Does Insurance Coverage Fall when Nonprofit Insurers Become For-Profits?



Similar documents
The Effect of Health Insurance Coverage on the Reported Health of Young Adults

The Impact of the Massachusetts Health Care Reform on Health Care Use Among Children

Issue Brief. Growth and Variability in Health Plan Premiums in the Individual Insurance Market Before the Affordable Care Act. The COMMONWEALTH FUND

Rising Premiums, Charity Care, and the Decline in Private Health Insurance. Michael Chernew University of Michigan and NBER

President Bush s Health Care Tax Deduction Proposal: Coverage, Cost and Distributional Impacts. John Sheils and Randy Haught

Public Health Insurance Expansions for Parents and Enhancement Effects for Child Coverage

How To Calculate The Cost Of A Health Insurance Tax Credit In Oregona

The Effect of Health Insurance on Emergency Department Visits: Evidence from an Age-Based Eligibility Threshold *

PUBLIC HEALTH INSURANCE EXPANSIONS FOR PARENTS: EVIDENCE FROM WISCONSIN

ObamaCare s Impact on Small Business Wages and Employment

THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF STATE-MANDATED HEALTH INSURANCE BENEFITS

Mandated Health Insurance and Provider Reimbursement: Evidence from the Massachusetts Health Reform

The Effects of Medicaid Expansions on Insurance Coverage of Children

The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice

MEDICAID EXPANSION IN HEALTH REFORM NOT LIKELY TO CROWD OUT PRIVATE INSURANCE by Matthew Broaddus and January Angeles

How To Determine The Impact Of The Health Care Law On Insurance In Indiana

EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT. The Burden of Health Insurance Premium Increases on American Families

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Government Intervention in Health Insurance Markets

2. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Assist with the first year of planning for design and implementation of a federally mandated American health benefits exchange

ONLINE APPENDIX FOR PUBLIC HEALTH INSURANCE, LABOR SUPPLY,

FEDERAL GOVERNMENT WILL PICK UP NEARLY ALL COSTS OF HEALTH REFORM S MEDICAID EXPANSION By January Angeles and Matthew Broaddus

The Impact of Health Care Reform. Evidence from Massachusetts

Generational Aspects of Medicare. David M. Cutler and Louise Sheiner * Abstract

AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTHPLAN EXCHANGE: WHICH EMPLOYEES WOULD BENEFIT AND WHY?

How To Get A Small Business Health Insurance Plan For Free

A special analysis of Mercer s National Survey of Employer-Sponsored Health Plans for the Massachusetts Division of Insurance

Sources of Health Insurance and Characteristics of the Uninsured: Analysis of the March 2010 Current Population Survey

In preparing the February 2014 baseline budget

Dynamic Inefficiencies in Insurance Markets: Evidence from long-term care insurance *

What s in Healthcare Reform for Women-Owned Small Businesses?

Expansion of Medigap to Under-65 Medicare Beneficiaries Could Increase Access at Little Cost. Health Services Research and Evaluation (HSRE)

ACA Premium Impact Variability of Individual Market Premium Rate Changes Robert M. Damler, FSA, MAAA Paul R. Houchens, FSA, MAAA

Medicaid Topics Impact of Medicare Dual Eligibles Stephen Wilhide, Consultant

Preliminary Health Insurance Landscape Analysis

TRENDS AND ISSUES EARLY RETIREE HEALTH INSURANCE ISSUES. By Marilyn Moon, American Institutes for Research and TIAA-CREF Institute Fellow

In Search of a Elusive Truth How Much do Americans Spend on their Health Care?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF HEALTH INSURANCE COVERAGE ON THE USE OF MEDICAL SERVICES. Michael Anderson Carlos Dobkin Tal Gross

Sources of Health Insurance and Characteristics of the Uninsured: Analysis of the March 2012 Current Population Survey

How Sensitive are Low Income Families to Health Plan Prices?

Findings from Massachusetts Health Reform: Lessons for Other States. The Effect of the Massachusetts Reform on Health Care Utilization.

2012 Vermont Household Health Insurance Survey: Comprehensive Report

Employers costs for total benefits grew

PhD Thesis Prospectus. "Health Insurance, Preventative Health Behaviour, and Universal Childcare" Overview of Research Papers

The Impact of the ACA on Maine s Health Insurance Markets

Policy Forum. Understanding the Effects of Medicare Prescription Drug Insurance. About the Authors. By Robert Kaestner and Kelsey McCoy

Worksheet: Firearm Availability and Unintentional Firearm Deaths

THE OREGON HEALTH INSURANCE EXPERIMENT: EVIDENCE FROM THE FIRST YEAR

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

medicaid and the uninsured June 2011 Health Coverage for the Unemployed By Karyn Schwartz and Sonya Streeter

Insurance Trends for the Medicare Population,

How Much Equity Does the Government Hold?

The Risk of Losing Health Insurance Over a Decade: New Findings from Longitudinal Data. Executive Summary

AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTHPLAN EXCHANGE: WHICH EMPLOYEES WOULD BENEFIT AND WHY?

TRENDS IN INSURANCE COVERAGE AND TREATMENT UTILIZATION BY YOUNG ADULTS

75 Washington Ave. Suite 206 Portland, ME (207)

Updated Estimates for the Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act

Second Hour Exam Public Finance Fall, Answers

Policy Options to Improve the Performance of Low Income Subsidy Programs for Medicare Beneficiaries

Changes in Health Insurance Coverage in the Great Recession, John Holahan and Vicki Chen The Urban Institute Executive Summary

THE MASSACHUSETTS HEALTH CARE REFORM ACT: WHAT MUST EMPLOYERS DO?

Welfare Reform and Health Insurance Coverage of Low-income Families. Revised September 2002

Wisconsin typically ranks among the states with the highest level of health

Where Have All the Good Jobs Gone?

