New Estimates of the Fraction of People Who Consume Current Income



Similar documents
DOES HOUSEHOLD DEBT HELP FORECAST CONSUMER SPENDING? Robert G. Murphy Department of Economics Boston College Chestnut Hill, MA 02467

Benchmark Revisions and the U.S. Personal Saving Rate. Leonard I. Nakamura and Tom Stark. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Credit Card Use After the Final Mortgage Payment: Does the Magnitude of Income Shocks Matter? Barry Scholnick University of Alberta

Monetary Policy and Long-term Interest Rates

Household debt and consumption in the UK. Evidence from UK microdata. 10 March 2015

ON THE DEATH OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE William A. Niskanen

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds

Real Business Cycle Models

2. What is the general linear model to be used to model linear trend? (Write out the model) = or

Bank Profitability: The Impact of Foreign Currency Fluctuations

An Analysis of the Effect of Income on Life Insurance. Justin Bryan Austin Proctor Kathryn Stoklosa

Part 2: Analysis of Relationship Between Two Variables

Empirical Project, part 2, ECO 672, Spring 2014

Final. 1. (2 pts) What is the expected effect on the real demand for money of an increase in the nominal interest rate? How to explain this effect?

Miles Kimball. University of Michigan and NBER. This Draft: May 29, 2012

DID THE 2001 TAX REBATE STIMULATE SPENDING? EVIDENCE FROM TAXPAYER SURVEYS. Matthew D. Shapiro and Joel Slemrod. University of Michigan and NBER

Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data

ANNUITY LAPSE RATE MODELING: TOBIT OR NOT TOBIT? 1. INTRODUCTION

THE EFFECTS OF THE DURATION OF FEDERAL TAX REDUCTIONS: EXAMINING THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle

Real Business Cycle Models

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty

Determinants of Stock Market Performance in Pakistan

How To Find Out How Effective Stimulus Is

How Important Is the Stock Market Effect on Consumption?

ijcrb.com INTERDISCIPLINARY JOURNAL OF CONTEMPORARY RESEARCH IN BUSINESS AUGUST 2014 VOL 6, NO 4

Is there a revolution in American saving?

17. SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION II

2013 MBA Jump Start Program. Statistics Module Part 3

WORKING PAPER NO BENCHMARK REVISIONS AND THE U.S. PERSONAL SAVING RATE. Leonard Nakamura and Tom Stark Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

14.74 Lecture 16: Savings and Insurance: how villagers deal with risk

Univariate Regression

IT, Inventories and the Business Cycle

Forecasting in STATA: Tools and Tricks

Introduction to Regression and Data Analysis

Econometric Modelling for Revenue Projections

Influence of Aggressivenessand Conservativenessin Investing and Financing Policies on Performance of Industrial Firms in Kenya

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector

REAL BUSINESS CYCLE THEORY METHODOLOGY AND TOOLS

Investors and Central Bank s Uncertainty Embedded in Index Options On-Line Appendix

Business Cycles, Theory and Empirical Applications

Marginal Person. Average Person. (Average Return of College Goers) Return, Cost. (Average Return in the Population) (Marginal Return)

Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

MACROECONOMICS II INFLATION, UNEMPLOYMENT AND THE PHILLIPS CURVE

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract

Econometrics I: Econometric Methods

Credit Spending And Its Implications for Recent U.S. Economic Growth

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series.

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model

Chapter 9: Univariate Time Series Analysis

4. Simple regression. QBUS6840 Predictive Analytics.

MULTIPLE REGRESSION AND ISSUES IN REGRESSION ANALYSIS

Despite an unprecedented degree of monetary policy accommodation,

The Macrotheme Review A multidisciplinary journal of global macro trends

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Money and Public Finance

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Week TSX Index

1. What is the critical value for this 95% confidence interval? CV = z.025 = invnorm(0.025) = 1.96

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Determinants of student demand at Florida Southern College

Demographic Influence on the U.S. Demand for Beer Steve Spurry, Mary Washington College

Earnings Announcement and Abnormal Return of S&P 500 Companies. Luke Qiu Washington University in St. Louis Economics Department Honors Thesis

A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance

NCSS Statistical Software Principal Components Regression. In ordinary least squares, the regression coefficients are estimated using the formula ( )

THE U.S. HOUSEHOLD SAVINGS RATE AND CONSUMPTION 3 March 2009, additions 4 March see

Chapter 5 Estimating Demand Functions

Consumer Spending and the Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008 *

RELEVANT TO ACCA QUALIFICATION PAPER P3. Studying Paper P3? Performance objectives 7, 8 and 9 are relevant to this exam

