Cash Settlement, Price Manipulation, and the Modigliani-Miller Theorem

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Cash Settlement, Price Manipulation, and the Modigliani-Miller Theorem"

Transcription

1 Cash Settlement, Price Manipulation, and the Modigliani-Miller Theorem Albert S. Kyle Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland Very Preliminary First Draft May 1, 2007 Please do not quote without permission

2 CASH SETTLEMENT, PRICE MANIPULATION, AND THE MODIGLIANI-MILLER THEOREM Albert S. Kyle May 1, 2007 [Preliminary Version: Please do not quote without the permission of the author.] Some futures contracts call for physical delivery of the underlying asset. Examples are the bond contracts originally traded on the CBOT. Other futures contracts call for liquidation of outstanding positions at expiration by cash settlement. An example is the S&P 500 futures contract traded on the CME. When a cash-settled contract expires, outstanding positions are liquidated by marking them to cash market prices observed around the time of expiration. For example, the S&P 500 contract is liquidated by marking the position to the value of the S&P 500 index calculated at the open of trading. CFTC rules require that markets underlying cash-settled futures contracts be not subject to manipulation or distortion. The rules also require that cash settlement be based on a cash price series that is reliable, acceptable, publicly available, and timely. It has been argued by others that cash settlement makes futures markets less subject to manipulation, since it is not necessary for traders to trade in the underlying cash market. For the purposes of this paper, I will define manipulation as an intentional trading strategy undertaken for the purpose of influencing prices so that they do not reflect the underlying, natural, or market forces of supply and demand. Manipulative strategies include corners and squeezes, dissemination of false rumors designed to influence prices, and dissemination of fake transactions quantities and prices for the purpose of affecting prices. There may be other types of manipulative trading strategies, but that is an issue which goes beyond the scope of this paper. Does having cash settlement rather than physical delivery make it easier or harder to manipulate a futures contract? Does a cash-settled futures contract create the possibility for manipulative schemes that are distinctly different from ones used with physical delivery? Does the goal of preventing manipulation suggest useful guidelines for constructing cash-settled futures contracts rather than contracts requiring physical delivery? How should cash-settled contracts be constructed? The purpose of this paper is three-fold. 1

3 First, I argue that there is a simple and obvious sense in which it does not matter whether a futures contract has cash settlement or physical delivery. Under certain assumptions discussed below, the two different contract forms lead to precisely the same pricing and precisely the same economic outcomes. I call this The Modigliani-Miller Theorem of Cash Settlement. The concept of arbitrage I have in mind is stronger than the static arbitrage relationship between a spot price and a futures price as it is usually formulated in textbooks. It is much stronger than the Black-Scholes notion of arbitrage, which requires traders to agree on zero-probability events. In addition to various tradability, solvency, and fungibility assumptions about the market, my argument rests crucially on the assumption that arbitragers have the ability to place market orders in the cash market with the property that the orders have guaranteed execution at precisely the cash market prices which will be used for cash settlement. I show that this crucial assumption makes futures contracts with physical delivery exactly equivalent to futures contracts with cash settlement. Second, I argue that both the academic literature and practice of regulatory enforcement have become confused as a result of not recognizing the significance of this Modigliani-Miller Theorem. The literature confuses trades exerting downward pressure on prices with trades exerting upward pressure on prices. It imputes monopolistic motives to innocuous trading strategies in which traders supply liquidity to one another. The CFTC shares this confusion with the literature, as illustrated by their arguments in the Avista case. 1 I show that when traders agree on fundamental values, the logic of these monopolistic efforts to supply to liquidity to one another leads to a market price precisely equal to this fundamental value, with no trade necessary to achieve this since all traders agree what this fundamental value is. Third, I argue that a useful perspective on futures contract design and futures market regulation is obtained when one starts the analysis from the Modigliani-Miller perspective. Here are some examples: 1. If the cash market is closed when the cash settlement prices are to be calculated, it is a good idea to defer the calculation to a future date at which the cash market allows guaranteed execution of market orders. This allows market-on-expiration orders to be used to conduct arbitrage with the cash market. 2. Futures markets are sometimes used as the underlying for cash-settled OTC derivatives. An example includes the NYMEX electricity futures considered in the Avista case. When the settlement price of the futures market is used to cash-settle OTC derivatives, it is a bad idea for this settlement price to be based on an average of trading prices during a brief episode of human, eyeball-to-eyeball trading on a traditional trading floor. Such human trading makes it difficult to guarantee execution of a market-on-expiration at the settlement price. 1 The author worked as an expert witness for one of the individual defendants in the Avista case. 2

