A HOW-TO GUIDE: LABOUR MARKET AND UNEMPLOYMENT STATISTICS



Similar documents
A HOW-TO GUIDE: UNDERSTANDING AND MEASURING INFLATION

Sharp Declines in Underemployment for College Graduates

A HOW-TO GUIDE: FINDING AND INTERPRETING GDP STATISTICS

Underutilization in U.S. Labor Markets

Labor Market and Unemployment Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D.

Discussion Paper: Conceptual difficulties in measuring retirement

Currently 32 million, Canada s population is

Impact of the recession

The workforce in the United States is

Trends in part-time and temporary work

13.8% Inflation-adjusted GDP (billions) Cumulative growth 2009 to Q Exhibit 1 Steady U.S. Economic Growth After a Severe Recession $17,000

Lars Osberg. Department of Economics Dalhousie University 6214 University Avenue Halifax, Nova Scotia B3H 3J5 CANADA

Regional Profile Labor Force, Employment and Unemployment in Region 5

New York State Employment Trends

Careers Advisory Service

Recent reports of corporate downsizing,

For Immediate Release

CHAPTER 8. Practise Problems

The Recession of

Left Behind: DC s Economic Recovery Is Not Reaching All Residents By Ed Lazere and Marco Guzman 1

Labor Market and Demographic Analysis: A National Picture of Short-term Employment Growth by Skill

2015 Global Partner Compensation System Survey

ANTHONY P. CARNEVALE TAMARA JAYASUNDERA BAN CHEAH THE COLLEGE ADVANTAGE: WEATHERING THE ECONOMIC STORM EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

UNIVERSITY WORKS employment report

Over the past several years, Americans have

Labour Market Assessment Ottawa, Canada March 25,

Field of Degree and Earnings by Selected Employment Characteristics: 2011

Chapter 7 Employment and Unemployment Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Sources of Health Insurance and Characteristics of the Uninsured: Analysis of the March 2012 Current Population Survey

THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY

Undergraduate Degree Completion by Age 25 to 29 for Those Who Enter College 1947 to 2002

Fort McPherson. Atlanta, GA MSA. Drivers of Economic Growth February Prepared By: chmuraecon.com

Women s Participation in Education and the Workforce. Council of Economic Advisers

Review of Card Surcharging: A Consultation Document

Table of Contents. A. Aggregate Jobs Effects...3. B. Jobs Effects of the Components of the Recovery Package...5. C. The Timing of Job Creation...

The Labor Market Problems of Massachusetts Workers in the Recovery from the Great Recession: The Great Socioeconomic Divergence

Transfer income/payments : payments received by persons from the federal government in the form of cash social service benefits such as pensions.

Aboriginal People and the Labour Market: Estimates from the Labour Force Survey,

Who wants to be an entrepreneur?

Long Island is rapidly losing its lead in private health care coverage. That distinctive mark of middle class success - private

Disability and Job Mismatches in the Australian Labour Market

Labour Force Survey: Q2/2015

Answer: A. Answer: A.16. Use the following to answer questions 6-9:

HELP Interest Rate Options: Equity and Costs

The Decline in Student Applications to Computer Science and IT Degree Courses in UK Universities. Anna Round University of Newcastle

Creating Opportunity or Entrenching Disadvantage? ACT Labour Market Data

LEVEL ECONOMICS. ECON2/Unit 2 The National Economy Mark scheme. June Version 1.0/Final

COLLEGE ENROLLMENT AND WORK ACTIVITY OF 2014 HIGH SCHOOL GRADUATES

Choice Of Health Insurance And The Two-Worker Household by Claudia L. Schur and Amy K. Taylor

HOW BAD IS THE CURRENT RECESSION? LABOUR MARKET DOWNTURNS SINCE THE 1960s

ABOUT FINANCIAL RATIO ANALYSIS

Sources of Health Insurance and Characteristics of the Uninsured: Analysis of the March 2010 Current Population Survey

Labour Market Outcomes of Young Postsecondary Graduates, 2005 to 2012

On March 11, 2010, President Barack

Objectives for Class 24: The Business Cycle and Unemployment. Class 24 The Business Cycle and Unemployment (latest revision October 2004)

Alaska Employer Health-Care Benefits: A Survey of Alaska Employers

ICI RESEARCH PERSPECTIVE

Project LINK Meeting New York, October Country Report: Australia

The Training Needs of Older Workers

When Will the U.S. Job Market Recover?

