HOW DOES FAMILY INCOME DICTATE THE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION BEHAVIOR OF MARRIED WOMEN?



Similar documents
Education and Wage Differential by Race: Convergence or Divergence? *

Women s Earnings and Income

MOMS AND JOBS: Trends in Mothers Employment and Which Mothers Stay Home

The Life-Cycle Motive and Money Demand: Further Evidence. Abstract

POVERTY AND THE EARNED INCOME TAX CREDIT

Determining Future Success of College Students

Effect of Race on Married Women s Retirement Planning

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF UBC FACULTY SALARIES: INVESTIGATION OF

Are Women Opting Out? Debunking the Myth

A Gender Reversal On Career Aspirations Young Women Now Top Young Men in Valuing a High-Paying Career

Employer-Provided Health Insurance and Labor Supply of Married Women

is paramount in advancing any economy. For developed countries such as

Household division of labor and cross-country differences in household formation rates

An Analysis of the Health Insurance Coverage of Young Adults

The Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) is the largest federal

How Equal Pay for Working Women would Reduce Poverty and Grow the American Economy*

The Effect of Social and Demographic Factors on Life Insurance Demand in Croatia

Social Security: Vital to Retirement Security for 35 Million Women and Men

Why Laura isn t CEO. Marianne Bertrand March 2009

Income Sustainability through Educational Attainment

Business Cycles and Divorce: Evidence from Microdata *

Division of Economics A.J. Palumbo School of Business Administration and McAnulty College of Liberal Arts Duquesne University Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Individual Retirement Accounts and Saving

COMPARISONS OF CUSTOMER LOYALTY: PUBLIC & PRIVATE INSURANCE COMPANIES.

Marriage and divorce: patterns by gender, race, and educational attainment

"Income Splitting Among the Self-Employed"

Methodology For Calculating Damages in the Victim Compensation Fund

Giving Secondary Earners a Tax Break: A Proposal to Help Low- and Middle-Income Families

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Payroll Taxes and the Decision to be Self-Employed

Regression Analysis of the Relationship between Income and Work Hours

Percentage of women in U.S. labor force. Percentage of women in U.S. labor force. Population of adult women in the United States

Effects of Demographic and Educational Changes on the Labor Markets of Brazil and Mexico

Is the person a permanent immigrant. A non permanent resident. Does the person identify as male. Person appearing Chinese

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 17 - Income distribution and Welfare programs Welfare policy in the United States Motivations - relative

MULTIPLE REGRESSION WITH CATEGORICAL DATA

Demographic Analysis of the Salt River Pima-Maricopa Indian Community Using 2010 Census and 2010 American Community Survey Estimates

Remarriage in the United States

The traditional work schedule for an

Number, Timing, and Duration of Marriages and Divorces: 2009

Changes in Family Health Insurance Coverage for Small and Large Firm Workers and Dependents: Evidence from 1995 to 2005

Saving and Life Insurance Holdings at Boston University A Unique Case Study

Working Beyond Retirement-Age

Enrollment Projections for Nebraska s Medicaid Insurance for Workers with Disabilities (Medicaid Buy-In Program) Mary G. McGarvey, Ph.D.

Retirement Savings Of Private And Public Sector Employees: A Comparative Study Swarn Chatterjee, University of Georgia, Athens, USA

TAX POLICY, LUMP-SUM PENSION DISTRIBUTIONS, AND HOUSEHOLD SAVING ANGELA E. CHANG *

Kevin E. Cahill, Analysis Group, Inc. Michael D. Giandrea, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Joseph F. Quinn, Boston College

Can Annuity Purchase Intentions Be Influenced?

When Will the Gender Gap in. Retirement Income Narrow?

Full report - Women in the labour market

center for retirement research

United States

Male and Female Marriage Returns to Schooling

Paid and Unpaid Labor in Developing Countries: an inequalities in time use approach

CENTER FOR LABOR MARKET STUDIES

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Comparing the Labor Market Return to An Associate Degree and to A Bachelor s Degree

The Loss in Efficiency from Using Grouped Data to Estimate Coefficients of Group Level Variables. Kathleen M. Lang* Boston College.

East-West Migration and Gender: Is there a Double Disadvantage vis-à-vis Stayers?

Using the National Longitudinal Survey

How To Calculate Export Earnings

Gender Differences in Employed Job Search Lindsey Bowen and Jennifer Doyle, Furman University

ADP Annual Health Benefits Report

DOES LIFE INSURANCE PROMOTE ENTREPRENEURSHIP? Lisa L. Verdon Department of Economics College of Wooster (330)

LECTURE: HEALTH INSURANCE AND LABOR MARKETS HILARY HOYNES UC DAVIS EC230 OUTLINE OF LECTURE: 1. Introduction and background

Women s Participation in Education and the Workforce. Council of Economic Advisers

Employment in the United States is recovering slowly from the

Where Supply Meets Demand: Women in Diesel Mechanics

THE CONTRIBUTION OF ECONOMIC FREEDOM TO WORLD ECONOMIC GROWTH,

Why Do Rich People Buy Life Insurance? By Lisa L. Verdon College of Wooster. January Abstract

Statistics 104 Final Project A Culture of Debt: A Study of Credit Card Spending in America TF: Kevin Rader Anonymous Students: LD, MH, IW, MY

MICHIGAN EARNED INCOME TAX CREDIT Tax Year 2013

Students Wage and Employment Expectations. Andrew J.A Dyck Supervisor: Ehsan Latif Thompson Rivers University

Expansion of Higher Education, Employment and Wages: Evidence from the Russian Transition

Nonprofit pay and benefits: estimates from the National Compensation Survey

HELP Interest Rate Options: Equity and Costs

Employment-Based Health Insurance: 2010

THE IMPACT OF CHILDHOOD HEALTH AND COGNITION ON PORTFOLIO CHOICE

Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance. Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER

A HAND UP How State Earned Income Tax Credits Help Working Families Escape Poverty in Summary. By Joseph Llobrera and Bob Zahradnik

The Interaction of Workforce Development Programs and Unemployment Compensation by Individuals with Disabilities in Washington State

1 PEW RESEARCH CENTER

Gender Wage Gap Accounting: the Role of Selection Bias

State of Working Britain

Introduction to Regression and Data Analysis

DOES MORTALITY DIFFER BETWEEN PUBLIC AND PRIVATE SECTOR WORKERS?