4 3. Both market-on-expiration orders which replace futures positions and transfers of positions from the futures market to the cash market in the delivery process of a physically-delivered futures contracts have two properties in common with of wash sales: No risks are transferred, and the price of the transaction does not have economic significance. For physical delivery contracts, deliveries are reported as a separate category of transaction, a good practice which allows traders to distinguish between deliveries and real volume in which risk is actually transferred. For cash-settled contracts, it would be a good idea to require offsetting market-on-expiration orders for all cash-settling futures positions to be automatically executed and reported as a separate category of volume, economically equivalent to deliveries. Such reporting would make it possible for traders to measure the volume of transactions in which risk is transferred. 4. Some traders may intentionally choose to let cash-settled positions expire, in which case the traders transfer risk to other traders by having their positions liquidated according to the cash-settlement price formula. To the extent that traders do this, it facilitates efficient use of the cash-settlement mechanism to structure the cash settlement procedure to resemble a trading strategy which a trader might otherwise choose to carry out without resorting to the cash-settlement mechanism. For example, since some traders like to use VWAP (volume-weighted-average price) strategies, the cash settlement procedure could be structured as a VWAP strategy which averages prices over time rather than rather than taking a snapshot of prices at one point in time. For purposes of practical implementation and clean arbitrage, time-weighted-average price might be more practical. For example, rather than establishing a cash-settlement price by calculating the value of an index at a single point in time (say, the open), the index could be averaged over a number of openings or averaged continuously over a trading interval ranging from several minutes to several days. ASSUMPTIONS Consider a hypothetical economy in which there exists a potentially large number of assets of various kinds. Among these assets are two futures contracts based on the same underlying asset. Make the following assumptions about these two futures contracts. The first assumption, ability of traders to place market-on-expiration orders, is the key assumption. The other assumptions are meant to assure enough tradability, solvency, and fungibility to make the contracts perfectly arbitrage-able against each other. I will refer to these assumptions collectively as microstructure fungibility. 3

5 (These assumptions are evolving and may be different in a future, less preliminary, version of this paper.): 1. Market on Expiration Orders : At any point prior to the execution of the cash-settled contract, it is possible for any trader to place a zero-transactionscost market order to buy or sell an arbitrary quantity of the deliverable asset in the cash market for guaranteed execution at precisely the cash settlement price. This assumption is satisfied if there is a transparent single-price auction which determines the settlement price, but it may also be satisfied even if the settlement price is determined in a non-transparent manner. This assumption does not require that there are no transactions costs for other types of transactions in the cash market. The cash market may in fact have very high transactions fees, otherwise be non-transparent, illiquid, and even subject to manipulative strategies such as corners or squeezes. 2. Identical Contract Terms: The terms of the two contracts are identical except that one contract calls for cash settlement and the other contract calls for physical delivery. In addition to the same underlying asset, the contracts have the same size, delivery date, mark-to-market conventions, and other similar specifications. 3. No Transactions Costs for Futures Arbitrage Transactions: There are no commissions or exchange fees charged to a trader who makes arbitrage transactions in which he buys a physical-delivery contract and simultaneously sells a cash settled contract, or vice versa. The assumption does not rule out commissions or exchange fees on other types of transactions. For example, the traders on the opposite sides of the two legs of the arbitrage transactions might incur commissions or exchange fees. This assumption also does not require markets to be particularly liquid. It allows for the ask price to be above the bid price, and it allows market impact to be larger when larger quantities are traded. The bid-asked spread may be wide or tight, and markets may be illiquid or illiquid. 4. Identical Exchange Fees and Commissions. The commissions for transactions in the cash-settled and physical-delivery futures contracts are the same. This assumption is meant to imply that a trader pays the same commissions and fees for a given amount of trading volume, regardless of whether the volume is in the cash-settled or physical-delivery contract. This assumption does not rule out volume discounts, nor does it require all traders to have the same commission rate. For example, a trader who trades 100 contracts of the cashsettled contract and 500 contracts of the physically-delivered contract pays the same fees he would pay if all 600 contracts were cash-settled (or physicallydelivered). 5. Fungible Delivery with the Cash Market: The delivery mechanism for the futures contract with physical delivery is identical to the delivery mechanism 4