The following text represents the notes on which Mr. Parry based his remarks. 1998: Issues in Monetary Policymaking

Estimating Lost Secondary Childcare in Wrongful Death Cases Using Data From the American Time Use Survey (ATUS) Mark W. Erwin, M.A., J.D.

3. Understanding the part-time RAB charge

Quality of life in the Spanish workplace

Recent Developments in Interest Rates on Bank Lending

In the current e-commerce boom,

WAGE REPORTS FOR WORKERS COVERED BY FEDERAL OLD-AGE INSURANCE IN 1937

The self-employed and pensions

Statistical Bulletin. Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings, 2014 Provisional Results. Key points

RECRUITMENT OF HIGHLY SKILLED LABOUR ABROAD OECD COUNTRIES THE PRACTICE OF SELECTED. DICE Reports

4. Work and retirement

4. The statistics and data on unemployment are gathered and reported: A) daily. B) weekly. C) monthly. D) yearly.

Employment Relations Comment

Employment Recovery in Urban Areas following the Great Recession

Grand Challenges Making Drill Down Analysis of the Economy a Reality. John Haltiwanger

CENTER FOR LABOR MARKET STUDIES

The impact of the recession on the labour market

Employment and Wages for Alberta Workers with a Post-Secondary Education

An Evaluation of the Possible

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES THE AMERICAN ACADEMY OF ACTUARIES RETIREMENT PLAN PREFERENCES SURVEY REPORT OF FINDINGS. January 2004

Unemployment and Economic Recovery

A Working Model for Student Success: The Tennessee Technology Centers

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE CBO. The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2008 and 2009

Dualization and crisis. David Rueda

Econ 202 Section 2 Final Exam

Beware the Insurance Model :

News. The Real Wage. Wages, Labor Markets and Unemployment. Organizing Theme Five Labor Market Trends

Non Farm Payroll Employment Developments among States during the Great Recession and Jobless Recovery

LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY AND UNIT LABOUR COST Economic development Employment Core indicator

The Developer Hiring Landscape US Insight

Fort Hays State University

How s Life in Australia?

Deficits as far as the eye can see

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

INTRODUCTION TO MACROECONOMICS MIDTERM- SAMPLE QUESTIONS

Marginal Costing and Absorption Costing

Personal debt ON LABOUR AND INCOME

Implications of MBA Durability for Providers of Masters in Business Administration Degrees

How To Understand The Results Of The Operations Survey

Transcription:

A HOW-TO GUIDE: LABOUR MARKET AND UNEMPLOYMENT STATISTICS By Jim Stanford Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives, 2008 Non-commercial use and reproduction, with appropriate citation, is authorized. This guide provides a simple introduction to various common measurements of the labour market: employment, unemployment, and the labour force. It also discusses some of the problems with conventional measurements of unemployment. Aggregate labour market behaviour and statistics are discussed in more detail in Chapter 13 of Economics for Everyone. Definitions: The following are simple definitions for the various terms used in the examples below: Labour Force: The total population of working-age people who are willing and able to work, and who hence have officially entered the labour market. The labour force includes individuals who are employed, and those who are actively seeking employment. The labour force is also referred to as labour supply. Participation Rate: The proportion of working-age individuals who decide to participate in the labour force, by either being employed or actively seeking work. The precise definition of what constitutes actively seeking work varies from one country to another, and this can affect measurements of the labour force and unemployment. Employment: Employment is a specific form of work, in which the worker performs their labour for someone else in return for a money wage or salary. Employment can also be thought of as labour demand. Employment Rate: This measures the share of working age adults are actually employed in a paying position. The employment rate can be a better indicator of the strength of labour markets than the unemployment rate (since the unemployment rate depends on whether or not a nonworking individual is considered to be in the labour force). 1

