Are adults better behaved than children? Age, experience, and the endowment effect



Similar documents
SHORT-SELLING AND THE WTA- WTP GAP. Shosh Shahrabani, Tal Shavit and Uri Ben-Zion. Discussion Paper No July 2007

Evidence of the Endowment Effect in Stock Market Order Placement

Love the One You re With: The Endowment Effect in the Dating Market

Risk Attitudes of Children and Adults: Choices Over Small and Large Probability Gains and Losses

Chapter 19 The Chi-Square Test

The Willingness to Pay Willingness to Accept Gap, the Endowment Effect, Subject Misconceptions, and Experimental Procedures for Eliciting Valuations

Estimating the returns to education using the newest current population survey education questions

Implicit versus explicit ranking: On inferring ordinal preferences for health care programmes based on differences in willingness-to-pay

Curriculum Map Statistics and Probability Honors (348) Saugus High School Saugus Public Schools

Chi Square Tests. Chapter Introduction

A Hands-On Exercise Improves Understanding of the Standard Error. of the Mean. Robert S. Ryan. Kutztown University

INVESTORS DECISION TO TRADE STOCKS AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY. Sharon Shafran, Uri Ben-Zion and Tal Shavit. Discussion Paper No

The information content of lagged equity and bond yields

Market efficiency in greyhound racing: empirical evidence of absence of favorite-longshot bias

Evaluation of the MIND Research Institute s Spatial-Temporal Math (ST Math) Program in California

Working Paper Series No. 12

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES BEHAVIORAL INDIFFERENCE CURVES. John Komlos. Working Paper

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013)

Simulating Chi-Square Test Using Excel

the general concept down to the practical steps of the process.

Technological Tools to Learn and Teach Mathematics and Statistics

Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) Using Minitab

Endowment Effects in Bundles

How To Check For Differences In The One Way Anova

Financial Assets Behaving Badly The Case of High Yield Bonds. Chris Kantos Newport Seminar June 2013

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Insurance Demand and Prospect Theory. by Ulrich Schmidt

Insurance Decisions for Low-Probability Losses

Lesson 1: Readiness for Fractions (5 Bars and Fraction Bingo) Your group may select elements from one or both lesson plans.

C. Wohlin, "Is Prior Knowledge of a Programming Language Important for Software Quality?", Proceedings 1st International Symposium on Empirical

Contingency Tables and the Chi Square Statistic. Interpreting Computer Printouts and Constructing Tables

The Willingness to Pay, Accept and Retire

Do Supplemental Online Recorded Lectures Help Students Learn Microeconomics?*

Ethnic Discrimination in the Marketplace of Small Business Transfers

Mind on Statistics. Chapter 12

Statistical Impact of Slip Simulator Training at Los Alamos National Laboratory

STATISTICS 8, FINAL EXAM. Last six digits of Student ID#: Circle your Discussion Section:

Topic 8. Chi Square Tests

POL 451: Statistical Methods in Political Science

Getting Used to Risks: Reference Dependence and Risk Inclusion

Statistics 100A Homework 4 Solutions

Crosstabulation & Chi Square

Prospect Theory Ayelet Gneezy & Nicholas Epley

Knut Ole Lysø Associate professor. Sor-Trondelag University College. Teacher Education. Trondheim, Norway

Voluntary Provision of a Public Good

DOES HOUSEHOLD DEBT HELP FORECAST CONSUMER SPENDING? Robert G. Murphy Department of Economics Boston College Chestnut Hill, MA 02467

CONSUMER BEHAVIOR COURSE OUTLINE AND READING LIST

Summary of Uniform CPA Examination Candidate Test-Taking and Pass-Fail Patterns in the First Ten Windows of Computer-Based Testing (CBT) (04Q2-06Q3)

Journal of Experimental Social Psychology

2013 MBA Jump Start Program. Statistics Module Part 3

Anomalies: The Endowment Effect, Loss Aversion, and Status Quo Bias. by Daniel Kahneman, Jack L. Knetsch, Richard H. Thaler

M E M O R A N D U M (EARLY CHILDHOOD) GRADUATE Competitive Admission to the Teacher Education Program

Two-sample inference: Continuous data

If your schedule allows you might consider joining ROTC.

