Reforming the Tax System Lecture II: The Taxation of Savings. December 2015 Richard Blundell University College London



Similar documents
Noah Williams Economics 312. University of Wisconsin Spring Midterm Examination Solutions

The Real Business Cycle model

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

Lecture 1: The intertemporal approach to the current account

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

The Real Business Cycle Model

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

From Basic Research to Policy Recommendations: The Case for a Progressive Tax

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Chapter 22 Taxes on Savings

Optimal Age Specific Income Taxation

Optimal fiscal policy under commitment

New Dynamic Public Finance. Mikhail Golosov (Yale, New Economic School, and NBER) Aleh Tsyvinski (Yale, New Economic School, and NBER)

LONGEVITY AND ANNUITIES: AN INTRODUCTION

The Case for a Progressive Tax: From Basic Research to Policy Recommendations

TAXATION AND SAVINGS. Robin Boadway Queen s University Kingston, Canada. Day Six

OECD countries rely to varying degrees on

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Problem Set #3 Answer Key

ECON 305 Tutorial 7 (Week 9)

Paternalism vs Redistribution: Designing Retirement Savings Policies with Behavioral Agents

Consumption and Savings Decisions: A Two-Period Setting

China's Social Security Pension System and its Reform

Notes on Papers on Public Debt & Dynamic Public Finance

Taxation and Savings: A Survey

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Pareto gains from trade: a dynamic counterexample

Nonseparable Preferences and Optimal Social Security Systems

Dynamics of Small Open Economies

What do Aggregate Consumption Euler Equations Say about the Capital Income Tax Burden? *

Hurley, Chapter 7 (see also review in chapter 3)

THE EFFECTS OF TAXATION ON SAVINGS AND RISK TAKING

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey

Optimal Social Insurance Design: UI Benefit Levels

Tax By Design: The Mirrlees Review

Money and Public Finance

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

Class Notes, Econ 8801 Lump Sum Taxes are Awesome

Improving the Equity-Efficiency Trade-Off: Mandatory Savings Accounts for Social Insurance

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

ECON4620 Public Economics I Second lecture by DL

On the irrelevance of government debt when taxes are distortionary

Effective marginal tax rates on savings 1

2 Voluntary retirement module specification

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Chapter 4. Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

ECON Elements of Economic Analysis IV. Problem Set 1

Redistributive Taxation and Personal Bankruptcy in US States

Intermediate Microeconomics (22014)

Capital Income Taxation and the Mirrlees Review

THE IMPORTANCE OF INCENTIVES IN INFLUENCING PRIVATE RETIREMENT SAVING: KNOWN KNOWNS AND KNOWN UNKNOWNS

Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey

Income tax, consumption value of education, and the choice of educational type

Redistributive Taxation and Bankruptcy in US States

1 The Terrace, PO Box 3724, Wellington 6140 Tel: (04)

Pareto Efficient Income Taxation with Stochastic Abilities

Econ 116 Mid-Term Exam

TAXATION AND SAVING. B. DOUGLAS BERNHEIM Stanford University, Stanford, CA National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

Saving and the Demand for Protection Against Risk

Designing Tax Policy for Finland: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review and Comments on Peter s Presentation

Consumption, Saving, and Investment, Part 1

Since 1960's, U.S. personal savings rate (fraction of income saved) averaged 7%, lower than 15% OECD average. Why? Why do we care?

General Equilibrium Tax Model

Dynamics of current account in a small open economy

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

Inflation. Chapter Money Supply and Demand

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija

HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS

Labour markets. Spring Suppose workers can freely choose the amount of hours they work, wages are given, no unemployment.

Week 4 Market Failure due to Moral Hazard The Principal-Agent Problem

Unemployment Insurance under Moral Hazard and Limited Commitment: Public versus Private Provision

Redistributive Taxation and Personal Bankruptcy in US States

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Determinants of Social Discount Rate, general case

Optimal Income Taxation with Multidimensional Types

MA Macroeconomics 10. Growth Accounting

The Trick is to Live: Is the Estate Tax Social Security for the. Rich?