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Report to the Health Care Access Bureau Within the Massachusetts Division of Insurance

Impact of Merging the Massachusetts Non-Group and Small Group Health Insurance Markets

Health Care Reform: What s in the Law

March 19, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

1. A. Should the Colorado Health Benefit Exchange operate as one or two entities and

Using Insurance Before You Lose It: Health Care Consumption at the End of Coverage

GAO PATIENT PROTECTION AND AFFORDABLE CARE ACT. Effect on Long-Term Federal Budget Outlook Largely Depends on Whether Cost Containment Sustained

HEALTH INSURANCE CONNECTORS SHOULD BE DESIGNED TO SUPPLEMENT PUBLIC COVERAGE, NOT REPLACE IT By Judith Solomon

Indiana s Health Care Sector and Insurance Market: Summary Report

Exchanges go live: Early trends in exchange dynamics

Massachusetts has garnered national attention recently for its bipartisan

Report to the Massachusetts Division of Insurance:

ESTIMATED PREMIUM IMPACTS OF ANNUAL FEES ASSESSED ON HEALTH INSURANCE PLANS OCTOBER 31, 2011 CHRIS CARLSON, FSA, MAAA

Health Care Reform Premium Impact in New York

Sources of Health Insurance and Characteristics of the Uninsured: Analysis of the March 2013 Current Population Survey

FOUR STEPS TO REFORMING LONG-TERM CARE

Why a State s Health Insurers Should Support Expanding Medicaid

Crowd-out 10 years later: Have recent public insurance expansions crowded out private health insurance?

How To Get A Health Insurance Tax Credit For Small Businesses

How do Labor Market Conditions Affect the Demand for Law School? January Jeffrey Greenbaum. Massachusetts Institute of Technology

Health Coverage among 50- to 64-Year-Olds

Profile of Rural Health Insurance Coverage

Sources of Health Insurance Coverage in Georgia

Strengthening Community Health Centers. Provides funds to build new and expand existing community health centers. Effective Fiscal Year 2011.

Latest House Republican Budget Threatens Medicare and Shreds the Safety Net

The Health Insurance Marketplace 101

Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (H.R. 3590)

Maryland's Wal-Mart Tax Likely to Hurt Wal-Mart's Workers

Impact of the Health Insurance Annual Fee Tax

ADP Annual Health Benefits Report

THE MEDICAID PROGRAM AT A GLANCE. Health Insurance Coverage

State Parity Legislation and Changes in Health Insurance and Perceived Access to Care Among Individuals with Mental Illness:

Insuring the Uninsurable: The Growth in High-Risk Pools. HSRE Working Paper 12

Data Concerns in Out-of-Pocket Spending Comparisons between Medicare and Private Insurance. Cristina Boccuti and Marilyn Moon

DRAFT. Final Report. Wisconsin Department of Health Services Division of Health Care Access and Accountability

Transcription:

Does Insurance Coverage Fall when Nonprofit Insurers Become For-Profits? Ethan M.J. Lieber University of Notre Dame Ethan.Lieber.2@nd.edu COMMENTS WELCOME PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE August, 2015 Abstract Since their beginnings in the 1930s and 1940s, Blue Cross and Blue Shield (BCBS) health insurance plans have operated as nonprofits. In exchange for tax exemptions, they were expected to provide health insurance to the bad risks, those for whom coverage was unavailable from other insurers. When BCBS companies began converting to for-profit status in the 1990s and 2000s, concerns were raised that many consumers would no longer be able to obtain coverage. I present evidence that health insurance coverage rates actually increased when BCBS plans converted to for-profit status. The estimates suggest that five years after a conversion, private coverage was 1.8 percentage points higher than it would have been while the probability of having any type of coverage was 1.1 percentage points higher. The latter estimate translates to a 7.5% reduction in the uninsured. This is an additional 764,000 thousand working-aged consumers with health coverage in the 16 states where plans converted. The aggregate increase in coverage does not mask reductions in insurance rates among populations that tend to be the targets of public policies to expand coverage (e.g. those with low incomes near Medicaid thresholds). There is no evidence that coverage rates increased in states where the BCBS plan began the conversion process, but ultimately did not become a for-profit. These results suggest that BCBS conversions did not adversely affect consumers abilities to obtain health insurance coverage. Keywords: Nonprofit; Conversion; Health Insurance JEL Codes: L33, H25, I13, I18, L50 This work has benefited greatly from helpful comments and suggestions by Kasey Buckles and Dan Hungerman. Any errors are my own. Lieber: 915 Flanner Hall, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, Indiana 46556. 1

1 Introduction Health insurance coverage has been shown to increase consumers health care use (e.g. Manning et al., 1987; Card et al., 2007; Finkelstein et al., 2012; Miller, 2012), to protect against the financial risks associated with sickness (e.g. Engelhardt and Gruber, 2011; Gross and Notowidigdo, 2011), and to have a number of other important effects. In addition, it was the focus of many major public policies in recent years such as the Affordable Care Act, the Medicare Modernization Act, and Medicaid expansions for children and parents. Generally, these policies were aimed at increasing health insurance coverage and were shown to have had some success (e.g. Currie and Gruber, 1996; Antwi et al., 2013). The private market for health insurance is one of the few markets in which nonprofit and for-profit firms compete with each other, but neither has a dominant market share. In 2013, approximately 30% of the market was controlled by nonprofits. 1 Blue Cross and Blue Shield (BCBS) plans, which account for nearly 29% of the market today, have traditionally been the primary nonprofit health insurers. In the 1930s and 1940s as health insurance markets were forming, states passed laws that let BCBS plans operate as nonprofits; in exchange for the tax breaks and exemptions from some insurance regulations, BCBS plans were to act as the insurers of last resort. They were supposed to provide coverage to the bad risks, those for whom coverage was unavailable at reasonable rates from other health insurers (Eilers, 1962). This role is still important today. In August of 2014, the California Franchise Tax Board stripped Blue Shield of California s state tax exemptions because the insurer had failed to offer affordable coverage or other public benefits (Terhune, 2015). 2 For more than forty years, BCBS plans operated as nonprofits. But in the 1990s and 2000s, BCBS plans in 16 states converted to for-profit status. Models of nonprofit behavior suggest that when a firm values the quantity of output, it will tend to produce more than 1 Author s calculation based on insurers data submitted to the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services as part of the Medical Loss Ratio reporting requirements. Only fully insured plans included in this calculation. 2 BCBS plans lost their federal tax-exempt status on January 1, 1987, but many plans retain their exemptions from state taxes. 2