Homework Activities for Kindergarten

2002 Worcester Public Schools (WPS) Benchmarks for Grade SC.TE.05 Develop a knowledge and understanding of the metric measurement system.

MATH 140 HYBRID INTRODUCTORY STATISTICS COURSE SYLLABUS

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

Chapter 6: The Information Function 129. CHAPTER 7 Test Calibration

Transitions Math Project Placement Survey Whatcom Community College Fall 2005

Individual Behavior and Beliefs in Experimental Parimutuel Betting Markets

Volume 30, Issue 4. Market Efficiency and the NHL totals betting market: Is there an under bias?

Working Paper Game form misconceptions are not necessary for a willingness-to-pay vs. willingness-to-accept gap

Answer: (a) Since we cannot repeat men on the committee, and the order we select them in does not matter, ( )

Fairfield Public Schools

A/B Testing and Analysis with Cascade Server

MAKING MATH MORE FUN BRINGS YOU FUN MATH GAME PRINTABLES FOR HOME OR SCHOOL

Clocking In Facebook Hours. A Statistics Project on Who Uses Facebook More Middle School or High School?

Different Conceptions in Software Project Risk Assessment

9. Sampling Distributions

Comparison of frequentist and Bayesian inference. Class 20, 18.05, Spring 2014 Jeremy Orloff and Jonathan Bloom

Calculating P-Values. Parkland College. Isela Guerra Parkland College. Recommended Citation

An Endowment Effect for Risk: Experimental Tests of Stochastic Reference Points

MULTIPLE REGRESSION AND ISSUES IN REGRESSION ANALYSIS

South Carolina. 180 The Proficiency Illusion

CONTENTS OF DAY 2. II. Why Random Sampling is Important 9 A myth, an urban legend, and the real reason NOTES FOR SUMMER STATISTICS INSTITUTE COURSE

Have several sets of truck pieces (see below for list of truck pieces) cut out for the group.

Educational research on teaching the nature and process of science

FIRST GRADE Number and Number Sense

Course Text. Required Computing Software. Course Description. Course Objectives. StraighterLine. Business Statistics

A STUDY OF WHETHER HAVING A PROFESSIONAL STAFF WITH ADVANCED DEGREES INCREASES STUDENT ACHIEVEMENT MEGAN M. MOSSER. Submitted to

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Statistical tests for SPSS

SCRATCHING THE SURFACE OF PROBABILITY. Robert J. Russell, University of Paisley, UK

An Evaluation of Kansas City Reading Programs for Turn the Page Kansas City

Predicting the Performance of a First Year Graduate Student

UNIT: PSYCHOLOGICAL RESEARCH

Post Master s School Counseling Specialization

INTRODUCTION TO CREDIT

CHANCE ENCOUNTERS. Making Sense of Hypothesis Tests. Howard Fincher. Learning Development Tutor. Upgrade Study Advice Service

GENDER BASED PRESCRIPTIONS Evidence for altruism

Student Name GRADE. Mississippi Curriculum Test, Second Edition PRACTICE TEST BOOK MATHEMATICS

Business Statistics. Successful completion of Introductory and/or Intermediate Algebra courses is recommended before taking Business Statistics.

BUS/ST 350 Exam 3 Spring 2012

USING CURRENT POPULATION SURVEY DATA TO EXAMINE SCHOOL ADMINISTRATORS CAREERS

Important Steps to Becoming a Masters of Social Work (MSW)

Poisson Models for Count Data

Data Mining Techniques Chapter 5: The Lure of Statistics: Data Mining Using Familiar Tools

Transcription:

Economics Letters 70 (2001) 175 181 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Are adults better behaved than children? Age, experience, and the endowment effect William T. Harbaugh *, Kate Krause, Lise Vesterlund a, b c a University of Oregon, Department of Economics, Eugene, OR 97403-1285, USA b Department of Economics, University of New Mexico, 1915 Roma NE/Economics Bldg., Albuquerque 87131-1101, NM, USA c Department of Economics, 260 Heady Hall, Iowa State University, Ames IA 50011-1070 and Harvard Business School, 187 Boker Library ( West) Boston, MA 02163, USA Received 18 October 1999; received in revised form 19 May 2000; accepted 15 June 2000 Abstract We find that large increases in age do not reduce the endowment effect, supporting the hypothesis that people have reference-dependent preferences which are not changed by repeated experience getting and giving up goods. 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Endowment effect; Prospect theory; Reference dependence; Experimental economics JEL classification: D1 1. Introduction The minimum compensation people are willing to accept (WTA) in return for giving up a good they already possess exceeds the amount that they are willing to pay (WTP) to acquire the same good. When offered an opportunity to trade, people tend to keep the good that they have. This endowment effect is particularly large when people are asked hypothetical questions about values of non-market goods, but it has also been found in experiments involving real transactions with common market goods, as well as in real life decisions. One explanation for the endowment effect is that people have reference-dependent preferences, defined over changes in the consumption of goods rather than over levels. Another is that this reluctance to trade is simply a mistake. If it is a mistake, then people who exhibit endowment effects are trading too little, and losing out on beneficial trades. As people gain experience in markets they should learn from these mistakes, make them less frequently, and the endowment effect should *Corresponding author. Tel.: 11-541-346-1244; fax: 1-541-346-1243. E-mail address: harbaugh@oregon.uoregon.edu (W.T. Harbaugh). 0165-1765/ 01/ $ see front matter 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S0165-1765(00)00359-1

176 W.T. Harbaugh et al. / Economics Letters 70 (2001) 175 181 decrease. On the other hand, if preferences are reference-dependent, the reluctance to trade is not a mistake, and experience should not lead to a reduction. Unfortunately the literature does not agree on how the endowment effect changes with experience. Knez et al. (1985), Coursey et al. (1987), Brookshire and Coursey (1987) and Shogren et al. (1994) have used repetition to examine how reported WTA and WTP change as subjects gain familiarity with the experimental protocol. While they found that the measures converge, Kahneman et al. (1990) used a different incentive-compatible mechanism and found that it does not. Besides being inconclusive, we argue that this line of research addresses whether subjects learn to respond to a particular mechanism rather than the more general question of how real world experience with transactions changes the endowment effect. In this paper we examine the effect of changes in actual market experience on the endowment effect. In order to obtain large variations in market experience, we use a subject pool that includes both five to 10-year-old grade school children and college undergraduates. The accumulated market experience of a typical 5-year-old is substantially different from that of a 10-year-old, and the difference between these children and undergraduates is even more dramatic. For example, only 9% of our 3rd and 5th grade subjects reported that they bought things with their own money on a weekly basis. 2. Experimental design Our experiments were conducted during the fall and winter of 1998 on a total of 163 subjects from New Mexico. We collected data on 125 children from kindergarten, third-grade, and fifth-grade classrooms at a public elementary school, and from 38 undergraduates in introductory economics classes at the University of New Mexico. While we did not collect data on individual ages, with rare exceptions children start kindergarten at age 5, and start fifth grade at age 10. The undergraduate subjects average age was 20. We used a simple protocol from Knetsch (1989). Subjects were given one good and then asked if they wanted to keep it or trade it for another. This procedure was repeated for three of the four pairs of goods described in Table 1. Children chose from the first three pairs of goods, and undergraduates Table 1 The goods Pair ID Description Letter 1 A Key chain with a toy alien attached B Small irregularly shaped super ball 2 C Mechanical pencil D Highlighter marker 3 E Six-function electronic calculator F Box of eight colored overwriting markers 4 G Chocolate bars (2) H Coffee mug