8. Time Series and Prediction

Macroeconomics Series 2: Money Demand, Money Supply and Quantity Theory of Money

MULTIPLE REGRESSIONS ON SOME SELECTED MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES ON STOCK MARKET RETURNS FROM

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

Demand for Life Insurance in Malaysia

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

TEMPORAL CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN STOCK MARKET CAPITALIZATION, TRADE OPENNESS AND REAL GDP: EVIDENCE FROM THAILAND

Lecture 1: Asset pricing and the equity premium puzzle

Stock Returns and Equity Premium Evidence Using Dividend Price Ratios and Dividend Yields in Malaysia

The Impact of Privatization in Insurance Industry on Insurance Efficiency in Iran

5. Linear Regression

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

The effect of the Internet on regional integration: evidence from China

The Real Business Cycle Model

DOES A STRONG DOLLAR INCREASE DEMAND FOR BOTH DOMESTIC AND IMPORTED GOODS? John J. Heim, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, New York, USA

THE IMPACT OF EXCHANGE RATE VOLATILITY ON BRAZILIAN MANUFACTURED EXPORTS

IMPACT EVALUATION: INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE METHOD

Real Business Cycle Theory

Household Spending Response to the 2003 Tax Cut

Projections of Global Meat Production Through 2050

ER Volatility Forecasting using GARCH models in R

1. Portfolio Returns and Portfolio Risk

MGT 267 PROJECT. Forecasting the United States Retail Sales of the Pharmacies and Drug Stores. Done by: Shunwei Wang & Mohammad Zainal

Transcription:

New Estimates of the Fraction of People Who Consume Current Income Mark Senia Joe McGarrity Abstract: Using data from 1953-1986, Campbell and Mankiw (1989) estimate the fraction of consumers who consume their current income. They estimate their model on data through 1986. We find that after 1986 the estimate of the fraction of consumers who spend all of their current income drops by 51% when compared to the estimate from the earlier time period. These results suggest that after 1986 temporary tax cuts will be comparatively less successful and permanent tax cuts will be comparatively more successful. I. Introduction Campbell and Mankiw (1989) divided consumers into two groups, one follows consumption smoothing and the other follows the rule of thumb that consumers spend based on current income. Using data from 1953-1986, they estimate the fraction of people who consume current income. This paper estimates the model with data from 1953-2009. When the model is applied to data from 1987 to 2009, we find a 51% drop in the estimated coefficient that represents the percentage of consumers that consume their current income. II. Methodology Typically a representative consumer is used to explain aggregate consumption decisions. Campbell and Mankiw argue that aggregate consumption can be better explained with two types of consumers. One type of consumer consumes all of their current income. The other type spends according to the permanent income hypothesis (Friedman, 1957). This hypothesis states that a consumer will spend based on their long-term income expectations which arise from the consumer s physical and human capital. Consumers will smooth their consumption Economics & Business Journal: Inquiries & Perspectives 91 Volume 4 Number 1 October 2012

over their lifetime. Under the permanent income hypothesis, short term income changes will not impact consumption. In the Campbell and Mankiw model a fraction of income (λ) is allocated to individuals who consume their current income, while the remainder (1- λ) is allocated to individuals who consume their permanent income. Incomes of the two groups are denotedy 1t and Y 2t. It then follows that the total income is: Y t = Y 1t + Y 2t. Because the first group receives λ of total income and the second group receives (1- λ) of income, this implies that: Y 1t = λy t Y 2t = (1 λ) Y t. The first group consumes their current income while the second group obeys the permanent income hypothesis. C 1t = λδy t C 2t = (1 λ)ε t Using these facts, the change in aggregate consumption can be written as C t = C 1t + C 2t This can be rewritten as C t = λδy t + (1 λ)ε t. In this model the change in consumption is a weighted average of the change in current income and the unforecastable innovation in permanent income. A λ value close to zero would imply that the permanent income theory is approximately true. The model will reduce to the permanent income hypothesis when λ = 0. If λ is found to be large, this would imply the permanent income hypothesis is not true. The model is estimated by an instrumental variable approach. The model cannot be directly estimated using ordinary least squares since the error term ε t may be correlated withδy t. Instruments are used to find estimated values in the equation Δc y = μ + Δy t The main instruments chosen for computation are: Δy t 2,, Δy t 4 Δc t 2,, Δc t 4 Δi t 2,, Δi t 4 c t 2 y t 2 In this paper, we use sample ranges from the first quarter of 1953 to the last quarter of 2009. In the model y t is disposable personal income per capita in 1996 dollars. Consumption (c t ) is the measure of non-durables and services consumed per capita, in 1996 dollars. A quarterly average of three-month nominal Treasury bill rates (i t ) was also an instrument. The data for all three instruments was obtained from St. Louis Federal Reserve. Campbell and Mankiw s data was obtained from Data Resources, Inc. and is not publically available. Our data is publically available on the St. Louis Federal Reserve s web site. Following Campbell and Mankiw s specification, we take the natural logs of all variables. This was done because the relationship between consumption and income seem to be loglinear. Another correction is needed to deal with serial correlation. This correction is Inquiries & Perspectives 92 Volume 4 Number 1 October 2012