a similar firm that is maximizing only profits (e.g. Lakdawalla and Philipson, 2006). In the case of health insurers, this suggests a nonprofit firm will fill the role of insurer of last resort or offer coverage at lower rates than for-profit insurers. Opponents of the conversions were concerned that if BCBS plans became for-profits, consumers seen as bad risks would no longer be able to obtain coverage. On the other hand, proponents of conversion argued that it would help BCBS plans raise capital to invest in new technologies, merge with other plans across state lines to spread risk, and take other actions that would lower costs and enable plans to provide coverage to more consumers (Schaeffer, 1996). There is an extensive empirical literature on differences between nonprofit and for-profit hospitals (e.g. Norton and Staiger, 1994; Silverman and Skinner, 2004; Picone et al., 2002) 3, but there is surprisingly little evidence for the health insurance industry. Town et al. (2004) do not find any evidence in the HMO market that premiums, profits, or consumers care use changes when an HMO switches from nonprofit to for-profit status; Dafny and Ramanarayanan (2012) find premium increases for large employers plans, but only in markets where the converting firms had a large market share. Using the Anthem BCBS and Wellpoint BCBS conversions to for-profit status, Conover et al. (2005) do not find strong evidence that insurance coverage changed in response to the conversions. Using the same conversions, Dafny and Ramanarayanan (2012) find similar results with the exception of an increase in Medicaid coverage. This paper complements and contributes to this nascent literature in three ways. First, previous works empirical strategies estimate immediate, level changes in coverage, but this paper s study design allows for identification of changes in trends as well. Because health insurance markets are highly concentrated and BCBS plans are often one of the dominant firms, the conversion of a BCBS plan will likely affect not only BCBS plans behaviors, but those of competing insurers as well. 4 As a result, impacts of conversions might not manifest 3 Sloan (2000) reviews the empirical evidence for hospitals and concludes that nonprofit and for-profit hospitals behave quite similarly. 4 For example, Dafny (2010) and Dafny et al. (2012) found evidence that premiums are strategic complements for health insurers. 3

as level shifts immediately after the conversion, but as changes in trends in insurance coverage over a longer period of time. I find that accounting for these changes in trends is important to uncovering the full impacts of the conversions on health insurance coverage. Second, this paper makes use of all of the BCBS conversions that have occurred. Third, whereas previous work has largely focused on aggregate impacts, this paper this paper examines impacts on specific subgroups of consumers. 5 If BCBS were covering individuals who are less likely to be able to obtain coverage from other insurers, impacts of conversions might be focused on these consumers. The analysis begins with a test for a structural break in insurance coverage trends. The Quandt Likelihood Ratio Test does not impose a change in trends when there was a conversion. Instead, it tests for the presence and statistical significance of a break in trend in a large window around the conversions. I find evidence that the most likely year for a trend break was the actual year of conversion and that this break is statistically significant. I then estimate the magnitude of the impact of conversions with a difference-in-differences regression approach that compares coverage trends between states with and states without BCBS conversions, before and after those conversions. The identifying assumption is that absent the conversion, the states that had a conversion would have continued on the same trend relative to the states that did not experience a conversion. This is a slight variant of the usual assumption because I am identifying a break in trends, not levels. I find that, if anything, conversions to for-profit status increased the probability of being insured. The estimates suggest that five years after conversion, the fraction insured in the private market was 1.8 percentage points higher than it would have been absent the conversion. If these were all newly insured consumers, this would be a 12% reduction in the uninsured rate and translate to an extra 1.2 million people with health insurance in the 16 states that converted. 6 I show that the results are not simply capturing the impact of mergers, changes in 5 The one exception is in Dafny and Ramanarayanan (2012) where the authors estimate the impacts of conversion on different age groups. 6 In 1990, just under 15% of the non-elderly were uninsured (authors calculation from Current Population Survey data). 4

Medicaid eligibility, or other unobservable trends. However, there is still a concern that the conversion to for-profit status was not causing the market level changes, but instead reflecting some other process that led to both the conversion and the increase in insurance coverage converting firms chose to convert and may have done so because of anticipated changes in the market that would lead to increased coverage rates. To address this concern, I take advantage of 9 states in which BCBS plans attempted to convert but were not allowed to do so. The reasons that conversion bids were rejected (or accepted) do not appear to be related to underlying trends in insurance coverage. For example, two common reasons that conversions were rejected were disagreements over how much of the nonprofit s assets were to be transferred to another public benefit organization and objections to the bonuses that BCBS executives would reap from the conversion. Thus, if plans choose to convert in states that will experience an increase in coverage for other reasons, then states with failed conversions should experience the same increase in coverage rates as states with successful conversions. I do not find evidence that states with failed conversions had similar increases in coverage. They do not have a change in trend that is statistically distinguishable from zero at conventional levels and even if the estimated impact were correct, the magnitude is small. Although private health insurance coverage is rising after a conversion, it could be falling for certain subgroups that are less likely to have health insurance. Generally, I do not find evidence consistent with this hypothesis. Consumers who are less educated or have low incomes actually see the largest increases in coverage after a BCBS conversion. If the increase in private coverage coincides with a similarly sized reduction in other sources of insurance, then the overall rate of health coverage could be unchanged. To address the issue of crowd-out, I estimate how a BCBS conversion affects the probability of having any health insurance coverage. Five years after a conversion, insurance coverage is estimated to be 1.1 percentage points higher than it would have been without the conversion. This indicates some substitution between sources of coverage or the use of multiple types of 5