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

14.74 Lecture 16: Savings and Insurance: how villagers deal with risk

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

A Theory of Capital Controls As Dynamic Terms of Trade Manipulation

Dynamics of the current account in a small open economy microfounded model

Chapter 7 Externalities

Multiple Year Cost Calculations

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013)

Health Insurance and Retirement Incentives

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

How To Understand The Relationship Between A Country And The Rest Of The World

A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities

THE MARKET OF FACTORS OF PRODUCTION

Graduate Macroeconomics 2

The Economics of Consumer Credit

Real Business Cycle Models

Transcription:

Econ 3007 Economic Policy Analysis Reforming the Tax System Lecture II: The Taxation of Savings December 205 Richard Blundell niversity ollege London Teaching Resources at: http://www.ucl.ac.uk/~uctp39a/lect.html http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesreview

The Taxation of Savings Background readings (on moodle): Auerbach (2006) The hoice between Income and onsumption Taxes: A Primer, on website hapters 3 &4 of Mirrlees Review: Tax by Design Atkinson and Stiglitz (976), Journal of Public Economics 6, pp55 75 ; L (electronic) library.

Some Guiding Principles Individuals will have different preferences for saving and face different opportunities to engage in saving. In general, the tax system should be designed to enable choices to be based on trade-offs that reflect the underlying costs of moving productive resources across time that is, the opportunities for real investment. Economic efficiency arguments suggest that the trade-off individuals and households face for consuming tomorrow rather than today should reflect the return to investment in productive capacity in the economy The marginal rate of transformation of consumer goods the real interest rate.

Implications On this basis the tax system should allow individuals to make their consumption decisions in a way that reflects the true cost of the use productive resources over time between current consumption and investment. If we define the normal return to be the return on a safe investment, then the normal return reflects this trade-off. Taxing (or subsidizing) the normal return will distort the trade-off and is generally unwise.

Guiding Principles for the Taxation of Savings As a counter-example - if the decision to delay consumption tells us about an individual s earning capacity (e.g. it may be that clever people are patient), then taxing savers may be a useful tag enabling us to tax high-ability people with less distortion to labour supply. Remember in a Mirrlees tax model the government cannot observe true ability and can only tax income from earnings and from savings. If savings indicates a high ability high life-time earnings potential person, then taxing the return to savings may be optimal - that is high ability types are more patient. It may also be that savings and labour supply are directly linked.

Guiding Principles for the Taxation of Savings A good place to start considering this class of models is the Atkinson-Stiglitz theorem (976, Journal of Public Economics 6, 55 75 ) which states: when the available tax tools include nonlinear earnings taxes, differential taxation of first- and second-period consumption is not optimal if two key conditions are satisfied:. all consumers have preferences that are separable between consumption and labour, and 2. all consumers have the same (sub)utility function of consumption.

The Atkinson Stiglitz Result Model with two periods t and t2, with no uncertainty. Individual gets labor income Y L w.h at t (w wage rate, h labor supply), and chooses how much to consume and 2. Max (, 2 ) V(h) under budget constraint: 2 /(r) Y L. Period savings S Y L -, Period 2 capital income Y k (r)s 2, r rate of return ( marginal product of capital F K with production function F(K,L)) >>> taxing capital income Y k is like taxing the relative price of period 2 consumption 2

The Atkinson Stiglitz Result Atkinson-Stiglitz: under separable preferences: (, 2 ) -V(h), there is no point taxing capital income; it is more efficient to redistribute income by using solely a labor income tax t(y L ). With non-separable preferences: (, 2,h), it might make sense to tax less the goods that are complements with labor supply (say, tax less day care or baby sitters, and tax more vacations); but note this requires a lot of information on cross-derivatives. Implies: If second period leisure time is more complementary with consumption then it may make sense to tax capital income.

Guiding Principles for the Taxation of Savings Returning to the conditions (can be somewhat relaxed): The first condition states that the marginal benefit derived from consumption over the life-time should not depend on labour supply. The second requires all consumers to be similar in their desire to smooth consumption across their life-cycle and across potentially uncertain states of the world. The theorem refers to not differentially taxing first- and second-period consumptions. That is, a tax on consumption that is the same in both periods. With no uncertainty and borrowing at the safe rate this is equivalent to exempting interest income from taxation.

Guiding Principles for the Taxation of Savings It is differential tax rates that matter for efficiency by introducing a wedge between the intertemporal marginal rate of substitution (MRS) and the intertemporal marginal rate of transformation (MRT) between consumer goods in different periods. Two ways of having differential taxation of consumption in the two periods are:. through different tax rates on consumption in the two periods and 2. through taxation of the capital income that is received as part of financing second-period consumption out of firstperiod earnings.

Guiding Principles for the Taxation of Savings That is, if taxes should not distort the timing of consumption (if the MRS should equal the MRT), then the optimum is not consistent with taxing these consumer goods other than with equal rates, and thus inconsistent with taxing saving at the margin. The theorem extends to having multiple periods of consumption.