W.T. Harbaugh et al. / Economics Letters 70 (2001) 175 181 177 from the last three. The children s goods were chosen because they were familiar, widely available in stores, and appealed to both boys and girls. The goods in a pair were roughly of equivalent value. During the experiment it was clear that the appeal to children of the goods increased from the first to the third pair. The undergraduates were not given the first pair of children s goods, since we doubted these goods would appeal to adults. Their last pair was a choice between two 100-g Swiss chocolate bars, or a coffee mug with the university logo on it, similar to the goods that Knetsch and others have used. We randomly divided the subjects in each classroom into two groups. Subjects in one group were given one good, and those in the other group were given the other good. Along with the item, each subject was given a tag. A sample of the other good was then passed among each group. After inspecting the item, the students chose to either keep their original good (by placing a blue sticker on the tag it came with) or to trade it for the other good (by placing a yellow sticker on the tag). The second and third rounds were played exactly as the first, but with different pairs of goods. Every subject and every class received the pairs of goods in the same order, except for the difference for undergraduates noted above. The protocol is available from the authors. 3. Results When given a choice between two goods, an endowment effect exists if the probability that a person chooses, say, good A is higher if they were initially endowed with good A than if they were endowed with good B. We define the endowment boost as the average across the two goods of the increase in the likelihood that a person chooses a good when they are endowed with it, relative to being endowed with the other good. That is, if pjui denotes the probability of choosing good j when endowed with good i, then the endowment boost equals: 1 p1u1 1 p2u2 ]]] 1]]] 2 p 2 p 1u2 2u1 The children s choices for each of the three pairs are presented in Tables 2 4. The rows indicate the good that a subject was endowed with, while the columns indicate which good they chose. We report both n ij, the number of subjects endowed with good i who choose good j, and p jui, the probability a Table 2 Children s choices: Pair 1 A B Endowment A 24 ( paua50.40) 36 ( pbua50.60) 60 B 6 (paub50.092) 59 ( pbub50.91) 65 30 95 125 Endowment boost52.9 p-value of hypothesis of no endowment effect50.000

178 W.T. Harbaugh et al. / Economics Letters 70 (2001) 175 181 Table 3 Children s choices: Pair 2 C D Endowment C 47 ( pcuc50.76) 15 ( pduc50.24) 62 D 30 (pcud50.48) 33 ( pdud50.52) 63 77 48 125 Endowment boost51.9 p-value of hypothesis of no endowment effect50.002 person chooses good j, conditional on having been endowed with good i. We say an endowment effect exists if the endowment boost is greater than 1. Formally we use Fisher s exact test of the null 1 hypothesis that endowment has no effect on which good a person chooses. The probability values for the test statistics and the endowment boost are reported for each pair. For every good, the likelihood of choosing the good increases when the child is endowed with it. Fisher s exact test rejects the null hypothesis of no endowment effect for all pairs. Furthermore, the effect is quite large. In Table 2, for example, the first row shows that 24 of the 60 subjects who were endowed with good A kept it, while 36 switched to good B. The second row shows that of the 65 subjects who were endowed with good B, six switched to A and 59 kept B. While good A was not very popular relative to good B, it was considerably more likely to be chosen when a subject was endowed with it than when not, and the same was true of good B. For the A and B pair of goods, children on average are 2.9 times more likely to choose the good they are endowed with than the good they are not. The analogous number is 1.9 and 2.5 for the subsequent pairs. We are unable to say anything about the effect of repetition on the size of the endowment effect for two reasons. First, it is possible that any effect is driven by differences in the pairs of goods, rather than by repetition. Table 4 Children s choices: Pair 3 E F Endowment E 39 ( peue50.70) 17 ( pfue50.30) 56 F 19 (peuf50.28) 50 ( pfuf50.72) 69 58 67 125 Endowment boost52.5 p-value of hypothesis of no endowment effect50.000 1 This test, from Fisher (1925), is done by using the binomial distribution to calculate the exact probability of getting the observed results, or results more contradictory to the null, if the null is true.

Table 5 Undergraduates choices: Pair 2 W.T. Harbaugh et al. / Economics Letters 70 (2001) 175 181 179 C Endowment C 12 ( pcuc50.63) 7 ( pduc50.37) 19 D 3 (pcud50.16) 16 ( pdud50.84) 19 15 23 38 Endowment boost53.1 p-value of hypothesis of no endowment effect50.003 D Second, the Zelen test has a probability value of 0.51, so we cannot reject the hypothesis that the 2 endowment boosts are equivalent across goods. Next we look at the data from our undergraduate subjects. Tables 5 7 show that, as with the children, an endowment effect exists for all three pairs of goods. We then examine whether age is related to the endowment effect. Table 8 shows the endowment boosts for all four pairs of goods by grade level so that we can look at differences in the boosts by age. While the pair 1 boost for the kindergartners is undefined because none of the subjects endowed with good B switch, the endowment effect is obviously large. While the third-graders appear to be the least susceptible to the endowment effect, their behavior is not significantly different than that of the other age groups. Formally, for pairs 1, 2, and 3, the Zelen test cannot reject the null hypothesis that Table 6 Undergraduates choices: Pair 3 E Endowment E 9 ( peue50.47) 10 ( pfue50.53) 19 F 2 (peuf50.11) 17 ( pfuf50.89) 19 11 27 38 Endowment boost53.1 p-value of hypothesis of no endowment effect50.013 F 2 The Zelen test (Zelen, 1971) is an exact test, derived from the binomial probabilities, for the homogeneity of the odds-ratios: n11 n21 ]]] n11 1 n12 n21 1 n22 ]]] n Y]]] 12 n22 ]]] ]]] n11 1 n12 n21 1 n22 across treatments (or pairs, in our case), where n ij is the number of observations in row i, column j for a given treatment.