coverage after a conversion. Overall, these estimates suggest that the uninsured rate fell by 7.5% and approximately 764,000 consumers gained coverage when the 16 BCBS plans converted to for-profit status. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents information about BCBS plans and their conversions. Section 3 briefly describes the data before presenting graphical evidence of and tests for structural breaks in insurance coverage rates. In Section 4, I present the empirical strategy and estimated impacts of conversions on health insurance coverage. Section 5 presents the impacts of conversions on specific population groups as well impacts on different types of coverage. Section 6 concludes. 2 Blue Cross and Blue Shield Plans Health insurance was all but nonexistent in the United States until the late 1920s and early 1930s. At that time, hospital care was thought of as a social service. In a given year, 30% of patients hospitalized for acute conditions received care for free while another 20% had reduced rates based upon their ability to pay; 70% of hospital beds were in government hospitals and 25% more were in non-profit hospitals (Rorem, 1939). In this context, hospitals created hospital service plans which would soon become Blue Cross plans. A typical plan included 21 days of hospital care for a monthly premium between $0.50 and $2.00 (Leland, 1933b). These plans were attractive to hospitals because the steady stream of income they generated helped offset the financial stress caused by the Great Depression (Leland, 1933a). In February, 1933, the American Hospital Association established a set of principles that were to characterize such plans including (1) an emphasis on public welfare and (2) nonprofit organization (Norby, 1939). However, at least 28 state departments of insurance viewed hospital prepayment plans as insurance (Leland, 1933a). As a result, these plans could only be issued by stock or mutual insurance companies which met capital stock, reserve, and assessment requirements. To circumvent these regulations, states passed enabling acts. 6

New York s was the first and it served as a template for other states. Enabling acts allowed hospital service plans to organize as nonprofits and be exempt from federal income taxation so long as they met the requirements for an organization for social welfare as laid out in Section 101(8) of the Revenue Act of 1936 (Rorem, 1939). 7 At the same time, analogous enabling acts were passed that allowed a corporation to guarantee medical or surgical services in exchange for a monthly premium. Again, the corporation offering the service plan was not an insurer, but a charitable and benevolent institution (Burns, 1939). These medical care plans soon became known as Blue Shield plans. In practice, meeting the requirements of promoting social welfare or being a charitable and benevolent institution meant offering coverage to those who would not otherwise be able to pay their hospital and medical bills. Although this might appear to be an easily avoidable obligation, several Blue Cross and Blue Shield executives have said they would prefer to be treated as insurance companies for regulatory purposes because of what they consider to be impossible expectations and stringent regulatory treatment (Eilers, 1962). It was not until the 1990s that Blue Cross and Blue Shield plans began converting from nonprofit to for-profit status. 8 As seen in the top panel of Table 1, 16 states had a BCBS plan convert to for-profit status. Although 8 of these states were part of Anthem Blue Cross and Blue Shield s conversion in November of 2001, the conversions began in the early 1990s and were spread throughout the decade. Aside from freeing the plans from being the insurers of last resort, becoming a for-profit makes it easier for the plan to raise capital and merge with other, out-of-state plans. Expanding geographically enables a BCBS plan to take advantage of economies of scale, serve multistate employers, diversify risk across markets, and compete 7 Section 101(8) of the Revenue Act of 1936 reads, Civic leagues or organizations not organized for profit but operated exclusively for the promotion of social welfare, or local associations of employees, the membership of which is limited to the employees of a designated person or persons in a particular municipality, and the net earnings of which are devoted exclusively to charitable, educational, or recreational purposes. 8 I denote a plan as converting to for-profit status if it successfully converts or if it transfers the majority of its assets to a for-profit subsidiary. The results are not sensitive to not including the latter type of conversion. I do not treat conversion from non-profit to mutual companies as conversions to for-profit status because mutual companies are owned by their policy holders. Information in Conover et al. (2005) and Consumers Union (2007) was used to determine when plans converted. If a plan converted in the second half of a year, it was considered to have converted the following year. 7

with other insurers that were actively consolidating (Grossman and Strunk, 2001). To attempt to become a for-profit, a BCBS plan submits a conversion plan to its state s Insurance Commissioner or analogous body with regulatory power. One of the main hurdles to conversion is disagreement over the value of the nonprofit s assets and what should be done with them. Because of plans nonprofit status, regulators have often treated plans assets as public property that must be transferred to another public benefit entity. For example, when Blue Cross of California converted, it gave all $3.2 billion of its assets to create the California Endowment and the California HealthCare Foundation. Disagreement over what to do with the plan s assets played a key role in the rejection of conversions in North Carolina, Washington, and Alaska. Conversion plans have also been rejected because of large bonuses that would be paid to BCBS officials: In the CareFirst conversion proposal including BCBS plans in Delaware, Washington D.C., and Maryland executives would have received $120 million in payments. Dafny and Ramanarayanan (2012) provide more detail on why specific conversions were rejected and suggest that the rejection of these conversion plans is unlikely to be related to trends in premiums, medical spending, or health care coverage. For a number of plans, there is a significant delay between when the conversion is first announced and when it is completed. California Blue Cross s conversion began in January of 1993, but was not completely finished until May, 1996; Wisconsin s BCBS plan began the conversion process in June of 1999, but it was not finished until March, 2001. On the other hand, many of the conversions happened quickly; Anthem, which owned BCBS plans in Connecticut, Indiana, Colorado, and other states, only waited eight months for its conversion plan to be approved. Although the conversion process could take multiple years to complete, industry experts suggest that BCBS plans might have begun adopting changes to their business practices before the conversions were finalized (Hall and Conover, 2003). As a result, it is not immediately clear that the date the conversion was completed is the relevant treatment date. In the next section, I formally test the years surrounding conversions to determine whether conversions had an impact and if so, the most likely date 8

that these impacts began. 3 Data and Structural Break Analysis The data used in this article are drawn from the Current Population Survey. The sample runs from 1988 through 2009; years 2010 and later are excluded because the Affordable Care Act has had direct impacts on health insurance markets (e.g. Antwi et al., 2013; Dickstein et al., 2015). The sample is also limited to 22-64 year olds. This avoids near universal coverage of those 65 or older by Medicare as well as the large changes to public programs that provide health insurance to children during my sample period. 9 I focus initially on private health insurance coverage, rather than any health coverage, because a BCBS conversion will affect Medicaid or other public insurance rates primarily through general equilibrium effects. To ease exposition, I will often omit the qualifier private from private health insurance coverage with the understanding that this represents coverage in the private market for health insurance only. Summary statistics for 1990, before any of the conversions were announced, are presented separately for states that will convert (converters) and those that will not convert (non-converters) in Table 2. Approximately 77-78% of the sample had some private health insurance coverage. Private health insurance is obtained through a group (usually through employment) or individually. As seen in Table 2, the great majority of people with private coverage secure it through a group. Just about half of the sample is female, the average age is 40 years old, median income is in the upper $50,000s, approximately 60% of the sample s highest educational attainment is high school, and just under one-quarter of the sample has a college degree. For each variable, the difference across people in states that will convert and states that will not have a conversion are not statistically distinguishable from zero. To help visualize the data, while accounting for trends over time and differences across 9 Some individuals younger than 65 qualify for Medicare coverage (e.g. because of a disability). I exclude consumers younger than 65 who report having Medicare coverage from the analysis. 9