The Family Tax Cut. Ottawa, Canada 17 March

ONLINE APPENDIX Education Choices and Returns to Schooling: Mothers and Youths Subjective Expectations and their Role by Gender.

The Demand for Financial Planning Services 1

Old-Age and Survivors Insurance: Insured Workers and Their Representation in Claims

Predicting the Performance of a First Year Graduate Student

An update on the level and distribution of retirement savings

Betty Gray Community College Scholarship Program Evaluation

AN ANALYSIS OF UNEMPLOYMENT TRENDS AMONG IEEE U.S. MEMBERS. Laura Langbein, Ph.D.

11. Analysis of Case-control Studies Logistic Regression

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Loss of Future Income in the Case of Personal Injury of a Child: Parental Influence on a Child s Future Earnings. Lawrence M. Spizman and John Kane*

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

What It s Worth: Field of Training and Economic Status in 2009

Transcription:

HOW DOES FAMILY INCOME DICTATE THE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION BEHAVIOR OF MARRIED WOMEN? A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences at Georgetown University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Public Policy in Public Policy By Qiuchi Hua Washington, DC April 15, 2014

Copyright 2014 by Qiuchi Hua All Rights Reserved ii

HOW DOES FAMILY INCOME DICTATE THE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION BEHAVIOR OF MARRIED WOMEN? Thesis Advisor: Robert Bednarzik, Ph.D. ABSTRACT This paper analyzes the relationship between labor force participation of married women and family income. This study tests the hypothesis that in the United States, the probability of becoming a full-time housewife is positively related to family income. Nowadays, many U.S. women face the family-work decision after marriage. Many married women found that they can create more values at home than working in the labor market. This study analyzes how much family income influences married women s decisions on participating in the labor market. This thesis uses several regression models to analyze the quantitative relationship between married female labor force participation and family income with recent U.S. national data. It also examines whether the sensitivity of labor force participation of married women to family income differs by income group. The regression results demonstrate that there is a negative correlation between family income and married female labor force participation and the sensitivities varied by income group. That is, the negative relationship between income and work is more clearly visible among high income families. It illustrate to policy makers that it is important to work incentives to consider targeting income groups when making tax policies and welfare policies. If policies are not made appropriately, a number of well-educated women could leave labor market. It is a great loss of human capital and will raise gender inequality in the labor market. This study uses data from the 2013 Current Population Survey, March supplement. iii

TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION... 1 II. LITERATURE REVIEW... 3 A. Women s Labor Force Participation and Economic Status... 3 B. The Influence of Husbands Income... 4 C. The Influence of Taxation Policies... 5 D. Women s Labor Force Participation May Differ by Income Group... 7 III. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY AND DATA DESCRIPTION... 8 A. Hypothesis... 8 B. Data... 8 C. Descriptive Statistics... 9 D. Definitions and Justifications of Variables... 11 IV. ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS... 17 A. Methodology... 17 B. Regression Results... 19 C. Robustness and Limitations of the Models... 23 V. POLICY RELEVANCE... 23 A. Current Polices about Married Women s Employment... 23 B. Findings... 24 C. Policy Recommendations... 24 VI. CONCLUSION... 26 APPENDIX... 28 REFERENCES... 31 iv

LIST OF FIGURES Chart1. The Labor force participation rate of women by marital status from 1960 to 2010 in the United States...1 Table1. Labor force status among married people for all ages in the United States, 2012 (numbers in percentage)...9 Table2. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) in the United States by selected demographic characteristics, March 2013...10 Exhibit1. Variable matrix and justifications...11 Chart2. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by education attainment, 2013 in the United States...13 Chart3. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by age, 2013 in the United States...14 Chart4. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by race, 2013 in the United States...14 Chart5. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by own children under 6 years old, 2013 in the United States...15 Chart6. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by earnings (in one thousand dollars), 2013 in the United States...16 Exhibit2: Variable definitions and calculations...18 Table3. Regression results showing coefficients using LPM model (with robust standard errors) with the dependent variable of labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) in March 2013...19 Table4. Regression results showing coefficients using IV model with the dependent variable of labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) in March 2013...20 Table5.Regression results showing coefficients using tobit model with the dependent variable of labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) in March 2013...22 Table6. Variable correlations...28 Table7. White test...28 v

Table8. Linktest of LPM, IV and tobit model...29 Table9. Ramsey Reset of LPM...29 Table10. Anderson Rubin test and Wald test for IV model...30 vi

I. INTRODUCTION The number of working women has trended upwards in the United States for a number of years. Nowadays, many U.S. women face the family-work decision after marriage. For example, Powell (2013) stated that, from 1870 to 2000 women s participation in the workforce continually increased. However, since 2000, women s participation in the workforce has declined to where it was in 1994. Chart1. The Labor force participation rate of women by marital status from 1960 to 2010 in the United States 70.00% 60.00% 50.00% 40.00% 30.00% Labor Force Participation Rate by Marital Status 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 Year Total Women Never Married Married Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Women in the Labor Force: A Databook, Report 1026, December 2010, and unpublished, Basic Tabulations, Table 12. See also<http://www.bls.gov/cps/wlf-databook2009.htm> Chart1 demonstrates that, in history, never married women have a significantly higher labor force participation rate than married women; however, the net difference of the labor force participation of never married women and married women has narrowed significantly. It also shows that total women s labor force participation had dramatically increased from about 38 percent to 60 percent in the period of 1960 to 2000. Thus, in the long time period, 1