180 W.T. Harbaugh et al. / Economics Letters 70 (2001) 175 181 Table 7 Undergraduates choices: Pair 4 G Endowment G 12 ( pgug50.63) 7 ( phug50.37) 19 H 2 (pguh50.11) 17 ( phuh50.89) 19 14 24 38 Endowment boost54.2 p-value of hypothesis of no endowment effect50.003 H the endowment effects are the same for all grades. The probability values are 0.091, 0.16, and 0.75, respectively. Only the test for pair 1 is even marginally significant. 4. Conclusion We examine the endowment effect in children and adults and find strong evidence for the existence of the effect in all our subjects. We find no evidence that the endowment effect decreases with age. Fifth-graders are, on average, twice as old as kindergartners and have accumulated substantially more market experience. Despite this age difference, the strength of the endowment effect did not differ significantly between the two groups. This lack of a difference is even more striking when comparing children and college undergraduates. The undergraduates are four times as old as the kindergartners, and are far more familiar with shopping, trading, and getting and giving up goods. Yet the endowment effect for the two groups is nearly the same. Of course, there are many differences between children and undergraduates besides market experience, and so we cannot be totally sure that there might not be an age related difference in some other variable that is offsetting the effect of increased market experience. Still, this possibility seems remote. Table 8 Endowment boosts by grade Grade a Endowment boosts Pair 1 Pair 2 Pair 3 Pair 4 Average K * 2.5 3.7 ** 3 1.5 1.1 2.0 ** 1.5 5 6.6 3.0 2.2 ** 3.9 Undergraduate ** 3.1 3.1 4.2 3.5 Average 3.2 2.8 4.2 p-value of test that endowment boosts are the same across grades 0.091 0.16 0.75 ** a p 1u1 * Undefined, because n 50, but] 5 1.5. ** n.a. 21 p 1u2

W.T. Harbaugh et al. / Economics Letters 70 (2001) 175 181 181 We argue that these results are inconsistent with the argument that the endowment effect is a mistake or a transitory anomaly related to market inexperience. If that were true, then the relatively unsophisticated children would have kept their initial endowments at higher rates than did the adults in this study. We believe the most reasonable interpretation of these results is that they support reference-dependent preferences. The endowment effect appears to be a real part of preferences, rather than a mistake that diminishes with experience and learning. Acknowledgements We thank the principal, teachers and students who made this project possible. We also thank Rachel Croson and seminar participants at the 1998 ESA meetings for helpful comments; John Hobbs for his work on an earlier version of this project; and Josha Antos and Kristin Hutchens for expert research assistance. NSF Grants SBR-9810847 and SBR-9810835 funded this research. References Brookshire, D.S., Coursey, D.L., 1987. Measuring the value of a public good: an empirical comparison of elicitation procedures. American Economic Review 77 (4), 554 566. Coursey, D.L., Hovis, J.J., Schulze, W.D., 1987. The disparity between willingness to accept and willingness to pay measures of value. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (3), 679 690. Fisher, R.A., 1925. Statistical Methods for Research Workers. Oliver and Boyd, Edinburgh. Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J.L., Thaler, R., 1990. Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy 98 (6), 1325 1348. Knetsch, J.L., 1989. The endowment effect and evidence of nonreversible indifference curves. American Economic Review 79 (5), 1277 1284. Knez, P., Smith, V.L., Williams, A.W., 1985. Individual rationality, market rationality, and value estimation. American Economic Review 75 (2), 397 402. Shogren, J.F., Shin, S.Y., Hayes, D., Kliebenstein, J.B., 1994. Resolving differences in willingness to pay and willingness to accept. American Economic Review 84, 255 270. Zelen, M., 1971. The analysis of several 232 contingency tables. Biometrika 58 (1), 129 137.