National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union Andrew K. Rose and Eric van Wincoop*



Similar documents
Trade, Finance, Specialization and Synchronization: Sensitivity Analysis

The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU. Inter-American Development Bank

The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU

C ountries select particular exchange rate

Trade Costs,

Do Currency Unions Affect Foreign Direct Investment? Evidence from US FDI Flows into the European Union

CANADA SHOULD OPT FOR COMMON CURRENCY WITH THE US OTHERS WILL FOLLOW. Jerzy (Jurek) Konieczny Wilfrid Laurier University

AN ESTIMATE OF THE EFFECT OF COMMON CURRENCIES ON TRADE AND INCOME* Jeffrey Frankel and Andrew Rose

Currency Unions and Irish External Trade. Christine Dwane Trinity College Dublin. Philip R. Lane, IIIS, Trinity College Dublin & CEPR

Has the Euro Increased Trade?

Modelling multilateral trade resistance in a gravity model with exchange rate regimes * Christopher Adam (University of Oxford) 5 AUGUST 2007 ABSTRACT

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix

Trade Intensity and Business Cycle Synchronization: Are Developing Countries any Different?

U.S. International Business Travel: Its Impact on U.S. Merchandise Exports. by Maksim Belenkiy and David Riker

FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina

The effect of the Internet on regional integration: evidence from China

Inflation. Chapter Money Supply and Demand

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

Commentary: What Do Budget Deficits Do?

Impact (%)

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits

Measuring long-run equilibrium exchange rates using standardized products with different specifications

Keywords: empirical; panel; union; country; exchange rate; volatility; gravity; model; data.

THE CONTRIBUTION OF ECONOMIC FREEDOM TO WORLD ECONOMIC GROWTH,

What Drives a Successful Fiscal Consolidation?

Export Pricing and Credit Constraints: Theory and Evidence from Greek Firms. Online Data Appendix (not intended for publication) Elias Dinopoulos

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics THE CURRENCY DENOMINATION OF SOVEREIGN DEBT

European Financial Market Integration and German Cross Border Portfolio Flows

Infrastructure, Geographical Disadvantage, Transport Costs and Trade

A Panel Data Analysis of Bangladesh s Trade: The Gravity Model Approach

Integrated Resource Plan

Impact of Mexico's Peso-Dollar Exchange Rate on Texas Metropolitan Area Retail Sales

The Impact of U.S. Economic Growth on the Rest of the World: How Much Does It Matter?

The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share. by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY)

A Note on Extensive Import Margins and Technology Adoption

Real income (Y)

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract

The Gravity Equation and the Interdependency of Trade Costs and International Trade

2. Discuss the implications of the interest rate parity for the exchange rate determination.

The Euro s Impact on France s Trade with Adopting and Non-adopting Countries. Julie DeRoo

Chapter 5 Estimating Demand Functions

STOCK MARKET CORRELATIONS AND CROSS-EQUITY HOLDINGS RADOSLAV I. ILIEV

Borders, Common Currencies, Trade, and Welfare: What Can We Learn from the Evidence?

An International Look at the Growth of Modern Finance ONLINE APPENDIX

Imagine you are planning a trip to France

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

Economic Growth and Government Size. Mark Pingle Professor of Economics University of Nevada, Reno. and

2. Linear regression with multiple regressors

Identifying the Relationship Between Trade and Exchange Rate Volatility

Optimal Currency Areas

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression

United States-China Trade: Where are the Exports? Barry Bosworth Susan Collins Aaron Flaaen

DO HIGH INTERNATIONAL TELECOM RATES BUY TELECOM SECTOR GROWTH? An Empirical Investigation of the Sender-Pays Rule

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

Mohammad Mafizur Rahman, PhD School of Accounting, Economics and Finance

Used-Clothing Donations. and Apparel Production in Africa

The Internet and International Trade in Services

EXTERNAL DEBT AND LIABILITIES OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES. Mark Rider. Research Discussion Paper November Economic Research Department

MGE#12 The Balance of Payments

Do Taxes Really Affect the Consumption of Cigarettes?