there is an increasing trend of the labor force participation rate of women. However, starting from around the mid-1990s, the trends changed. Married women s rate held steady while the rate for never married women started to decline. It is a signal that women are becoming more reluctant to participate in the labor market, both married and unmarried women. It could be related to the heavy burden that married women have in pursuing future career achievements. They are far more likely to take more shares of home responsibilities, especially after they have children. According to a published yearly Mother's Day Common Task Index 1, the 2013 market value of a housewife is $59,862. That includes $6,570 for cooking, $5,135 for cleaning and $1,606 for shopping. Hence, many families find that wives can create more value at home than working in the labor market. Second, married women are more likely to face secondary earner bias. Women usually earn less than men. Goldin (1990) demonstrated evidence that the gender gap in income and job level has existed throughout history and cannot be explained simply as a matter of sex discrimination, nor as a result of inherent structural phenomena in the employment market. As secondary earners, married women s additional income places families in a higher marginal income tax bracket. Thus, if a family needs a person to stay at home to take care of housework, the wife is typically the first choice. So, family income appears to be a key ingredient to the decision of wives working. 1 Insure.com is a website that provides a comprehensive array of information on life, health, auto, and home insurance. The website started publishing Mother s day common task index in 2011. The index is calculated from a list of household tasks that moms usually perform, like cooking, driving, planning, cleaning, and taking care of the kids. 2

This thesis uses recent U.S. data to analyze the quantitative relationship between labor force participation rate and family income. It also examines whether married women s labor force participation sensitivity to family income differs by income group. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II examines recent literature on the influences of family income to married women s labor force participation. Section III presents the hypothesis, data, and methodology used to conduct this analysis. Section IV discusses the formal results of econometric analysis. Section V provides the policy implications and recommendations. Section VI makes conclusions. II. LITERATURE REVIEW A. Women s Labor Force Participation and Economic Status Previous literature throws light on the evidence that women s labor force participation rate is negatively correlated to their socio-economic status. There is a sort of philosophy that women do not work unless they have to. Mincer (1962) provided a basic framework for the analysis of changes in the female labor force participation rate and its influencing factors. His work triggered a series of studies on the labor force participation of married women among 57 U.S. cities. Mincer (1962) pointed out that one should distinguish work at home and leisure. Work in the home should be treated and valued as a separate work option because doing housework creates market value. He (1962) also found that the labor force participation of married women was determined by both their diverse socio-economic environments and 3

their own human capital characteristics. His work supports the hypothesis of the thesis that there is a significant relationship between female labor force participation and family income. B. The Influence of Husbands Income Two main important influences to family income are the husbands wage and taxation policies. Many previous studies discussed how those two factors affect the labor force participation rate of married women. For example, Becker (1991) and Devereux (2004) discussed the influence of husbands income and Eissa (1995) discussed the effect of tax policies. Becker (1991) predicted that wives would reduce their market work and focus more on housework, if their husbands have higher income. This prediction has been supported by Devereux (2004), who analyzed the influencing factors of women s labor force supply and concluded that there is a strong negative response of female labor supply to changes in their husband's wages. However, Goldin (1990) and Juhn and Murphy (1997) found that this relationship has changed significantly over time. Goldin (1990), in her analysis of the changing economic role of American women, collected and tabulated a number of estimates of labor supply elasticities (how sensitive it is to changes in wages/income) over the twentieth century and concluded that the labor supply curve is not stable. She (1990) argued that women s income sensitivity to outside forces appeared to have decreased over the century, while sensitivity to their own wages first rose and then fell. Juhn and Murphy (1997) found continued declining trends in the sensitivity of women s labor supply with more recent data. 4

In more recent studies, Bradbury and Kats (2008) stated that the decline in wives responsiveness to husbands wages has come to an end. According to their research, the responsiveness of married women s labor force participation to husbands wages was significantly more negative in 2006 than in 1997. They found evidence of rising responsiveness to husbands wages, occurring largely between 1997 and 2002 and concentrated among younger women and women with children. They also pointed out that one possible explanation of this development is changes in the tax system. C. The Influence of Taxation Policies Obviously, husbands income and taxation policy are both important indicators of women s socio-economic environments that can partially explain married women s labor supply. Eissa (1995) used the Tax Reform Act of 1986 as a natural experiment to identify the labor supply responsiveness of married women to changes in the tax rate. She found evidence that the labor supply of high-income, married women increased due to the lower tax rates of the Tax Reform Act of 1986. The increase in total labor supply of married women at the top of income distribution implies sensitivity with respect to the after- tax wage. Studies by Mroz (1987) and Eissa and Hoynes (2004) illustrate that the married female labor force participation rate is the best measure of labor supply in evaluating economic changes due to taxation programs. Mroz (1987) provided a consistent finding that labor supply responses are concentrated along the extensive (entry) margin, rather than the 5

intensive (hours worked) margin. The whether-to-work and how-much-to-work distinction has important implications for the design of tax-transfer programs. Because of Mroz (1987) s finding, Eissa and Hoynes (2004) also used labor force participation rate as a coefficient to evaluate the outcome of the earned income tax credit (EITC) program. In this study, they showed that particular taxation policy changes can affect women s labor force participation rate. This paper examined the labor force participation response of married couples to EITC expansions between 1984 and 1996. The analysis used both quasi-experimental and traditional reduced-form labor supply models to estimate the effect of tax credits. Both results showed that the EITC expansions reduced the total family labor supply of married couples. Particularly, the labor force participation rate of married men increased by about 0.2 percentage points; that of married women decreased by just over a full percentage point. These findings implied that the EITC expansions actually encouraged married mothers to stay home. This result also matches the finding that labor force participation of secondary earners is likely sensitive to taxes (Triest, 1992). The target sample of the thesis is married women because women s labor force participation is more sensitive to taxation policies. Women are more likely to be secondary earners. Frank (1978) s finding shows that equally qualified females would be paid less than males because many married women would follow their husbands to a particular geographic location which constrained their possibilities to find a suitable job. Besides, women usually take more home responsibilities than men. As husband's income increases, controlling for wife's income and other factors, wife's home responsibilities increase; but as wife's income 6