Unemployment: Individuals who would like to be employed, and are actively seeking work, but cannot find a job, are considered officially unemployed. Individuals who are not working, but not actively looking for work, are considered to be outside of the labour force, and hence don t count as officially unemployed. Unemployment Rate: The number of unemployed people measured as a proportion of the labour force. Obtaining Labour Market Data: Data on labour markets, employment, and unemployment are readily available from the web sites of virtually all national statistical agencies, usually on a monthly basis. Here are the links to labour market data for the major Anglo-Saxon economies: U.S.: Bureau of Labor Statistics, www.bls.gov. U.K.: U.K. Statistics Authority, www.statistics.gov.uk. Canada: Statistics Canada, www.statscan.ca. Australia: Australian Bureau of Statistics, www.abs.gov.au. Measuring Employment and Unemployment: Measuring the level of employment in an economy (or, alternatively, labour demand) is relatively straightforward. Statisticians generate an estimate of the number of individuals who are working for money in the overall economy. They gather this information by conducting statistical surveys. Generally, two broad survey approaches are used. Household surveys involve contacting a large random sample of households and interviewing individuals about their employment activity, hours worked, wages, etc. Establishment surveys involve contacting employers (including all large firms, and a random sample of smaller firms) to collect information on how many workers they employ, how long they work, and how much they get paid. Household surveys are usually considered somewhat more comprehensive and accurate, but provide less industry-specific data, than establishment surveys. Employment data can then be broken down into several categorizations: full-time and part-time; waged, salaried, or self-employed; private sector or public sector; and employment by industry. Measuring labour supply, on the other hand, is a little bit trickier. Whereas it is fairly clear whether an individual is employed or not, it is harder and more arbitrary to define whether an individual is in fact supplying their labour to the market (especially if they are not employed). This creates some inherent difficulties in measuring labour supply and hence measuring unemployment (which represents the difference between labour supply and labour demand). 2

Labour supply measures are based on household surveys. Individuals are asked whether they are working. If not, they are asked if they would like to be working, and if they are undertaking active efforts to find a job. If they would like to work and are looking for work, they are considered to be in the labour market although not successfully employed. But that classification is necessarily arbitrary. Different statistical agencies utilize different concepts of active job search, and this can increase or decrease the apparent size of the labour force (and hence the apparent level of unemployment). Official unemployment therefore depends on the strictness of the definition of whether a nonemployed individual is indeed actively seeking employment. A convenient way to reduce apparent unemployment, therefore, is simply to change that definition setting a higher hurdle for someone in order to be considered officially unemployed. (Indeed, that is exactly what statistical agencies in the U.K. and the U.S. did in the early 1980s, to defuse widespread popular anger over the very high unemployment levels that initially resulted from the implementation of neoliberal monetary policies.) Once measures have been attained of total labour supply and total labour demand, the following important variables can be calculated: Participation Rate: Labour supply as a proportion of the working age population. Unemployment: Labour supply minus labour demand. Unemployment Rate: Unemployment as a proportion of the labour force (ie. labour supply). Employment Rate: Employment as a proportion of the working age population. When unemployment (and hence the unemployment rate) is high, the labour market is considered slack, with abundant numbers of unutilized workers. Large numbers of people who want to work cannot find jobs. Competition for scarce jobs will tend to drive down wages, and make workers feel more insecure (and hence enhance the sense of labour discipline in the workplace as described in more detail in Chapter 8 of Economics for Everyone, on the employment relationship). 3