accomplished by starting with at least a lag of two periods in the model. The authors argue that if the permanent income hypothesis were to hold true, then consumption would be a random walk. III. Results The model was estimated in a two stage regression. The first stage regression produces results similar to Campbell and Mankiw s results when the model is run on the same sample period. In the first stage regression, Δc t was regressed against the instrumental variables which are indicated in the first column of Table 1. Δc t = α 0 + α 1 Δy t 2 + α 2 Δy t 3 + α 3 Δy t 4 + α 4 Δc t 2 + α 5 Δc t 3 + α 6 Δc t 4 + α 7 Δi t 2 + α 8 Δi t 3 + α 9 Δi t 4 + α 10 (c t 2 y t 2 ) The results of this regression can be seen in column 2 and 4 in Table 1. This was done for each of the two different time periods. The adjusted R square value for the 1953-1986 Δc t regression in Mankiw s Table 1 is 0.078, while the value obtained from our estimation is 0.089. The difference is likely due to the different sources of data. When expanded to the 1987-2009 time frame, the adjusted R square value for Δc t was found to be 0.243. The process was repeated for Δy t for which the results can be observed in columns 3 and 5 in Table 1. Δy t = β 0 + β 1 Δy t 2 + β 2 Δy t 3 + β 3 Δy t 4 + β 4 Δc t 2 + β 5 Δc t 3 + β 6 Δc t 4 + β 7 Δi t 2 + β 8 Δi t 3 + β 9 Δi t 4 + β 10 (c t 2 y t 2 ) The adjusted R square value for the Δy t regression from Campbell and Mankiw s Table 1 is 0.093, while the value in our Table 1 is 0.135. When the model was applied to the 1987-2009 time frame, the adjusted R square value for the Δy t regression was found to be 0.214. Next the predicted values obtained in the first regression were used for the second stage regression. In the second state regression, the predicted values found for Δc t and Δy t were used to estimate the equation Δc y = μ + λδy t. This was repeated for each of the two time periods. The results of this regression can be found in Table 2. Our λ estimate in the early time period is 0.382. In the 1987-2009 period, the λ estimate is 0.186. One interesting result of the regressions is that interest rate appears to have a more significant affect on consumption for the 1953-1986 estimate than in the 1987-2009 estimate. The t statistics for i t 2 and i t 4 in the 1953-1986 regression were -2.38 and -2.76 which are both significant at the 0.01 level. In the 1987-2009 regression, i t 2 and i t 4 were not significant at conventional levels. A major difference in the model over different time periods is the estimate of λ. This λ represents the fraction of people consuming their current income. In the model for 1953-1986, the estimate for λ = 0.382, while the estimate for the time frame 1987-2009 is λ = 0.186. This represents a 51% drop in the fraction of people consuming their current income. Inquiries & Perspectives 93 Volume 4 Number 1 October 2012

Table 1: First Stage Regression 1 2 3 4 5 1953-1986 1987-2009 Dependent variable = Δc t Δy t Δc t Δy t Name Constant 0.010 (2.99) 0.011 (1.86) 0.009 (1.70) 0.018 (1.45) Δy t 2 0.012 (0.22) -0.011 (-0.11) 0.045 (0.82) 0.296 (2.41) Δy t 3 0.044 (0.77) 0.053 (0.51) 0.034 (0.60) -0.212 (-1.64) Δy t 4 0.034 (0.60) -0.145 (-1.43) -0.024 (-0.43) -0.187 (-1.51) Δc t 2 0.129 (1.20) 0.003 (0.01) 0.158 (1.26) -0.278 (-0.98) Δc t 3 0.118 (1.08) 0.352 (1.79) 0.371 (2.70) 1.115 (3.59) Δc t 4-0.004 (-0.04) 0.454 (2.37) -0.013 (-0.10) -0.652 (-2.21) Δi t 2-0.008 (-2.38) -0.011 (-2.01).001 (0.56) -0.009 (-1.86) Δi t 3-0.001 (-0.42) 0.0005 (-0.08) 0.0005 (0.22) 0.014 (0.89) Δi t 4-0.008 (-2.76) -0.016 (-2.89) -0.002 (-0.84) 0.0002 (-0.047) c t 2 y t 2 0.025 (1.36) 0.049 (1.51) 0.036 (1.25) 0.064 (0.97) t-statistics in parenthesis Adjusted R Square 0.089 0.135 0.243 0.214 F-Statistic 2.319 3.101 3.922 3.477 Inquiries & Perspectives 94 Volume 4 Number 1 October 2012