increases, controlling for husband's income and other factors, the opposite effect is seen on her home responsibilities; that is, her share of home responsibilities declines (Maret and Finlay,1984).That is, the larger the income gap between husbands and wives, the more home responsibility would be taken by wives. Hence, when economic environments change, women s labor force participation rate is more sensitive to it than men s. D. Women s Labor Force Participation May Differ by Income Group The previous literature implies that, as an important indicator of socio-economic status, family income is a key determent factor of women s labor force participation rate. There should be a strong negative response of the labor force participation rate of married women to changes in their family income. This thesis will examine women s labor force participation by income groups. Actually, some studies have already stated that labor supply sensitivities may differ by income group (Juhn, Murphy, and Topel, 2002, and Ziliak and Kniesner, 1999). For example, if lower-income people have lower labor force participation rates, then their participation response to reductions in tax rates could be higher because there are more people who could enter the workforce. (Ziliak and Kniesner, 1999). However, this result was based on a sample of all people instead of just married women. With the sample of just married women, this thesis aims to verify that whether the previous finding that labor supply sensitivities may differ by income groups still holds. 7

III. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY AND DATA DESCRIPTION A. Hypothesis In this study, the dependent variable is whether or not a married woman is participating in the labor force (a dummy variable). The main independent variable is family income. The hypothesis of the thesis is that married female labor force participation is negatively correlated to family income. Classic economic theory suggests both an income effect and a substitute effect on labor supply. Assuming that total family income is composed of worker s wage and other income, as the wage rate increases, the worker would substitute work hours for leisure hours in order to earn more. Thus, the wage rate is positively correlated to labor supply. Remember too that leisure, especially for women, includes housework. The income effect is with more non-wage income, one will buy more leisure hours and thus work less. Hence, as the family income increases, it will have offsetting income and substitute effects on labor supply. So, since these two theoretical impacts move in opposite directions, the outcome is considered an empirical question: This means it must be examined with data. B. Data The data come from the 2013 March Supplement Current Population Surveys (CPS).The CPS is the source of the official government statistics on employment and unemployment. It has been conducted monthly for over 50 years. Currently, about 54,000 households are interviewed monthly for four consecutive months one year, and again for the 8

corresponding time period a year later. The CPS collects information on the demographic status of the population, information such as age, sex, race, marital status, educational attainment, and family structure. The CPS March supplement also includes labor market and income information of the previous year. The CPS provides information on households, families and individuals respectively. In this study, the population of interest is married women. Hence, the sample only includes married female individuals. Married women who are younger than 18 years old or older than 54 years old usually do not participate in the labor market. So, married women age from 18-54 years old are defined as the working-age population, and there are 27, 770 observations in total in the sample. C. Descriptive Statistics Table1. Labor force status among married people for all ages in the United States, 2012 (numbers in percentage) Married Married Labor Status Total Women Men Not in Labor Force 28.6 8.5 19.0 Labor Force 71.4 91.5 81.1 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source: Current Population Survey (CPS), March 2013. Bureau of Labor Statistics, which collects data for the previous year. According to Bureau of Labor Statistics, in 2012, the U.S. total married labor force was 40,273 thousand. Table 1 illustrates that about 7 of 10 married women participate in labor force in the United States in 2012, compared to about 9 of 10 married men. Both figures indicate that among working age adults in the United States, labor force participation is high. 9

However, as shown earlier, the rate for married women appears to have plateaued. Table2. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) in the United States by selected characteristics, March 2013. Characteristics Total Labor Force Not in Labor Force Count Percent Count Percent Count Percent Total 27,770 100.0 19,838 71.4 7,932 28.6 Age 18-29 3,779 100.0 2,330 61.7 1,449 38.3 30-44 14,242 100.0 10,161 71.4 4,081 28.7 45-54 9,749 100.0 7,347 75.4 2,402 24.6 Race White 22,947 100.0 16,464 71.8 6,483 28.3 Non White 4,823 100.0 3,374 70.0 1,449 30.0 Education Some College 18,710 100.0 14,297 76.4 4,413 23.6 No College 9,060 100.0 5,541 61.2 3,519 38.8 Children Own Unmarried Children Under 6 8,380 100.0 5,281 63.0 3,098 37.0 years old No Unmarried Children Under 6 years old 19,390 100.0 14,556 75.1 4,833 24.9 Earnings in 1,000 U.S. dollars 30 17,636 100 9,876 56.0 7,760 44.0 >30 10,134 100 9,962 98.3 172 1.7 Family Income in 1,000 U.S. dollars (women s earnings not included) 50 13,113 100.0 9,188 70.1 3,925 29.9 >50 14,657 100.0 10,650 72.7 4,007 27.3 Source: Current Population Survey (CPS), March 2013. Bureau of Labor Statistics Table2 digs a little deeper. It shows that education, children, and earnings are important predictors of labor force participation. More education, fewer children and higher earnings all predict higher labor force participation for married women. 10

D. Definitions and Justifications of Variables Exhibit1. Variable matrix and justifications Definition Variable Name Expected Sign Justification Dependent Variable Dummy variable indicating Labor Force Participation Y of Married Women (Yes=1; No=0) LFP N/A Falzone, J. S. (2010) Eissa and Hoynes (2004) Independent Variables Continuous variable showing total family X 1 income (women's earnings not included) X 2 Dummy variable indicating education attainment FAMINCO _ Mincer (1962) Devereux (2004) Income effect EDUC + Falzone, J. S. (2010) X 3 X 4 X 5 X 6 X 7 Continuous variable indicating the age in yeas Quadratic variable indicating the square of age Dummy variable indicating White or Non-White Dummy variable indicating having children under 6 years old or no children under 6 years old Continues variable indicating women's earnings AGE + Falzone, J. S. (2010) AGE2 - Falzone, J. S. (2010) RACE + Falzone, J. S. (2010) KIDS6 _ Rincon, Betilde (2007) EARNING + Substitute effect Instrumental Variable X 8 categorical variable indicating percentage of male in professional occupations HUSOCCUP _ Income effect 11