Measuring Unilateral Market Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets: The California Market,

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

Andrés López and Eugenia Orlicki 1

Credit Contraction and International Trade: Evidence from Chilean Exporters *

Gravity Redux: Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data

The Economic Importance of the Country of Origin Principle in the Proposed Services Directive. Final report

Discussion Papers in Economics

1 Multiple Choice - 50 Points

VOLATILITY AND DEVIATION OF DISTRIBUTED SOLAR

The impact of exports on economic growth: It s the market. form

The Elasticity of Export Demand for U.S. Cotton

How Much Equity Does the Government Hold?

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

Aspects of Canadian and US Business Cycles

BUSINESS OCR LEVEL 3 CAMBRIDGE TECHNICAL. Cambridge TECHNICALS INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS CERTIFICATE/DIPLOMA IN F/502/5502 LEVEL 3 UNIT 22

Inequality, Mobility and Income Distribution Comparisons

Cash in advance model

Statement by Dean Baker, Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research (

ELASTICITY OF LONG DISTANCE TRAVELLING

EC201 Intermediate Macroeconomics. EC201 Intermediate Macroeconomics Problem Set 1 Solution

Comments on The Challenges Facing Currency Usage: Will the Traditional. Medium be Able to Resist Competition from the New Technologies?

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy

The relationships between stock market capitalization rate and interest rate: Evidence from Jordan

Extended gravity model of Polish trade. Empirical analysis with panel data methods

Monetary Policy Bank of Canada

THE EMU AND GERMAN CROSS BORDER PORTFOLIO FLOWS

The Gravity Model: Derivation and Calibration

Chapter 4 The Gravity Model in International Trade

Learning Objectives. Essential Concepts

Lecture 3: The Theory of the Banking Firm and Banking Competition

Price Dispersion. Ed Hopkins Economics University of Edinburgh Edinburgh EH8 9JY, UK. November, Abstract

Basic Concepts in Research and Data Analysis

IMF Institute. The Welfare Analysis of a Free Trade Zone: Intermediate Goods and the Asian Tigers 1

Developing a model to identify favorable export markets


CHAPTER 15 EXCHANGE-RATE ADJUSTMENTS AND THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

A New Dataset of Labour Market Reform/Rigidity Indexes for Up to 145 Countries since 1960: LAMRIG

Australian Dollars Exchange Rate and Gold Prices: An Interval Method Analysis

Transcription:

National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union Andrew K. Rose and Eric van Wincoop* Revised: December 18, 2000. Comments Welcome Andrew K. Rose Eric van Wincoop Haas School of Business Federal Reserve Bank of New York University of California 33 Liberty St Berkeley, CA 94720-1900 New York, NY 10045-0001 Tel: (510) 642-6609 Tel: (212) 720-5497 Fax: (510) 642-4700 Fax: (212) 720-6831 E-mail: arose@haas.berkeley.edu E-mail: eric.vanwincoop@ny.frb.org http://www.haas.berkeley.edu/~arose/ http://www.ny.frb.org/rmaghome/ Abstract National money is a barrier to international trade. Accordingly, currency unions have lower trade barriers, more trade, and higher welfare. This paper uses empirical gravity models to quantify these effects using a large panel data set. We estimate that trade barriers associated with national borders are halved when countries join a currency union, significantly raising trade and welfare. EMU may lead to an increase in euroland s trade of over 50%, with comparable numbers for Mexican dollarization. JEL Classification Numbers: F15, F33 Keywords: common, EMU, dollarization, empirical, panel, gravity, model, data, model. To be presented at the American Economic Association Meeting session on Currency Unions January 6, 2001. This is a MS Word 2000 document.

National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union Andrew K. Rose and Eric van Wincoop Europeans are proceeding with Economic and Monetary Union (EMU); a number of countries in the Americas are pursuing dollarization. Why? Conventional wisdom is that the costs are high, since members of currency unions cannot employ domestic monetary policy to smooth business cycles. More intriguingly, most economists think that the economic benefits from currency union are low. We argue below that conventional wisdom may be wrong, since national money seems to be a significant barrier to international trade in the data. Currency unions lower these monetary barriers to trade and are thus associated with higher trade and welfare; we estimate EMU will cause European trade to rise by over 50%. The benefits of trade created by currency union may swamp any costs of foregoing independent monetary policy. 1. Just Do It What is the effect of currency unions on international trade? One way to answer this question would be to examine trade patterns before and after countries join or leave currency unions. Unfortunately such time-series experiments are rare; currency unions are typically longlived and stable. Nevertheless, many countries are actually in currency unions. Andrew Rose (2000) provides a long list of currency unions and exploits this cross-sectional variation to estimate the effect of currency unions on trade. International trade is affected by a host of considerations, above and beyond any effect of a common currency. We account for these influences by estimating an empirical gravity equation. In a standard gravity equation, trade between a pair of countries is a negative function 1