A Simple Two-Period Model without ncertainty onsider a two period model in which an individual receives a fixed income Y (endowment) in period and allocates this between consumption and 2 in periods and 2 respectively. Savings Y - earn a known rate of return r, with the full payout consumed in period 2. All individuals can borrow or lend at this risk-free interest rate, which is determined outside the model (perfect capital market; small open economy). The individual cares only about consumption, and discounts period 2 utility at the discount rate ρ (rate of time preference).

A Two-Period Model without ncertainty In the absence of any tax, the individual chooses to maximise V ( ) ( ) ρ 2 subject to 2 (r)(y - ) with Y fixed.

Writing we obtain the familiar Euler equation for the intertemporal allocation of consumption ( ) ( ) ) )( ( Y r V ρ. 0 2 2 ρ ρ r r V A Two-Period Model without ncertainty

Pure Income Tax A tax on income at the constant rate t implies tax payments of ty on the endowment income in period, and tr[(-t)y - ] on the interest income in the second period. The budget constraint becomes 2 ((-t)r)[(-t)y - ] and the first order condition becomes: indicating that, by lowering the rate of return, the tax on capital income distorts the inter-temporal allocation of consumption. ρ ρ ) ( 0 ) ( 2 2 r t r t V

Pure onsumption Tax onsumption i in each period i is taxed at the constant rate τ, so that a consumption of i requires an outlay of O i i τ i i ( τ). Savings are now Y -O, generating an outlay in period 2 of O 2 (r)(y -O ) and consumption in period 2 of 2 O 2 /( τ). The first order condition becomes: indicating that a tax on consumption levied at a constant rate does not distort the inter-temporal allocation. ρ ρ τ 0 2 2 r r O V

Income Tax with Interest Exemption An income tax that exempts interest income implies a tax payment of ty on the endowment income in period only. This a lump sum tax that does not depend on the individual s consumption choice. The budget constraint is now 2 (r)[(-t)y - ] and the first order condition is again and, as expected, there is no distortion to the intertemporal consumption decision equivalent to consumption tax in this setting. ρ ρ 0 2 2 r r V

ncertain Returns Income Tax with Exemption for the Risk-free Rate of Return on Assets Income from capital is now taxed in period 2 at rate t, with an exemption for the risk-free rate of return on assets. Income from the safe asset is thus not taxed. If the risky asset pays the high rate of return, there is a tax charge of t(r H - r f ) on each unit held. Symmetrically, if the risky asset pays the low rate of return, there is a tax rebate of t(r L - r f ) on each unit held. Exercise: Show this is equivalent to a consumption tax.

Key Arguments for Taxing the Return to Saving Rents: If returns to saving represents pure rents, for example on a holding of land or a monopoly ownership of some resource, then income from savings should be taxed. But by how much? Notice with uncertainty we only exempt tax on the normal return on a safe asset, that is the risk free return. Excess returns above this are taxed. onsequently rents are captured as excess returns when an allowance for interest payments at the safe rate is made.

Key Arguments for Taxing the Normal Return to Saving Impatience and cognitive ability: In experimental psychology there seems to be wide acceptance that higher ability individuals are more patient. This gives the high-skill consumers a relatively stronger preference for consumption in the second period of life, and therefore the high-skill save more as a proportion of income than the low-skill. see arguments in Banks and Diamond (Mirrlees Review in moodle)

Key Arguments for Taxing the Normal Return to Saving Impatience and cognitive ability: If the rate of discount varies in a predictable way with productive ability then this give rise to an optimal tax on the return to risk-free saving. The tax on second-period consumption can be achieved by taxing observed saving, and this will implicitly tax the high-ability types. For example, for further reading see apital Income Taxes with Heterogeneous Discount Rates (Johannes Spinnewijn and Peter Diamond) - AEJ: Economic Policy 3(4), November 20

Key Arguments for Taxing the Normal Return to Saving ncertain earnings ability/individual productivity: Suppose an individual is uncertain about his or her ability (productivity) next period They will tend to save too much. That is they will save because they worry they maybe low ability (have low productivity) next period If they to have high ability/high productivity they will have saved too much and consequently will not work so much. Less than optimal for a high ability/productivity worker. In this case a positive tax on the return to capital/taxation of saving can be optimal see the discussion of uncertain earnings, see section, page 8 in Banks and Diamond (Mirrlees Review).