Dependent variable: The study uses whether married females are participating in the labor force as the main independent variable, a typical and useful measure of labor supply in evaluating economic changes. Labor force participation can be viewed as one s decision of whether to participate in the labor market. Mainstream economic theory assumes that there are only two mutually exclusive activities, labor and leisure. Individuals choose the combination of labor-leisure to maximize their utility. Labor force participation is a binary choice variable equal to 1 if the individual participates in the labor market and equal to zero otherwise. Main independent variable: Family income is the main independent variable showing total family income, excluding women s earnings. According to Mincer (1962), labor force participation of married women is significantly correlated to their diverse socio-economic environment. The expected sign of family income is negative because Devereux (2004) suggests that there is a strong negative response of female labor supply to changes in their husband's wages and husband income, both of which are important parts of family income. Control variables: Several other important factors may contribute to women s decision on whether to work or not. The main influences must be accounted for in the model. This paper would take the following control variables into consideration. 12

1. Education Chart2. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by education attainment, 2013 in the United States 80.00% 75.00% LFP by Education 76.41% 70.00% 65.00% 60.00% 61.16% 55.00% 50.00% Some College Education No College Education Source: Current Population Survey (CPS), March 2013. Bureau of Labor Statistics Education is a dummy variable, equals to one, if the woman received some college education, zero otherwise. Generally, investment in human capital represents the most important determinant of the market wage, thus would also influence the labor supply of married women. The expected sign of education is positive since years of schooling not only increase the expected market wage but also the likelihood of entering the labor market seeking a return on one s education investment. 13

Labor Force Participation(%) 2. Age Chart3. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by age, 2013 in the United States 90 LFP By Age 80 70 60 50 40 30 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 AGE Source: Current Population Survey (CPS), March 2013. Bureau of Labor Statistics The expected sign of age is positive. Age is included here as a proxy for labor market experience, which builds on itself in keeping married women interested in the labor market. Age-squared is included in the model as the willingness and desire to work seems to taper off with age. 3. Race Chart4. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by race, 2013 in the United States 80.00% 75.00% 70.00% 65.00% 60.00% 55.00% 50.00% 69.96% Non White LFP By Race 71.75% White Source: Current Population Survey (CPS), March 2013. Bureau of Labor Statistics 14

A dummy variable for race = 1 if the woman is white is included to control for any different proclivities for whites and nonwhites to participate in the labor force; 0 is for nonwhites. However, there appears to be only slightly more white, married women participating in the labor force than nonwhite, married women. 4. Kids Chart5. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by own children under 6 years old, 2013 in the United States 85.00% 80.00% 75.00% LFP by Kids Status(Under 6 years old) 75.07% 70.00% 65.00% 63.03% 60.00% 55.00% 50.00% No Unmarried Kids Under 6 Own Unmarried Kids Under 6 Source: Current Population Survey (CPS), March 2013. Bureau of Labor Statistics KIDS 6 is a dummy variable indicating whether a woman has unmarried children under 6 years old or no kids at all. The expected sign of kids is negative since women who have preschool children are more likely to have a heavier burden in children care and home responsibilities and thus less likely to participate in the labor market. According to the chart, the labor force participation rate for married women with children under 6 years old is significantly less than those with no children under 6 years old -- 63 versus 75 percent. 15

5. Earnings Chart6. Labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) by earnings (in one thousand dollars), 2013 in the United States 120.00% 100.00% LFP by Earnings (in one thousand dollars) 98.27% 80.00% 60.00% 56.01% 40.00% 20.00% 0.00% Yearly Earnings 30 Yearly Earnings>30 Source: Current Population Survey (CPS), March 2013. Bureau of Labor Statistics Earning is a continuous variable showing women s yearly earnings in one thousand dollars. The expected sign of earning is positive because of the substitution effect. Labor economics suggests that the rise of real wage rate would increase the opportunity cost of leisure, thus increase the labor force participation rate. Instrumental variable: Husbands professional occupation (husoccup) measures the percentage of male s professional occupation in each state. Husbands job and salary is highly correlated with family income, while, it is not likely to be correlated with women s labor force participation. That makes Husbands professional occupation a qualified instrument of family income. 16

IV. ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS A. Methodology Since labor force participation of married women is a binary variable, the study uses a linear probability model (LPM) to estimate the probability of participating in the labor force. The LPM analysis could provide results which can be easily interpreted and the method is straightforward to analyze. For the LPM model, this relationship is a particularly simple one, and allows the model to be fitted by simple linear regression. Since women with different family incomes do not randomly select themselves into working or not working groups, the original model may have a self-selection bias. This analysis attempts to deal with this problem by adding husbands professional occupation as an instrument of family income. This entails an instrumental variable (IV) model, the results of which will be compared to the LPM model. Another concern of the original model is married women not working do not report and earnings. Thus, there are several observations with zero earnings. This concentration of zeros could bias the results. Thus, a tobit model is used to deal with the problem, the results of which will be compared to the LPM and IV models. In this paper, the model will be constructed as follows: 17