of the distance between the countries and a positive function of their combined GDPs. We add a number of additional effects to this standard specification, including: the combined GDPs per capita of the countries; whether the countries are landlocked, share a common language, land border, or colonizer, belong to a common regional free trade agreement (FTA); and so forth. There is a special control for geographically disparate areas of the same nation (such as France and its overseas departments). Further details and the data set itself are available online. To all this, we add a dummy variable that is one if the two countries use the same currency, and zero otherwise. Currency unions occur where: a) one of the countries does not issue its own currency and uses that of another (e.g., Panama), and b) in multilateral currency unions (e.g., the African CFA franc zones). Table 1 reports OLS results using data at five-year intervals between 1970 and 1995 covering almost 200 countries and 98% of all international trade. The first column includes time-effects; the second column removes a few controversial controls and adds country-effects (we discuss the rationalization for this below). The coefficients are sensible and precisely estimated: more distant countries trade less, as do countries with larger land areas and land-locked countries. Larger and richer countries trade more; so do countries with common languages, land borders, trade agreements, and colonial histories. Further, the equations fit the data well, explaining around two-thirds of the variation in trade. Thus we are searching for the currency union effect in the context of an empirical model that performs admirably (certainly compared with most econometric models). ----- Table 1 around here ----- The point estimates of the currency union effect indicate that two countries that use the same currency trade more. Lots more. Since exp(1.38) 3.97, the estimate without country- 2

fixed effects indicates that currency union is associated with an increase in trade of almost four hundred percent. The effect is statistically significant; the robust t-statistic is 7.4. This despite the presence of eleven other controls (the least significant of which has a t-statistic of 2.6)! Adding country effects reduces both the economic and statistical impact of the currency union effect, but it remains economically large (a trade effect of over 230%) and statistically significant (the t-statistic is 4.6). Since most currency union members are small, poor or remote, only about 1% of the observations are members of currency unions. Still, the paucity of observations does not appear to prevent them from having a strong and identifiable effect. National money seems to be a significant trade barrier. Rose (2000) provides extensive sensitivity analysis. The results do not depend on the exact way that the equation is specified or estimated, or the precise way that the variables are measured. Cutting the sample in different ways does not change the thrust of the results. An extensive search for omitted variables which might lead one to conclude incorrectly that currency unions affect trade when it is really some third factor that matters turned up nothing. Reverse causality also does not explain away the findings; there is little evidence in the political science literature that countries join currency unions to increase trade, and instrumental variables only increase the impact of currency unions on trade. In all, some fifty different perturbations of the basic model yield no smoking gun. The effect of currency unions on trade remains large and significant throughout. A currency union should stimulate trade somewhat, since one money is more efficient than two as both unit of account and medium of exchange. The real question is: why is the 3

impact so large? In a world with derivative markets (at least for developed countries), it is hard to believe that lower transactions costs could lead trade to rise so much. There are two ways to proceed. One can doubt the estimation results. Despite Rose s extensive search, there may still be some omitted factor that drives countries to both participate in currency unions and to trade more. Graduate students take note! Another tack is to take a harder look at the empirical model. James Anderson and Eric van Wincoop (2000), hereafter AvW, derive a simple theoretical gravity equation that easily lends itself to interpretation and estimation. There are four advantages to using their structural approach. First, one can use the model to investigate the impact of a currency union among any set of countries, even those that have never been in a currency union. This is critical; without a structural model one may question the relevance of pre-emu currency unions (which consist of small or poor countries) when considering the impact of EMU. Second, it provides an estimate of the tariff-equivalent of the national monetary barrier. Third, the model provides an explicit welfare metric. Finally, it may lead to a more accurate estimate of the impact of currency unions on trade. 2. We Try Harder Adopting the assumptions of complete specialization and identical constant elasticity of substitution (CES) preferences that are central to the previous theoretical gravity literature, AvW obtain a simple and intuitive equation: x ij = (y i y j /y W )(t ij /P i P j ) 1-σ (1) 4