Table 2: Second Stage Regression c t = λδy t + μ 1 2 3 1953-1986 1987-2009 Name Constant 0.005 (22.35) 0.005 (14.50) y t 0.382 0.186 (15.98) (4.28) Adjusted R Square 0.653 0.160 F-Statistic 255.22 18.303 Note: t-statistics in parenthesis Table 3: Summary Statistics 1953-1986 1987-2009 N Min. Max. Mean Std. Dev. N Min. Max. Mean Std. Dev. Δy t 136 -.0155.0457.0092.0091 92 -.0222.0266.0068.0085 Δc t 136 -.0087.0233.0089.0050 92 -.0061.0142.0066.0038 y t 136 0.0 0.0.0100.0040 92 -.0104.0152.0068.0046 c t 136.0040.014.0080.0019 92 -.0030.0107.0066.0021 Inquiries & Perspectives 95 Volume 4 Number 1 October 2012

A Chow test was performed on the model expanded over the entire range 1953-2009. The test determined that a structural break exists in the model around the year 1986. This break suggests that the estimated coefficients are not the same in the whole dataset. The model was then broken into two samples at the year 1986. The evidence suggests the fraction of people making decisions as if they were following the permanent income hypothesis is greater after 1986. This means in the second time frame people are more willing to consume based on their long term income expectations and not on their current income. Table 3 shows the summary statistics forδy t, Δc t, Δy t, and Δc t. It should be noted that the means of the variables in the first time periods are close to 30% higher than those in the second time period. The standard deviations are very similar in both time periods although the standard deviation for consumption is higher in the first time period. One possible reason for the significant change in consumption behavior may be explained by a change in demographics. Dynan, Edelberg, & Palumbo (2009) claim that demographics may in part explain why, over the past two decades, there has been a smaller response in aggregate consumption to changes in income. Another possible reason for the difference may be a difference in uncertainty. The first regression covered a period with much higher uncertainty and risk as illustrated by a higher volatility in inflation and GDP. Indeed, the later period has been widely referred to as the Great Moderation. IV. Implications The results in this paper have significant policy implications. When deciding between a tax rebate and a permanent tax cut to stimulate the economy, it would be important to choose the option that would increase consumption the most. A temporary tax rebate will have a smaller effect after 1986 when consumers are more willing to consume based on their long term income expectations. This implies that a tax rebate would have little immediate influence on consumption because it would be factored into a consumer s long term income expectations. A permanent tax cut would have a larger affect on consumption after 1986. Consumers after 1986 are more likely to make decisions based on long term income. In our estimates, we found that after 1986 approximately 18.6% of people will consume based on their current income. This finding is largely consistent with Shapiro and Slemrod (2003) when they find that 21.8 percent of people received a tax rebate in 2001 would increase their spending. Later work by Shapiro and Slemrod (2009) found that one-fifth of those polled said that the 2008 tax rebates would cause them to increase consumption. The finding that a permanent tax change will have a larger affect than a tax rebate is supported by the literature. Blinder (1981) found that a tax rebate will have only 38% of the impact of a permanent tax cut. Souleles (2002) also suggests that a consumer is more likely to increase consumption when income increases are small and spread out over time in contrast to one large lump sum. Inquiries & Perspectives 96 Volume 4 Number 1 October 2012

References Blinder, A.S. (1981) Temporary Income Taxes and Consumer Spending. Journal of Political Economy 89, 26-53. Campbell, John Y., and N. Gregory Mankiw. (1989) "Consumption, Income and Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence." NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989 4, 185-246. Dynan, Karen E., Wendy Edelberg, and Michael G. Palumbo. (2009) "The Effects of Population Aging on the Relationship among Aggregate Consumption, Saving, and Income." American Economic Review 99, 380-86. Friedman, Milton. (1957) A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Shapiro, Matthew D., and Joel Slemrod. (2003) Consumer Response to Tax Rebates. The American Economic Review. 93, 381-396. Shapiro, M.D., and Joel Slemrod. (2009) Did the 2008 Tax Rebates Stimulate Spending? American Economic Review 99, 274-379. Souleles, N.S. (2002) Consumer Response to the Reagan Tax Cuts. Journal of Public Economics 85, 99-120. Contact information: Mark Senia Department of Economics Conway, AR 72035 Corresponding author: Joe McGarrity Department of Economics Conway, AR 72035 joem@uca.edu Inquiries & Perspectives 97 Volume 4 Number 1 October 2012