states, I estimate the following equation: insured ist = 10 j= 10 1 [j years from conversion st ] β j + X ist Γ + λ t + λ s + ε ist. (1) insured ist indicates whether person i had health insurance in state s in year t, X ist includes controls for education, income, gender, race, marital status, and age, λ t is a set of year fixed effects, and λ s is a set of state fixed effects. The βs trace out the relative probability of having health insurance across states that did and states that did not have a conversion. Because conversions occurred in different years, the βs are relative to the year of conversion. 10 The point estimates and trend lines are presented in Figure 1. 11 Consumers in states that were going to convert were losing health coverage. In particular, relative to states that would not convert, health coverage fell by approximately 1.7 percentage points in the ten years leading up to the announcement of a conversion. However, within a few years of conversion, that downward trend is stopped and even reversed. In fact, ten years after the announcement of a conversion, states with conversions had health insurance coverage rise by 2 percentage points. It is not surprising that there is some visual ambiguity in exactly which year the change in trend appears to occur. As discussed in Section 2, the conversion process took multiple years for a number of BCBS plans, changes to business practices occurred before the conversion was finalized, and reactions from other insurers might take time to implement. I formally test for a break in trend in the years before and after the actual conversion announcement. For four years on either side of the actual conversion, i.e. τ { 4,..., 4}, I estimate the equation insured ist = β 1 [year relative to conversion st (τ)] + δz st (τ) + X ist Γ + λ t + λ s + ε ist (2) 10 The year relative to conversion has been capped at 10 years before or 10 years after. The omitted category is the year of the conversion. 11 The trend lines are based on regressions of the estimated coefficients on the year relative to the conversion. Separate trends were estimated for the years before the conversion and for the years after the conversion. 10

where year relative to conversion st (τ) is a linear trend in the number of years before or after the hypothetical conversion (denoted by τ), Z st (j) = year relative to conversion st (τ) if t τ (i.e. the hypothetical conversion has occurred) and Z st (j) = 0 otherwise, and the remaining controls are the same as those reported in the equation (1). I estimate this equation nine times (by allowing the hypothetical trend break to be each of the four years before conversion, the conversion year, and the four years after conversion), form the F - statistic based upon ˆδ, and in each case test the null hypothesis of no trend break. The largest of the F -statistics determines the best possible break point as well as the significance of the trend break. This procedure is the Quandt Likelihood Ratio Test which was first described in Quandt (1958, 1960). I use the critical values from Andrews (1993, 2003) to account for the fact that multiple hypotheses are being tested. Figure 2 shows the F -statistic associated with each hypothetical conversion year. For example, if we suppose that the conversion occurred 4 years before the actual conversion, the F -statistic is just under 6. As the hypothetical conversion year approaches the true conversion year, the F -statistics grow steadily. They reach their peak in the actual conversion year at 11.54. This is statistically significant with p < 0.01. As the hypothetical conversion year passes the true conversion year, the F -statistic falls monotonically. Thus, the data suggest that a structural break occurred in exactly the year in which states had BCBS plans convert to for-profit status. 4 Impacts of Conversions on Health Coverage To test for an impact of BCBS conversions on health insurance coverage, I estimate the equation insured ist = years pre st β pre + years post st β post + X ist Γ + λ t + λ s + ε ist (3) 11

where years pre st is a linear trend in the number of years preceding the conversion, years post st is a linear trend in the number of years following the conversion, and X ist, λ t, and λ s are as described previously. I report the estimated impact of conversion five years after the conversion takes place. In particular, I form and report the test statistic 5 5 (β post β pre ). (4) With a regular difference-in-differences regression, the usual identifying assumption is that the trends over time for the treated and untreated groups would have been the same absent the intervention. Because I am identifying off of changes in trends and not levels, I require that the difference in trends across states would have remained constant. Thus, the downward trend before conversion in Figure 1 does not imply the results are biased or spurious. The identifying assumption requires only that the downward trend would have continued in the absence of a conversion. As seen in column 1 of Table 3, if anything, health insurance coverage appears to have risen after the BCBS plan converted to for-profit status. Five years after conversion, coverage rates were 1.7 percentage points higher than they had been. This estimate is highly statistically significant and allows me to reject that health coverage fell following conversion. With just under 15% of this age group uninsured in 1990, the estimated increase in coverage would be a 11% reduction in the uninsurance rate. 12 Another way to get a sense of the magnitude is to estimate how many additional people would have had health insurance in converting states five years after the conversions. By the end of the sample, almost 42 percent of the 166 million 22-64 year olds were in a state with a conversion. If interpreted causally and assuming no crowd-out, the estimated impact five years after conversion suggests that an additional 1.2 million people in those sixteen states would have had health coverage. The estimating equation restricts the impact of a BCBS conversion to a change in trends. 12 This calculation assumes that the estimated increase in coverage is not crowding out other forms of insurance. This possibility is explored below. 12