6 for the underlying cash market. In particular, when the contract with physical delivery expires, traders with long outstanding positions are required to make delivery to traders with short outstanding positions by entering into the cash market clearing and settlement system transactions in which the longs deliver to the shorts the underlying asset at the final settlement price for the futures contract with physical delivery. 6. Netting of Cash Market Deliveries: If a trader has obligations both to make and take delivery in the cash market at the same delivery date (including deliveries on physically-delivered futures contracts), the quantities to be delivered are netted to the extent possible, and price differences are settled in cash. For example, if a traders has an obligation to deliver 100 contracts at a price of 102 and to take delivery of 60 contracts at a price of 98, then the trader makes a delivery of 40 contracts (100 60) at 102 and collects as a cash payment of 240 his profit of 4 (= ) on the remaining 60 contracts which are netted. 7. Clearing House Solvency: Both the clearing house for the futures market and the clearing house for the cash market guarantee performance on contracts and never fail themselves. I include in this assumption the idea that the futures exchange will not change the rules of the game while it is being played. For example, the clearing house will not force liquidation of contracts at arbitrary prices or require margins on margin-free positions (to force a member to fail). I view breaking the rules as a form of clearing house failure. 8. Identical Settlement Prices: At the close of trading each day, a settlement price is calculated for futures contracts and all futures positions are marked to market in cash to this settlement price. If the best bid for each of the two contracts is less than the best ask of both of the two contracts, we assume that both contracts are given the same settlement price. For example, if the cashsettled contract is bid at 95 and offered at 101 and the physical delivery contract is bid at 98 and offered at 103, then the settlement price for both contracts is the same. For convenience (although not necessarily required for the proof below), we also assume that the settlement prices respect the bid and the ask at the close. Thus, both contracts might be settled at 98 (the best of the two bids), or both might be settled at 101 (the lowest of the two ask prices), or both might be settled at the same price anywhere between 98 and 103, e.g. at 100. Note that this assumption does not require the futures contracts to be settled at the same price. It merely requires the futures exchange to try to settle the contracts at the same price if that if feasible, in the sense of being consistent with the bids and offers posted at the close of trading. 9. Marking-to-Market: The cash flows associated with marking to market at the final settlement price for both futures contracts and the cash flows associated with deliveries in the cash or futures markets at expiration of the futures 5

7 contracts all occur at the same time. This assumption, together with the previous one, makes the final settlement price in the physical-delivery contract a matter of indifference to all traders. If the final physical-delivery settlement price is raised by one dollar, longs will receive an extra dollar when their final position is marked to market and they will pay an extra dollar when delivery is made. Since these two cash flows occur on the same date, they have no economic effect on the trader taking delivery. Analogously, they have no effect on the short trader taking delivery either. 10. Bids and Offers Subject to Immediate Acceptance. If a trader posts a bid or an offer, this bid or offer can be accepted immediately by other traders. Within one contract, a trader is not allowed to post an order inconsistent with existing orders at the time, i.e., a trader is not allowed to offer at 99 when the market is bid at 101. At the close of trading each day, we require that traders be given an opportunity to accept the last bids and offers before remaining unaccepted bids and offer become final. This assumption allows arbitragers to eliminate arbitrage opportunities which may exist in the market just before the close. Note that this assumption does not require that all traders have equal access to posting or accepting bids and offers. Some traders, e.g. floor traders or traders with faster computer technology, may be able to post, accept, or cancel bids and offers faster than others. Furthermore, this assumption does not require that the futures markets conduct an efficient single-price auction at the open, at the close, or at any other time. 11. Risk-free Legging of Spreads: If a trader wishes to accept simultaneously both a bid and an offer, possibly on different contracts, he can do this without risk that he will be executed on only one leg of the transaction. For example, if a trader sees the cash-settled contract bid at 101 and the physical-delivery contract offered at 99 (a situation we claim below to be an arbitrage opportunity), then the trader is allowed to accept both simultaneously. As a practical matter, this means that the trader can press a button on his computer to try to accept both simultaneously. He will then receive a confirmation either that both legs of the trade executed or that neither leg of the trade executed. (This assumption is meant to eliminate trade-throughs of economically identical contracts.) 12. No Position Limits on Arbitrage Positions: There are no position limits on spread positions in which a trader is long the cash-settled contract and short equal quantities of the physical delivery contract when both contracts expire at the same time (or vice versa). There may be position limits on net long or short futures positions or long-short positions involving the cash market. 13. Zero Margin on Futures Arbitrage Positions: Long and short positions in the cash-settled and physical-delivery futures contracts with the same expiration date are netted so that spread positions incur no margin. For example, if a trader is long 20 cash-settled contracts and short 15 otherwise identical 6