Exhibit2: Variable definitions and calculations E Y X = Pr (Y = 1 X) = β 0 + β 1 X 1 + β 2 X 2 + β 3 X 3 + β 4 X 4 + β 5 X 5 + β 6 X 6 +β 7 X 7 + ϵ Where: Pr (Y= 1 X) = LFP The probability of participating in the labor force Data from March, 2013 CPS X 1 =FAMINCO Total Family Income in one thousand dollars (women s earnings not included) X 2 = EDUC Education (some college education versus no college education) X 3 = AGE Age (in years) X 4 =AGE2 Age*Age (in years) X 5 = RACE Race (white versus non-white) X 6 = KIDS6 Have children in family under 6 years old versus Not have children in family under 6 years old X 7 = Earnings Women s yearly earnings in one thousand dollars ϵ = Unexplained Variance, Error Term β 0 = Y-intercept β 1, β 2, β 3, β 4, β 5, β 6, β 7 = Coefficients of respective independent variables, partial slope coefficients 18

B. Regression Results Table3, Table4 and Table5 provide the estimated regression coefficients for LPM model, IV model and tobit model respectively, with t-statistics reported in parentheses immediately below. Regression results using linear probability model: Table3. Regression results showing coefficients using LPM model (with robust standard errors) with the dependent variable of labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) in March 2013. characteristic mean total family income 50,000 Constant term 0.2715*** (5.02) Family income in 1,000 dollars (women s earnings not included) 69.9785-0.0006*** (-12.33) Education 0.6737 0.0909*** (10.93) Kids6 0.3018-0.1061*** (-16.75) Race 0.8263 0.0322*** (4.88) Age 40.0189 0.1563*** (5.54) Age2 1675.87-0.0002*** (-5.35) Earnings in 1,000 dollars 29.1300 0.0040*** (13.16) 0.2307*** (3.13) 0.0006** (2.42) 0.1099*** (7.30) -0.0923*** (-10.13) 0.0022 (0.24) 0.0158*** (3.96) -0.0002*** (-3.81) 0.0048*** (6.49) family income>50,000 0.3278*** (3.82) -0.0006*** (-10.44) 0.0508*** (4.74) -0.1165*** (-13.13) 0.0586*** (6.22) 0.0140*** (3.23) -0.0002*** (-3.21) 0.0037*** (11.62) Number of observations 27700 13113 14657 R 2 0.1855 0.1889 0.1915 F statistic 903.10 436.01 495.65 * Statistically significant at 0.05<p<0.1 ** Statistically significant at 0.01<p<0.05 *** Statistically significant at p<0.01 Numbers in the parentheses are t-statistics. The small estimated negative coefficient for family income in Table3 implies that one thousand dollars increase in family income would decrease married women s mean 19

probability of participating in labor force by a small amount. The results hold for both low and high income groups. However, this coefficients estimated are likely to be biased by self-selection problem. The results of diagnostic tests provided in Table8 and Table9 in the Appendix also indicate that the LPM model may have a problem of miss-specification. Regression results using IV model: Table4. Regression results showing coefficients using IV model with the dependent variable of labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) in March 2013. characteristic mean total family income 50,000 family income>50,000 Constant term 0.2533*** (4.25) 0.1265 (0.72) 0.3411*** (4.12) Family income in 1,000 dollars (women s earnings not included) 69.9785-0.0010** (-2.24) Education 0.6737 0.1027*** (7.37) Kids6 0.3018-0.1038*** (-15.22) Race 0.8263 0.0376*** (4.73) Age 40.0189 0.0164*** (5.13) Age2 1675.87-0.0002*** (-5.15) Earnings in 1,000 dollars 29.1300 0.0042*** (48.24) 0.0194 (0.78) 0.0499 (0.66) -0.1056*** (-5.01) -0.0622 (-0.71) -0.0005 (-0.02) 6.88e-06 (0.03) 0.0050*** (36.65) -0.0004 (-0.81) 0.0500*** (3.82) -0.1179*** (-12.47) 0.0589*** (6.15) 0.0125*** (2.83) -0.0002*** (-2.93) 0.0038*** (39.93) Number of observations 27700 12600 13888 R 2 0.1825 not reported 2 0.1932 F statistic 829.40 299.09 443.96 * Statistically significant at 0.05<p<0.1 ** Statistically significant at 0.01<p<0.05 *** Statistically significant at p<0.01 Numbers in the parentheses are t-statistics. By introducing an instrument in the regression, Table 4 shows the regression results of trying to minimize the self-selection problem. The estimated coefficient of -0.0010 for family 2 STATA did not report R 2 here, because the model sum of squares is negative. 20

income in Table4 implies that one thousand dollars increase in family income would decrease married women s probability of participating in labor force by still small but somewhat larger amount. However, when low and high income groups were analyzed separately, income was not statistically significant. 3 Regression results using tobit model: Table5. Regression results showing coefficients using tobit model with the dependent variable of labor force participation of married women (18-54 years old) in March 2013. characteristic mean total family income 50,000 family income>50,000 Constant term -0.0005 (-0.01) -0.0751 (-0.79) 0.1011*** (0.90) Family income in 1,000 dollars (women s earnings not included) 69.9785-0.0009*** (-19.01) Education 0.6737 0.1287*** (16.72) Kids6 0.3018-0.1502*** (-17.21) Race 0.8263 0.0446*** (4.92) Age 40.0189 0.0227*** (6.24) Age2 1675.87-0.0003*** (-5.91) Earnings in 1,000 dollars 29.1300 0.0053*** (63.96) 0.00008** (2.36) 0.1581*** (14.57) -0.1336*** (-10.54) 0.0023 (0.18) 0.0235*** (4.69) -0.0003*** (-4.38) 0.0064*** (41.33) -0.0008*** (-16.49) 0.0704*** (6.13) -0.1619*** (-13.49) 0.0800*** (6.31) 0.0197*** (3.48) -0.0002*** (-3.42) 0.0048*** (50.12) Number of observations 27700 13113 14657 Pseudo R 2 0.1007 0.1003 0.1068 LR statistic 5455.04 2606.85 3001.15 * Statistically significant at 0.05<p<0.1 ** Statistically significant at 0.01<p<0.05 *** Statistically significant at p<0.01 Numbers in the parentheses are t-statistics. 3 To ensure that the IV model produced reasonably results, multiple weak instruments tests were performed. Weak instrument tests were conducted in the IV model with total sample and the IV models with different income group respectively. A summary of results of weak instrument tests is provided in Table10. Weak instrument tests results indicate that the instrument is weak in the IV models with both income groups. Thus, the coefficients of both income groups reported in Table4 are not very reliable. 21