In column 2, I present results that allow conversions to affect both the level and trend of insurance coverage. 13 As seen in Table 3, the estimated impact on the trends remains unchanged and statistically significant. The estimated level impact is very small in magnitude (0.005) and nowhere near statistically distinguishable from zero. These findings are not surprising given the estimates presented in Figure 1 that show little difference in levels between the pre- and post-conversion periods. This lack of a change in levels is consistent with previous estimates of the average impact of a BCBS conversion on coverage (Conover et al., 2005; Dafny and Ramanarayanan, 2012). In a number of cases, BCBS plans that would eventually convert were merging with or being acquired by other BCBS plans. It could be that the estimated impact of conversion is actually reflecting changes due to the merger and not the conversion itself. To explore this possibility, I create years pre merge st and years post merge st variables which give the number of years before or after the merger analogous to the years pre st and years post st variables for the conversion and include them in the specification. The results are reported in column 3 of Table 3. The estimated impact of conversion actually becomes slightly larger after mergers have been taken into account. This suggests that the results were not simply being driven by mergers. During my sample period, Medicaid eligibility rules were changing. To test whether these changes are driving my results, I include a variable that gives the dollar threshold (in year 2000 dollars) that determines eligibility for Medicaid. This measure was constructed and used in Hamersma and Kim (2013). 14 These thresholds are not available for my entire sample period, only 1996 through 2007. When the sample is restricted to this timeframe, the estimated impact of conversions is a 1.5 percentage point increase in coverage five years after conversion. Column 4 shows the results when the Medicaid threshold variable is included. The estimated impact of conversion returns to a 1.7 percentage point increase, the same 13 Specifically, I include an indicator variable for whether or not the state has a BCBS plan that has converted by that date; this is the standard difference-in-differences estimator. 14 This theshold is not for the expansions of children s coverage studied in Currie and Gruber (1996) and others. Because my sample is all adults, I use the thresholds that determine their eligibility for Medicaid. 13

magnitude as the original estimates that do not directly control for Medicaid eligibility. This suggests that changes to Medicaid programs were not themselves causing the estimated impact of BCBS conversions. The impact of a conversion might vary with a BCBS plan s market share. If BCBS were a fringe competitor, then it s conversion is likely to have little impact; if it is the dominant firm in the market, then it s conversion might have much larger impacts. It is known that available measures of insurer market share are very noisy, to the point that even very large mergers are not readily detectable (Dafny et al., 2011). Despite these data quality issues, I interact the years pre st and years post st variables with BCBS plans market shares in 1990, the year before the first conversion. 15 The estimated impact five years after conversion is presented in Table 3 for a BCBS plan with a 15 percent market share as well as a BCBS plan with a 25 percent market share. The estimates suggest that if a BCBS plan with a 15 percent market share converts, health insurance rates will increase by 1.2 percentage points five years after the conversion; for a BCBS plan with a 25 percent market share, insurance rates will increase by 2.0 percentage points. Although the downward trends observed in Figure 1 would not lead to a spurious positive impact of BCBS conversions, BCBS plans might have chosen to convert based on changes they anticipate happening within the next few years. If those anticipated changes would have lead to increases in coverage rates, then my estimated increases could be spurious correlations instead of causal effects. To address this concern, I use the 9 BCBS plans whose conversions were rejected to determine whether conversion had an impact or was simply proxying for anticipated changes in coverage rates. Because regulators decisions to accept or reject conversions were unrelated to trends in coverage, states with BCBS plans that attempted, but failed, to convert should experience similar increases in their health coverage 15 To my knowledge, the only available state market share data available for 1990 are from the Interstudy reports (Porter et al., 1991). Unfortunately, these data only cover the HMO market and not all types of private health insurance. As a result, I use these data to construct market shares for BCBS plans and note that this is a noisy proxy. Also, note that the state fixed effects are collinear with the measure of BCBS market shares in 1990 and so the association between that variable and insurance rates is not separately identified. 14

rates as states with successful conversions. To test this, I augment equation (3) with separate variables for the number of years before and after a failed conversion (analogous to years post st and years pre st ). This effectively alters the untreated group to states in which there were no attempted conversions, successful or otherwise. The estimated impact of the successful conversions ( 5 ) and unsuccessful conversions ( 5 for failed) are presented in column 2 of Table 4; column 1 reproduces the main result from Table 3 for comparison. After separating out the failed conversions, the estimated impact of a conversion is still a statistically significant 1.7 percentage point increase in coverage after five years. However, the failed conversions do not show any economically or statistically significant impact on coverage. This suggests that the estimated impacts for successful conversions are causal impacts and not spurious correlations. 16 Because I am identifying off of changes in trends and not levels, the estimated impact could be a spurious correlation if states that convert were on differential quadratic trends from states that did not convert. To test this hypothesis, I add linear and quadratic state trends to the specification and re-estimate the impact of conversion. Column 3 presents these results. Adding in the state trends slightly increases the estimated impact of conversion which rules out the possibility that the results were simply being driven by a violation of the identifying assumption. In column 4 of Table 4, I present results from estimating equation (3) without sample weights. The results are again very similar to the original estimates presented in the first column. Taken together, the results in Tables 3 and 4 indicate that BCBS conversions actually increased health insurance coverage. The conversions do not appear to have led to deteriorated market conditions that made coverage unattainable for a larger portion of the population. 16 An alternative approach is to use states with failed attempts at conversion as controls for states with successful conversions as in Dafny and Ramanarayanan (2012). In Appendix Table A.1, I present results in which the sample has been restricted to states that attempted to convert. I show results for the same set of regressions displayed in Table 3. The results from this analysis are extremely similar to those presented in the main text. 15

It is important to note that the external validity of these results is unclear. Because states with attempted conversions were on a different trend from those without, it is unlikely that states without conversions would experience the same increase in health coverage if forced to convert. However, the robustness of the results and the similarity of the estimates when the sample is restricted to only those states that attempted to convert (Appendix Table A.1 suggest a causal impact of conversion for the states with attempted conversions. 5 Impacts on Subgroups and Crowd-out Aggregate categories of insurance might mask changes in coverage to specific groups that tend to have lower insurance rates and are the focus of much of the concern about a lack of insurance coverage (e.g. the less educated or those with lower incomes). In Table 5, I present estimates for the impact of BCBS conversions for subsets of the population. The first row presents the baseline estimates from the full sample for comparison. The next five rows report 5 for different income levels. Instead of lower income individuals being harmed by a BCBS conversion, it appears they are the most likely to see an increase in their probability of being covered. The estimated impact is not only largest in magnitude among the poor, but it is even larger in percentage terms because these consumers are less likely to be insured. The next three rows show the impact of conversion for people with varying levels of education. Those with less education tend to experience larger increases in insurance coverage after a BCBS conversion in percentage terms, though the impact is quite similar in magnitude. And the final three rows of the table show the impact of conversion for three different age groups: 55-64, 35-54, and 34 or younger. The estimated impacts are similar across age groups, though they are somewhat larger in percentage terms for the youngest group. Overall, these results suggest that those lower on the socio-economic status scale are not losing their insurance coverage when BCBS plans convert to for-profit status. If anything, it appears that they become more likely to gain health insurance coverage. 16

