable 5 logarithm of annual salary) Variable 1 3 4 5 Name Tenured Untenured Full Associate Assistants, Faculty Faculty Professors Professors Lecturers, Instructors Experience 0.0333*** 0.0044 0.0410*** 0.0145** 0.0019 (0.0043) (0.0057) (0.0066) (0.0066) (0.006) (Experience) 0.0005*** 0.0001 0.0006*** 0.0003 0.000 (0.0001) (0.000) (0.0001) (0.000) (0.000) Seniority 0.0107*** 0.054*** 0.0074* 0.00 0.066*** (0.0038) (0.010) (0.0031) (0.006) (0.0088) (Seniority) 0.000** 0.0007 0.7E-04 0.000 0.0005 (0.0001) (0.0005) (0.0001) (0.000) (0.0004) Sample size 3,315 1,694,003 1,396 1,559 Adjusted R 0.18 0.1 0.13 0.08 0.09 Notes: Standard errors are given in parentheses. Samples include faculty at all universities and liberal arts colleges. Regressions include degree type, race, gender, academic discipline, and publications. Asterisks denote statistical significance at the one (***), five (**), and ten (*) percent level. Faculty in the Other Ranks category are included in columns 1 and but excluded from columns 3, 4 and 5 (leading to a lower total sample size). academic employers might derive monopsony power from the great distances between academic institutions as well as the individualized nature of pay. Even accepting his finding of a negative return to seniority at research universities, this explanation is incomplete. If the entire labor market can be described as monopsonistic, why would the seniority wage premium be negative for research faculty only? We examined various subgroups of faculty to determine the circumstances under which increased seniority might reduce faculty salary. Estimating separate regressions by gender, institutional size, institutional control (public versus private), and selected disciplines, we consistently found that the seniority coefficient was positive and the other estimated coefficients, seniority-squared, experience, and experience-squared, tended to be negative, positive, and negative, respectively. Only two characteristics were associated with a negative return to seniority: advanced academic rank and achievement of tenure. As shown in the first two columns of Table 3, the estimated effect of seniority on salary is negative among tenured faculty at all universities and liberal arts colleges, but positive for untenured academics. Upon stratifying by academic rank (columns 3 5, Table 3), the estimated coefficient on seniority is negative for full professors and associate professors, but positive for the 9 ranks of assistants, instructors and lecturers. 9 On average, tenured and full professors have more seniority than other professors, which may be causing the negative seniority premium in those samples. The mean value of seniority is 16.8 for tenured faculty (versus 4.1 for untenured) and 18.1 years for full professors (versus 1.6 for associates and 5. for the assistant/ lecturer/ instructor category). Using the estimated coefficients for seniority and seniority-squared, however, the marginal return to an additional year of seniority remains positive until the 19th year for untenured professors and the 7th year for assistant/ lecturers/ instructors. So it is unlikely that the negative return found among senior professors simply reflects their greater levels of seniority.

44 D.A. Barbezat, M.R. Donihue / Economics Letters 58 (1998) 39 44 These findings suggest that the tenure system, a unique institutional feature of academia, is related to an employer s willingness to compensate seniority. If reduced faculty mobility accompanies the 10 granting of lifetime employment, employers may gain monopsony power over tenured faculty. The 11 result may be that additional years of service with the institution are no longer rewarded. References National Survey of Postsecondary Faculty, National Center for Education Statistics, 1988. U.S. Department of Education, Washington, DC. Boal, W.M., Ransom, M., 1997. Monopsony in the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature XXXV (1), 86 11. Hallock, K.F., 1995. Seniority and monopsony in the academic labor market: Comment. American Economic Review 85 (3), 654 657. Hoffman, E.P., 1976. Faculty salaries: Is there discrimination by sex, race, and discipline? Additional evidence. American Economic Review 66 (1), 196 198. Lazear, E.P., 1986. Raids and offer matching. Research in Labor Economics 8, 141 165. Ransom, M.R., 1993. Seniority and monopsony in the academic labor market. American Economic Review 83 (1), 1 33. Siow, A., 1994. The organization of the market for professors. Unpublished Working Paper, The University of Toronto, Department of Economics. 10 As evidence of reduced mobility, 67% of tenured faculty in the NSOPF responded that they were not at all likely to seek out or accept another position. 11 The possibility that tenure would result in a negative seniority wage premium is supported by some previous literature. For example, it has been suggested that the award of tenure constitutes an implicit downward binding minimum wage for faculty (see Siow, 1994).