where: x ij is the nominal value of exports from i to j, y i is the nominal GDP of country i, y W is the nominal value of world output, σ is the elasticity of substitution between the countries goods, t ij is the gross price-markup due to trade costs, and P i is i s multilateral trade resistance, a price index that depends positively on trade barriers between i and all of its trading partners (not just j). Multilateral resistance can be solved as a function of all bilateral trade barriers, {t ij }. In the model, trade between a pair of countries depends on their bilateral trade barrier relative to average trade barriers with all trade partners. According to the theory, each region produces a fixed quantity of goods which have to be sold somewhere in the world (analogous to the assumption of fixed factor supplies commonly made in trade theory). More goods will be sold to a region with which the exporter has a relatively low trade barrier. The theory has an intuitive implication for the impact of currency unions on trade flows. The stronger the level of pre-union trade among the members of a currency union, the smaller the percentage increase in trade among currency union members. If trade barriers are reduced among a set of countries that already trade a lot with each other, multilateral trade resistance will drop a lot and relative trade resistance will fall little. The drop in multilateral resistance of member countries reduces the impact on trade. Pre-union trade levels can be high either because the countries have relatively low preunion bilateral barriers (e.g. due to proximity or a regional trade agreement), or because the overall size of the union is large. These considerations imply a smaller effect of EMU on bilateral trade flows than most other currency unions. Existing currency unions, such as the East Caribbean Currency Area, are small and therefore imply a large effect on trade flows. We expect a smaller percentage increase in trade when Mexico or Canada dollarizes than when Argentina dollarizes, as Argentina trades less with the US than Canada or Mexico. 5

A rise in trade among members of the currency union implies a corresponding drop in trade with other countries and within member countries. That is, the model implies trade diversion as well as trade creation. But there is a positive welfare effect because fewer resources are wasted on trade costs. This is reflected in lower multilateral resistance; the price index P i falls. Welfare, as measured by the CES consumption index, can be shown to be approximately proportional to (1/P i ) 2. The more countries trade with each other before joining the union, the larger is the welfare benefit from joining the currency union, but the smaller the percentage increase in trade among union members. That is, welfare rises the most in currency unions where trade rises the least. We estimate the AvW model using a linear combination of the controls in Table 1 (other than land area and the GDP controls) for the bilateral trade barrier t ij ; details are available online. We estimate the model with country-fixed effects in place of the country-specific multilateral resistance terms. We use 1980 and 1990 data for a set of 143 countries for which we have complete bilateral data, which is necessary to solve for the impact of currency unions on multilateral resistance and trade. The currency union coefficient remains large and significant at.91, with a robust standard error of.18. The theory tells us that this is an estimate of [(σ 1) ln m], where (m-1) is the tariff equivalent of the national monetary barrier. If we use David Hummels (2000) estimate of σ =5, the tariff-equivalent of the monetary barrier to trade is estimated to be 26%! While larger values of σ reduce this estimate, for almost any value of σ the monetary barrier accounts for a little over half of the AvW estimate of the total national border barrier. The.91 estimate implies that the currency union is estimated to raise bilateral trade by around 250% (exp(.91) 2.48), ignoring the effect on multilateral trade resistance. But this is 6

warranted only in the unlikely case when there is a negligible amount of pre-union trade inside the currency union. To estimate the effect of currency unions on trade more realistically, we need to incorporate multilateral resistance effects. We do that in the first column of Table 2 for a number of actual and hypothetical unions. The theory allows us to estimate the effects of currency union for any set of countries, even if they have never been in one. The only assumption made is that the reduction in bilateral trade barriers for union members is the same as that for existing currency unions. We tabulate the average percentage change of trade among countries in the union, along with its standard error. 1 ----- Table 2 around here ----- The trade-creating effects of currency union were large in Table 1; the effects are smaller in Table 2. Instead of EMU causing trade to rise inside euroland by 400% or 250%, it is estimated to rise by 58% for current euroland members. Evidently taking multilateral resistance into account makes the effects appreciably smaller. The trade-creating effects of currency unions are smaller in Table 2; but the effects are large. (They are large even after dividing by two.) They vary somewhat depending on the exact perturbation of the currency union, but none are small, consistent with Jeffrey Frankel and Rose, 2000. These large effects also characterize the dollarization scenarios. The last column of Table 2 reports the effect of currency unions on the welfare of their members, measured by the average percentage increase in the consumption index, (assuming σ=5). Τhe welfare increases are large. This is particularly the case for EMU and a North- American currency union, where the welfare gains are in excess of 10%. 3. The Real Thing 7