In the private market for care, consumers usually obtain health insurance from either a group policy (most often through employer-sponsored plans) or in the individual market. Consumers who are having difficulty finding affordable coverage are most likely looking in the individual market where premiums are higher because of adverse selection and less favorable tax treatment. Even if overall coverage is rising when BCBS plans convert, increases in coverage in one market might mask reductions in coverage in the other. I present graphical evidence on the impacts of conversion in the group and individual markets in Figures 3 and 4. As in Figure 1 for all types of health coverage, these figures present year-by-year estimates of the difference in coverage between converting and non-converting states. Figure 3 shows that there is a clear, downward trend in the group market in the years preceding conversion. After conversion, the trend reverses and group coverage rises. Figure 4 shows that in the individual market, states with conversions do not appear to be on an obvious downward trend prior to their conversions. However, after the conversions, the trend becomes positive. These figures provide suggestive evidence that the conversions increased coverage in both the group and individual markets. To test for these impacts, I estimate equation (3) with the dependent variable replaced by indicators for specific sources of health insurance. In the first column of Table 6, I reproduce the five-year impact of a conversion on having private health insurance coverage. In the second column, I present the results for group health insurance coverage. The estimate suggests that five years after conversion, coverage in the group market is a little more than one percentage point higher than it would have been absent the conversion. This estimate is statistically distinguishable from zero, indicating that we can rule out a reduction in group coverage rates after a BCBS plan s conversion to for-profit status. In column 3, the corresponding estimates for obtaining coverage in the individual market are presented. The point estimate implies a 0.6 percentage point increase in individual coverage, but it is not statistically significant. Because only seven percent of consumers are insured through the individual market, the point estimate would imply a ten percent 17

increase in this type of coverage if it were statistically distinguishable from zero. Taken together, these results suggest that the majority of the increase in coverage that resulted from the conversion was coming through the group market. However, there is no evidence that the individual market shrank, that consumers participating in that market were less likely to obtain insurance after a conversion. Crowd-out (Cutler and Gruber, 1996; Card and Shore-Sheppard, 2004; Wagner, 2015) and crowd-in (Clemens, 2015) are important considerations for policies aimed at affecting health insurance rates. To address the issue of crowd-out directly, column 4 of Table 6 uses a measure of any insurance coverage as the dependent variable. 17 Five years after a conversion, the probability of having any type of health insurance rises by 1.1 percentage points, somewhat less than the increase in private coverage. Because consumers can have insurance from multiple sources, it does not immediately imply that consumers are switching away from Medicaid or other public insurance programs when BCBS plans convert. Column 5 presents results on the impact of BCBS conversions on Medicaid coverage. The estimates suggest that there was essentially no impact of BCBS conversions on Medicaid coverage, a finding reinforced by Figure 5. In both the years preceding and after a conversion, Medicaid coverage rates were fairly flat. It does not appear that consumers were simply switching away from Medicaid to private health insurance plans. Appendix Table A.2 shows that including level changes in the estimated impact of the BCBS conversions does not significantly alter the results presented in Table 6. Overall, the results on having any type of insurance indicate that coverage increased by approximately 1.1 percentage points five years after a BCBS plan conversion. This suggests that in the states with conversions, an extra 764,000 consumers obtained health insurance coverage and the uninsurance rate fell by 7.5% when the BCBS plans converted to for-profit status. 17 There are fewer observations in this column because the weighting variable that is used with the summary measure for any insurance coverage assigns a weight of zero to almost 10% of the sample. Using the same weighting variable as the rest of the analysis produces extremely similar results. 18

6 Conclusion It is difficult to overstate the policy relevance and impacts on consumer behavior of health insurance. The primary aim of the 2010 Affordable Care Act was to increase the number of Americans with health insurance; a central feature of the 2003 Medicaire Modernization Act was aimed at increasing prescription drug coverage for the elderly. Blue Cross and Blue Shield plans are an integral part of the health insurance market, insuring approximately one-third of the market when the conversions were happening. In this paper, I investigate whether Blue Cross and Blue Shield insurance plans conversions from nonprofit to for-profit status affected health insurance coverage. I find that instead of lowering coverage as consumer advocates feared, it appears that conversion actually increased coverage. The estimates suggest that five years after the conversion, private health insurance rates had risen by 1.7 percentage points and that coverage by any type of insurance had increased by 1.1 percentage points. The latter estimate translates to a 7.5% reduction in the uninsured rate or an additional 764,000 people with health insurance in the states that converted. I do not find any evidence that the overall increases in coverage were masking declines in particular subgroups that have been the focus of policy efforts to expand coverage (e.g. people with lower incomes near the Medicaid thresholds). The impacts of conversions appear to be strongest among those with smaller incomes and less education, suggesting that the conversion actually helped these individuals obtain coverage. There are a number of important caveats to these results. First, it is not clear whether cost-sharing, coverage limits, provider networks, and other features of insurance policies changed in conjunction with BCBS conversions. If plan features became less generous, these negative impacts could have spilled over to other consumers in the same insurance pool and reduced their welfare. Second, the results in this paper are based on voluntary BCBS conversions. Plans that chose to convert might have had larger benefits from converting than plans that have not attempted to do so. Actions that are likely to increase the probability 19

of a BCBS conversion, such as the removal of Blue Shield of California s exemptions from state taxes, might not lead to the same impacts as found in this paper. Despite these caveats, the findings provide important evidence of use to regulators who must decide whether conversions to for-profit status should be accepted or rejected. In addition, the results call into question the extent to which BCBS plans were acting as insurers of last resort. Although the evidence is not definitive, studies from the hospital industry often find that nonprofit and for-profit hospitals behave quite similarly (Sloan, 2000). The results in this paper suggest the same could be true for health insurers. 20