8 physical-delivery contracts, he is margined as if he were merely long 5 cashsettled contracts (20 15 = 5). The netted spread position long 15 cashsettled contracts and short 15 physical-delivery contracts has zero required margin. 14. Traders Prefer More to Less: If one transaction generates more economic value than another, the trader will choose the transaction which generates more rather than less. This assumption gives traders an incentive to eliminate arbitrage opportunities between the two futures contracts. This assumption does not require that markets be competitive. Indeed, all traders may recognize that their trading has an effect on market prices, and large traders may recognize that they have significant market power. Traders may attempt to exercise their market power in various ways, for example, by attempting to monopolize the deliverable supply of the asset (as in a corner or squeeze), or quoting wide bid-asked spreads when supplying liquidity to other traders. THE ECONOMIC EQUIVALENCE BETWEEN CASH SETTLEMENT AND PHYSICAL DELIVERY Under the assumptions above, I claim that the cash-settled contract and the physical-delivery contract must have identical prices. I do not assume that markets are particularly liquid. Instead, I assume that there is a best bid price and best offer price for each contract. Identical prices means that the maximum of the best (highest) bids for both the cash-settled and physically-delivered contracts cannot be greater than the best (lowest) offers for the two contracts. To prove that prices are identical, suppose that there is an arbitrage opportunity, e.g., the best bid for the physical-delivery contract, say 101 for 20 contracts, is greater than the best offer for the cash-settled contract, say 99 for 5 contracts. An arbitrager will attempt to sell the physical-delivery contract for 101 and simultaneously buy the cashsettled contract for 99 as many contracts as possible, 5 contracts in the case (min(20,5) = 5). Because I have assumed risk-free legging of spreads, this attempt will either result in no transaction (an unable ) or in a transaction in which the trader buys the cash settled contract for 99 (or lower) and sells the physical-delivery contract for 101 (or higher) for some number of contracts between 1 and 5. If the attempt results in no transaction, this means that the arbitrage opportunity disappeared because the arbitrager did not act on it quickly enough. Perhaps another trader got there first. Suppose the attempt to capture the trade is successful and the arbitrager buys 5 cash settled contracts at 99 and sells 5 physical-delivery contracts at 101. The arbitrager then sits on this position long 5 cash-settled contracts and short 5 physical-delivery contract until a shortly before the expiration of the contracts. To make his attempted arbitrage transaction successful, the arbitrager must unwind his transaction in a manner that locks in an arbitrage profit. He can do this in the 7

9 following manner. Shortly before the expiration of the cash-settled contract, the arbitrager places a market on expiration order to buy 5 contracts in the cash market at precisely the price at which the expiring cash-settled contract is going to be settled. When the arbitrager places this order, he does not know the price at which this order will be executed. It may be far higher or far lower than prices a few moments before he places the order. Suppose the order executes at a high price of 150. Since we have assumed that the order executes at the price used for cash-settlement of the cash settled futures contract, the cash-settled futures contract is settled at the same price of 150. Now let us examine the cash flows per contract which the arbitrager receives from the transactions he has made. He purchases the cash-settled contract for 99 and sells it for 150. This generates a positive cash flow, or profit, of 51, calculated as = 51. He sold (shorted) the physical delivery contract at 101, and this contract had a final settlement price of 150, generating a loss (negative cash flow) or 49, calculated as = -49. Thus, his net profit per contract from the futures transactions is 2, calculated as = 2, the same profit he locked in when he initiated the arbitrage transaction in the first place. The cash flows from the physical delivery mechanism are zero. On his physical delivery contract, the arbitrager has an obligation to deliver 5 contracts at a price of 150. From the market-on-close orders, the arbitrager has an obligation to take delivery of 5 contracts at a price of 150. According to our assumptions above, the delivery obligations net against each other, leaving the arbitrager with no obligation either to make or to accept delivery. If there were no netting, the arbitrager would be required both to make and to take delivery of 5 contracts. If delivery collateral were scarce, or there were fees associated with making or taking delivery, this would impose costs on the arbitrager. It might create fails or defaults in the physical delivery process. Since the prices of the purchase and sale are both identical, 150 in this case, they are netted against each other, and the arbitrager receives a cash payment of precisely zero from the cash-market delivery mechanism. Although the arbitrager locks in an ultimate profit of 2 per contract on his arbitrage transaction, it is conceptually possible that marking to market differences between the two contracts results in these cash flows occurring at different times. If this were the case, the arbitrager would also have to consider interest on cash flows resulting from different timing of the transactions. We claim that there can be no cash flow differences between the two contracts, because all of the contracts will be marked to market at the same prices on the same dates. To see this, consider first the trading process which determines the final settlement prices of both the cash-settled and physical-delivery contracts precisely when the contracts expire. Since there is only one set of cash flows after this point, and these cash flows occur at the same time, we do not need to worry about differences in timing of cash flows after this point. Our argument in the paragraph above guarantees that arbitrage opportunities will be eliminated at the final settlement point, in the sense that the highest of the best bids in the two contracts will be no higher than the lower of the two offers. This makes it feasible for the exchange to settle the two contracts at identical prices which respect these bids and offers. According 8