The analysis also introduced a tobit model to handle better the number of zero values for earnings. Table5 summarizes the results of the tobit model, perhaps the strongest model econometrically. All of the results of the tobit model are highly significant. Based on the reported coefficient for family income, holding control variables in the model constant, an increase in family income is associated with a decrease in married women s probability of participating in labor force, consistent with the LPM and IV models. The sensitivities of family income to labor force participation differed by income group. For married women whose family income is higher than 50 thousand U.S. dollars, the sensitivity of family income to labor force participation is very close to the sensitivity in the whole sample regression. However, for married women whose family income is less than 50 thousand U.S. dollars, an increase in family income is associated with a slightly higher increase in married women s probability of participating in labor force. This could indicate that among lower income families, the substitute effect dominates the income effect. That is, more work is desired over more leisure. These findings are statistically significant at the 0.10 level. These results are consistent with the findings of previous literature that family income is negatively associated with married women s likelihood of participating in labor force, although the magnitude of change is not very large. With the sample of both males and females, (Ziliak and Kniesner, 1999) suggests that lower-income people would have a higher response to reductions in tax rates. However, with a sample of just married women, this thesis finds that the magnitudes of sensitivities are similar among income groups. However, in the 22

lower income group, family income is positively associated with labor force participation, whereas family income is negatively correlated with labor force participation in the higher income group. C. Robustness and Limitations of the Models The analytical results have some limitations. First, according to the results of model specification tests provided in the diagnostic section, all of three models discussed above may have the problem of mis-specification. However, because all of the results are very robust and consistent with conclusions of previous literature, the results of the analysis can still provide some policy implications. V. POLICY RELEVANCE A. Current Polices about Married Women s Employment People have been calling for equal working opportunities for women for a long time. Indeed, since the late 19 th century, the female labor force participation rate increased dramatically. However, family-work conflicts are still an important factor that makes women choose to stay at home. Currently, according to Henneck (2003), the United States encourages families to seek market-based solutions to work-family conflict. For example, there is little attempt to subsidize family caregiving for working mothers. Social support for working mothers and their children are primarily reserved for only the most impoverished 23

families. Most must rely on their own income and the main findings have shown that family income dictates the labor force participation behavior of married women. B. Findings The main findings suggest that the sensitivities of labor force participation to family income differ by income group. In the lower income group, married women s labor force participation would increase if family income goes up. It indicates that extra family income is needed. Thus, to the lower income group, providing some subsidies working mothers could effectively encourage house wives come back to work. On the contrary, in the higher income group, the mean probability of participating labor force decreases when family income grows. One possible explanation is that, as theory says, people prefer leisure more than work when income permits. However, it can also be explained by the tax penalty. With increasing family income, the tax penalty could jump to a higher level. The high level of tax penalty is a potential factor that encourages married women to stay at home. Thus, in order to relieve the potential higher gender inequality, current tax policies need to be reviewed. C. Policy Recommendations First, to encourage married women from lower-income families to go back to work, the government could provide some subsidies to qualified working married women. The subsidies could effectively increase the labor force participation among lower-income 24

households. Essa and Hoynes (2004) suggest the earned income tax credit (EITC) which is the largest cash transfer program that providing subsidies to lower-income families with children is actually subsidizing married women to stay at home. However, with more recent data, the regression results of this thesis demonstrate that cash transfer program like EITC would effectively increase labor force participation since there is a positive correlation between labor force participation and family income among married women from lower-income families. To garner wider political support, the subsidies could be in the form of vouchers that can only be used for childcare and home-help care. Second, the government needs to review current tax policies and make sure they do not provide a disincentive to work. Further research could be conducted to exam whether the tax policies contribute to the negative relationship between family income and labor force participation. According to the tax policies of most states, when the family income exceeds a certain cap, the tax as a percentage of total earnings would jump to a higher level. To avoid a higher tax level, some family members would choose to stay at home. Because of the second earner bias discussed before, the wife usually becomes the one that stay at home. As a matter of fact, this scenario raises gender inequality and causes a waste of human capital. Third, it is important to consider targeting certain income groups when making tax policies and welfare policies that would influence family income. The main findings of the analysis suggest that sensitivity of labor force participation of married women to family income differ by income group. Thus, policies that affect family income would result in 25

different labor supply responses among different income groups. Ignoring the effect of income groups would make policies inefficient. VI. CONCLUSION Using a dataset from the 2013 March Supplement Current Population Surveys for 27,770 married women age from 18-54 years old, this paper investigates the relationship between family income and married women s labor force participation. This paper builds on prior research that found negative relationships between economic status and married women s labor force participation. Descriptive statistics supported existing research and economic theories, demonstrating that more education, fewer children and higher earnings all predict higher labor force participation. This analysis uses LPM, IV model and tobit model to exam the quantitative relationship. The regression results suggest a strong likelihood that family income and married women s likelihood of participating in labor force move in opposite directions and the sensitivities differ by income group. In the low income group, family income is positively associated with labor force participation, whereas family income is negatively correlated with labor force participation in the high income group. The findings have several implications for current tax policies and welfare policies. Among lower family income group, subsidies to qualified working women would effectively increase women s labor force participation. Among higher family income group, it is necessary to review current tax policies and make appropriate changes because tax penalty is 26

a potential cause that makes higher family income women stay at home. The analysis also suggests it is vital to consider targeting certain income groups when making tax policies and welfare policies that would influence family income because those police changes would result in different labor supply responses among different income groups. 27