References Andrews, D. W. (1993). Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point. Econometrica 61 (4), 821 856. Andrews, D. W. (2003). Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point: A corrigendum. Econometrica 71 (1), 395 397. Antwi, Y. A., A. S. Moriya, and K. Simon (2013). Effects of federal policy to insure young adults: Evidence from the 2010 affordable care act s dependent-coverage mandate. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 5 (4), 1 28. Burns, W. J. (1939). The michigan enabling act for non-profit medical care plans. Law and Contemporary Problems 6 (4), 559 564. Card, D., C. Dobkin, and N. Maestas (2007). The impact of nearly universal insurance coverage on health care: Evidence from medicare. American Economic Review 98 (5), 2242 2258. Card, D. and L. D. Shore-Sheppard (2004). Using discontinuous eligibility rules to identify the effects of the federal medicaid expansions on low-income children. Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (3), 752 766. Clemens, J. (2015). Regulatory redistribution in the market for health insurance. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 7 (2), 109 134. Conover, C. J., M. A. Hall, and J. Ostermann (2005). The impact of blue cross conversions on health spending and the uninsured. Health Affairs 24 (2), 473 482. Consumers Union (2007). Blue cross and blue shield: A historical compilation. Currie, J. and J. Gruber (1996, December). Saving babies: The efficacy and cost of recent changes in medicaid eligibility of pregnant women. Journal of Political Economy 104 (6), 1263 1296. Cutler, D. M. and J. Gruber (1996). Does public insurance crowd out private insurance? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (2), 391 430. Dafny, L. (2010). Are health insurance markets competitive? American Economic Review 100 (4), 1399 1431. Dafny, L., D. Dranove, F. Limbrock, and F. Scott Morton (2011). Data impediments to empirical work on health insurance markets. The BE Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 11 (2). Dafny, L., M. Duggan, and S. Ramanarayanan (2012). Paying a premium on your premium? consolidation in the us health insurance industry. American Economic Review 102 (2), 1161 1185. 21

Dafny, L. and S. Ramanarayanan (2012). Does it matter if your health insurer is forprofit? effects of ownership on premium, insurance coverage, and medical spending. NBER Working Paper No. 18286, 1 53. Dickstein, M. J., M. Duggan, J. Orsini, and P. Tebaldi (2015). The impact of market size and composition on health insurance ppremium: Evidence from the first year of the aca. NBER Working Paper No. 20907. Eilers, R. D. (1962). The fundamental nature of blue cross and blue shield. The Journal of Insurance 29 (3), 385 402. Engelhardt, G. V. and J. Gruber (2011). Medicare part d and the financial protection of the elderly. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 3 (4), 77 102. Finkelstein, A., S. Taubman, B. Wright, M. Bernstein, J. Gruber, J. P. Newhouse, H. Allen, K. Baicker, et al. (2012). The oregon health insurance experiment: Evidence from the first year. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (3), 1057 106. Gross, T. and M. J. Notowidigdo (2011). Health insurance and the consumer bankruptcy decision: Evidence from expansions of medicaid. Journal of Public Economics 95 (7), 767 778. Grossman, J. M. and B. C. Strunk (2001). Blue plans: playing the blues no more. Understanding Health System Change: Local Markets, National Trends, 37 60. Hall, M. A. and C. J. Conover (2003). The impact of blue cross conversions on accessibility, affordability, and the public interest. Milbank Quarterly 81 (4), 509 542. Hamersma, S. and M. Kim (2013). Participation and crowd out: Assessing the effects of parental medicaid expansions. Journal of Health Economics 32 (1), 160 171. Lakdawalla, D. and T. Philipson (2006). The nonprofit sector and industry performance. Journal of Public Economics 90 (8), 1681 1698. Leland, R. G. (1933a). Group hospitalization contracts are insurance contracts. American Medical Association Bulletin 28 (7), 113 116. Leland, R. G. (1933b). Prepayment plans for hospital care. Journal of the American Medical Association 100 (12), 870 873. Manning, W. G., J. P. Newhouse, N. Duan, E. B. Keeler, and A. Leibowitz (1987, June). Health insurance and the demand for medical care: Evidence from a randomized experiment. American Economic Review 77 (3), 251 277. Miller, S. (2012). The effect of insurance on emergency room visits: An analysis of the 2006 massachusetts health reform. Journal of Public Economics 96 (11), 893 908. Norby, M. J. (1939). Hospital service plans: Their contract pprovision and administrative procedures. Law and Contemporary Problems 6 (4), 545 558. 22

Norton, E. C. and D. O. Staiger (1994). How hospital ownership affects access to care for the uninsured. The RAND Journal of Economics 25 (1), 171 185. Picone, G., S.-Y. Chou, and F. Sloan (2002). Are for-profit hospital conversions harmful to patients and to medicare? RAND Journal of Economics 33 (3), 507 523. Porter, M. J., P. A. Ball, S. Bradley, and N. Kraus (1991). The interstudy competitive edge. Technical report, InterStudy. Quandt, R. E. (1958). The estimation of the parameters of a linear regression system obeying two separate regimes. Journal of the American Statistical Association 53 (284), 873 880. Quandt, R. E. (1960). Tests of the hypothesis that a linear regression system obeys two separate regimes. Journal of the American Statistical Association 55 (290), 324 330. Rorem, C. R. (1939). Enabling legislation for non-profit hospital service plans. Law and Contemporary Problems 6 (4), 528 544. Schaeffer, L. D. (1996). Health plan conversions: the view from blue cross of california. Health Affairs 15 (4), 183 187. Silverman, E. and J. Skinner (2004). Medicare upcoding and hospital ownership. Journal of Health Economics 23 (2), 369 389. Sloan, F. A. (2000). Not-for-profit ownership and hospital behavior. Handbook of Health Economics 1, 1141 1174. Terhune, C. (2015, July). California tax officials blast blue shield in audit. Los Angeles Times. Town, R., R. Feldman, and D. Wholey (2004). The impact of ownership conversions on hmo performance. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics 4 (4), 327 342. Wagner, K. L. (2015). Medicaid expansions for the working age disabled: revisiting the crowd-out of private health insurance. Journal of Health Economics 40, 69 82. 23