A Numerical Example: To see concretely how these labour market concepts fit together, consider U.S. labour market data for the year 2007, as summarized by the Bureau of Labor Statistics: 1. Working Age Population (civilians, aged 16 and over) 231,867,000 2. Labour Force (working or actively seeking work) 153,124,000 3. Participation Rate (2 3) 66.0% 4. Employed 146,047,000 5. Employment Rate (4 1) 63.0% 6. Unemployed (2 4) 7,078,000 7. Unemployment Rate (6 2) 4.6% Disguised Unemployment: As discussed in Chapter 13 of Economics for Everyone, official unemployment statistics may not accurately reflect the tightness of the labour market, because of the arbitrary nature of the household labour force surveys discussed above. Someone may fail the statisticians test of actively seeking work. They are hence excluded from official measurements of the labour market. Yet they are still not working, and may very well be willing to work if there was a realistic chance of obtaining suitable employment. In this manner, official unemployment statistics clearly understate the true degree of slackness in labour markets. And central bankers and other policy-makers who wring their hands over unemployment rates that are too low (hence sparking their fears of accelerating wage inflation) are overlooking (perhaps deliberately) these disguised pools of unemployment. Significant unemployment almost always exists in capitalism indeed, it is an explicit aim of neoliberal policy to maintain a certain, desirable cushion of unemployment in order to discipline workers and suppress wage demands. And labour markets almost always embody pools of unemployed or underemployed labour, that are much larger than implied in official labour market statistics: Discouraged Workers: Individuals with no realistic chance of finding a job, will naturally give up actively seeking one. They thus magically disappear from the official unemployment rolls! The extent of discouraged workers can be seen, especially during times of recession, in the decline in participation rates which typically accompanies prolonged labour market weakness. To adjust unemployment statistics for this effect, we can calculate an adjusted measure of the labour force by applying the pre-recession peak in labour force 4

participation to the current working age population. The difference between that adjusted labour force, and the officially measured labour force, is an indication of the extent to which individuals have given up looking and hence provides a rough indicator of the pool of discouraged workers. We can apply this methodology to the U.S. labour market data for 2007 summarized above. Labour force participation in 2007 was 66.0 percent. That was lower than the peak levels of 67.1 percent attained in 2000 (before the recession that began in 2001, and the subsequent slow and uneven recovery). If the participation rate had regained its peak by 2007, an additional 2.6 million workers would be officially part of the labour force. Unemployment would equal almost 10 million, instead of 7 million, and the unemployment rate would equal 6.3% instead of 4.6%. (Another way to estimate the number of discouraged workers is to include a question on the household labour force survey asking if non-participating individuals would be willing to work if jobs were available; a few national statistical agencies do this.) Involuntary Part-time Workers: Some workers would prefer to hold a steady full-time job, but are forced (out of necessity) to accept part-time work. This represents another underutilized segment of the labour market since their collective actual hours of work are far less than their desired hours of work. Household labour force surveys in some countries ask parttime workers if they would prefer to be working full-time. Other Underutilized Workers: There are other groups of workers who may be considered officially employed, but whose work situation does not at all reflect their full employment potential. This would include workers occupying positions that do not utilize their skills and training, as well as many nominally self-employed workers who undertake marginal, poorly-paid ventures in order to support themselves through periods of unemployment. Many of these individuals could be mobilized to fill more appropriate job vacancies should they arise. Untapped Labour Supplies: In many cases there are additional pools of potential wage labour that have not yet been integrated into the formal labour market (such as women, whose labour force participation in many countries is still far lower than for men). A genuinely tight labour market would find ways of integrating these workers into paid employment. The Centre of Full Employment and Equity (CofFEE) in Australia has done some particularly interesting work to quantify the hidden underutilization of labour in that country. See their alternative measures of unemployment at www.fullemployment.net. For all of these reasons, the official unemployment rate does not provide an accurate indicator of the true degree of labour market slackness. And changes in the true tightness of labour markets are often better captured by changes in the employment rate (which simply measures whether individuals are employed or not, and is not dependent on whether non-employed individuals qualify as actively seeking work) than by changes in the unemployment rate. 5