The case for currency unions is stronger than commonly considered. The cost of foregoing independent monetary policy may be low. Even perfectly effective monetary policy has a small effect if the welfare costs of business cycles are small. Frankel and Rose (1998) argue that business cycles may become more synchronized across countries because of currency union, further lowering the opportunity cost of national monetary policy. Further, currency union may be an efficient institutional arrangement to handle credibility problems, Alberto Alesina and Robert Barro (2000). But the thrust of this paper has been to estimate the real benefits of currency union. Currency union reduces trade barriers associated with national borders, leading to substantial increases in both trade and welfare. That is, a national currency seems to be a significant barrier to trade. Reducing these barriers through currency unions like EMU or dollarization in the Americas will thus result in increased international trade. Our empirical work indicates that this effect may be large, in excess of 50% for EMU. It will be unexpected. And it will be beneficial. Eliminating the monetary barrier to trade brings benefits for consumers possibly in the form of more currency unions. 8

References Alesina, Alberto and Robert J. Barro Currency Unions National Bureau of Economic Research (Cambridge, MA) Working Paper No. 7927, September 2000. Anderson, James E. and Eric van Wincoop Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle Working paper, Boston College, 2000. Frankel, Jeffrey A. and Andrew K. Rose The Endogeneity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria Economic Journal 1998, (449), pp. 1009-1025. Frankel, Jeffrey A. and Andrew K. Rose An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth National Bureau of Economic Research (Cambridge, MA) Working Paper No 7857, August 2000. Hummels, David Toward a Geography of Trade Costs Working Paper, Purdue University, 2000. Rose, Andrew K. One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common Currencies on Trade Economic Policy, 2000, (30), pp. 7-45. 9

Table 1: Impact of Currency Union on International Trade, 1970-1995 Currency Union Dummy 1.38 (.19) Log Distance -1.06 (.03) Log Product Real.94 GDP (.01) Common Language.56 Dummy (.06) Common Land.63 Border Dummy (.12) Free Trade 1.09 Agreement Dummy (.10) Common Colonizer.41 Dummy (.08) Ex-Colony/ 1.97 Colonizer Dummy (.13) Political Union.95 Dummy (.37) Log Product Real.48 GDP/capita (.02) Number landlocked -.32 (.04) Log of Land Area -.15 Product (.01).86 (.19) -1.31 (.03) 1.06 (.04).48 (.06).30 (.13).46 (.12).68 (.08) 1.74 (.13).81 (.32) RMSE 1.97 1.74 R 2.64.72 Observations 31,101 31,101 Time Effects Time, Country Effects Regressand is log of bilateral trade in real American dollars at 5-year intervals. OLS estimates; robust standard errors in parentheses. 10

Table 2: Impact of Currency Unions on Trade and Welfare using Anderson-van Wincoop % Trade Increase EMU for current 58 (11) members (12) EMU + Greece 59 (12) EMU + UK 44 (9) EMU for all (15) 40 EU members (8) Argentina 132 dollarizes (37) Ecuador dollarizes 106 (26) Mexico dollarizes 53 (13) Canada dollarizes 38 (9) Mexico and Canada 27 dollarize (8) New Zealand + 125 Australia (35) Israel + Palestine 62 (12) Existing currency 91 unions (22) World monetary 10 union (2) % Welfare Increase 11.1 (3.9) 11.1 (3.0) 13.8 (3.6) 14.4 (3.8) 1.7 (0.5) 4.5 (1.4) 12.4 (3.8) 15.3 (4.3) 18.4 (5.3) 2.0 (0.6) 10.1 (2.9) 5.0 (1.2) 21.3 (5.1) Standard errors recorded in parentheses. 11

Notes * Rose is B.T. Rocca Jr. Professor of International Business, University of California, Berkeley CA 94720, NBER Research Associate, and CEPR Research Fellow. Van Wincoop is Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New York NY 10045. The data sets and a current version of this paper are available at http://haas.berkeley.edu/~arose. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. 1 More precisely, the exponential of the change in the average natural logarithm of trade among all country-pairs in the currency union. Trade and welfare numbers for Palestine refer to the GDP weighted average for Gaza and the West Bank. 12