APPENDIX 1. Diagnostic: Multicollinearity Test: Table6. Variable correlation Variables faminco race educ kids18 age age2 earning family 1.0000 income (earnings not included) Race 0.0458 1.0000 (dummy) Education 0.1846-0.0149 1.0000 (dummy) Kids under -0.0399 0.0251 0.0529 1.0000 6 years old (dummy) Age (years 0.1463-0.0039-0.0055-0.5068 1.0000 old) Age 2 0.1400-0.0026-0.0144-0.5089 0.9938 1.0000 (quadratic term) Earnings 0.1210-0.0068 0.2308-0.0449 0.1016 0.0939 1.0000 Table 6 summarizes the results of multicollinearity test. According to the table, age is highly correlated with age2. It is because that age2 is the quadratic term of age. Although the multicollinearity test diagnosed a problem of age2, age2 should still be included in the model. Heteroskedasticity Tests: Table7. White test Source chi2 df p Heteroskedasticity 1054.24 23 0.0000 Skewness 11668.36 6 0.0000 Kurtosis 1695.72 1 0.0000 Total 14418.33 30 0.0000 28

Table7 summarizes the results of White test which indicates there exists heteroskedasticity in LPM model. It implies the OLS estimators are inefficient in the LPM. Thus, robust standard errors are used in the LPM to deal with this problem. Model specification errors: Table8. Linktest of LPM, IV and tobit model LPM IV tobit Married Women s Labor force participation (Y) t z t _hat 87.14 (0.000) _hatsq -50.42 (0.000) _cons -36.41 (0.000) Number of observations 78.05 (0.000) -39.36 (0.000) -22.24 (0.000) 84.67 (0.000) -48.28 (0.000) -29.22 (0.000) 27,770 27,770 27,770 R 2 /Pseudo R 2 0.2538 0.2285 0.1431 Numbers in the parentheses are p-values. Table9. Ramsey Reset of LPM Ramsey RESET test using powers of the fitted values of labor force participation Ho: model has no omitted variables F(3, 27759) = 2629.89 Prob>F = 0.0000 Table8 and Table9 summarize the results of Linktest for LPM, IV and tobit model 29

respectively and the results of Ramsey Reset of LPM. Both tests indicate there are mis-specification problems in all three models used in the analysis. Weak instrument test: Table10. Anderson Rubin test and Wald test for IV model. Chi-squared Clomn1 (Total) AR 5.02 (0.0251) Wald 5.03 (0.0248) Numbers in the parentheses are p-values. (Clomn2) Family income<50 0.87 (0.3511) 0.60 (0.4367) (Clomn3) Family income>50 0.65 (0.4214) 0.66 (0.4177) Table10 summarizes Anderson Rubin test and Wald test for IV model. Clomn1 reports the results of weak instrument tests for the total sample and Clomn2, Clomn3 reports results of weak instrument tests for the low income group and high income group respectively. The results indicate that husbands professional occupation as an instrument is not weak in the IV model with total sample. However, it is weak in the IV models of both income groups. 30

REFERENCES Becker, Gary S. (1991). A Treatise on the Family, Enl. Ed. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ.Press. Bradbury, Katharine; Katz, Jane.(2008). The responsiveness of married women's labor force participation to income and wages: Recent changes and possible explanations, Working paper series // Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, No. 08-7 Devereux, Paul J. (2004). Changes in relative wages and family labor supply, Journal of Human Resources, 39 (3): 699-722. Eissa, Nada. (1995). Taxation and Labor Supply of Married Women: The Tax Reform Actof 1986 as a Natural Experiment, NBER working paper no. 5023. Eissa, Nada, and Hilary Hoynes. (2004). Taxes and the Labor Market Participation of Married Couples: The Earned Income Tax Credit, Journal of Public Economics, 88(9-10):1931-1958. Frank, Robert H. (1978). Why Women Earn Less: The Theory and Estimation of Differential Overqualification, American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 68(3), 360-73, June. Goldin, Claudia. (1990). Understanding the gender gap: An economic history of American women. New York: Oxford University Press. Henneck, Rachel. (2003). Family Policy in the US, Japan, Germany, Italy and France: Parental Leave, Child Benefits/Family Allowances, Child Care, Marriage/Cohabitation, and Divorce, Council on Contemporary Families. Retrieved on Januarary16 th, 2014 from http://www.contemporaryfamilies.org/work-family/fampolicy.html Juhn, Chinhui and Kevin M. Murphy. (1997).Wage inequality and family labor supply.journal of Labor Economics 15, no. 1, part 1 (January): 72 97. Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin M. Murphy, and Robert H. Topel. (2002). Current Unemployment, Historically Contemplated, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2002 (1): 79-116. Marquand, Barbara. (2013). The Mother s Day Index 2013: Mom s value still declining, Insure.com. Retrieved on Januarary16 th, 2014 from http://www.insure.com/articles/lifeinsurance/the-mothers-day-index.html 31

Maret, Elizabeth and Barbara Finlay. (1984). The Distribution of Household Labor among Women in Dual-Earner Families. Journal of Marriage and the Family 46:357-364. McAllister, Ian. (1990). Gender and the Division of Labor: Employment and Earnings Variation in Australia. Work and Occupations 17:79-99. Mincer, Jacob, (1962)Labor Force Participation of Married Women, in H. Gregg Lewis, ed., Aspects of Labor Economics, Universities National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Series, no. 14 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1962), pp. 63-97. Mroz, T.A., (1987). The sensitivity of an empirical model of married women s hours of work to economic and statistical assumptions. Econometrica 55, 765 799. Triest, R.K., (1992). The effect of income taxation on labor supply in the United States. The Journal of Human Resources XXV, 491 516. Ziliak, James P., and Thomas J. Kniesner. (1999). Estimating Life Cycle Labor Supply Tax Effects, Journal of Political Economy, 107 (2): 326-359. 32