10 to the assumptions we have made above, they will in fact do so. Thus, at expiration, the final settlement price of the cash-settled contract will be equal to the final settlement price of the physical-delivery contract. Now, the day before the expiration day, all traders can anticipate that the final settlement prices will be the same on the last day. This implies that the timing of cash flows on any attempted arbitrage transactions (which take place on the day before the final settlement day) will be identical. This arguments extends backwards (by induction) to prove that settlement prices will be the same on each day in the life of the contract. If traders anticipate that cash flow timing will be the same on all future days, forces of arbitrage will induce them to eliminate arbitrage opportunities today in such a way as to make settlement prices the same today as well. When they do so, such traders will not have to worry that they lose interest on money due to differences in marking the two contracts to market. We have thus proved that the timing of cash flows on the two contracts is the same, because settlement prices are the same on every day in the lives of the two contracts. In other words, the trader who buys cash-settled contracts at 99 and sells physical-delivery contracts at 101 receives a cash flow of +2 per contract as soon as the day s trades are marked to market. By assumption, he posts no margin; therefore, he needs no capital to enter into the transactions. Since settlement prices are the same on subsequent days, his cash flows are precisely zero on every subsequent day. At delivery, netting in the cash market the delivery mechanism works in such a manner that he needs no collateral or cash to make or take delivery. Thus, capital requirements for this riskless arbitrage transaction are zero, and any trader can carry out such a strategy. Although the numerical example is specific, it clearly generalizes to arbitrary quantities and prices. Moreover, the arbitrage strategy operates equally in reverse, with the arbitrager buying the physical-delivery contract and selling the cash-settled contract rather than selling the physical-delivery contract and buying the cash-settled contract. The Modigliani-Miller Theorem of Cash Settlement. My proof above establishes that, under the assumptions made, the contract with physical delivery is economically exactly equivalent to the contract with cash settlement. In fact, the arbitrage concept we have established is much stronger than the usual arbitrage relationships found in the finance literature. In the finance literature, there are two distinctly different types of arbitrage relationships, which I will refer to as static arbitrage and dynamic arbitrage. To distinguish the type of arbitrage above from the other two, I will call the concept I am using microstructure arbitrage. An example of static arbitrage is the usual derivation which shows that a futures contract equals the cash price of the underlying deliverable instrument, adjusted upward for interest and storage costs and adjusted downward for dividends. This arbitrage relationship is usually demonstrated under the assumption that there is one price at which both the futures and cash instrument can be bought or sold. It demonstrates that the futures contract is a redundant asset, in the sense that it can be economically replaced by a cash instrument with associated borrowing and lending. This arbitrage relationship does not take into account the possibility that futures contracts may improve 9

11 economic equilibrium by offering lower trading costs and greater liquidity than the cash market. Instead, it is typically assumed that there are zero trading costs, markets are competitive, there is a single price at which traders can buy and sell, and there is a single interest rate at which traders can borrow and lend. An example of dynamic arbitrage is the dynamic trading strategy which leads to the Black-Scholes model of option pricing. In addition to the assumptions made for static arbitrage, dynamic arbitrage arguments require that traders agree unanimously that particular zero-probability events will not in fact occur. In the Black-Scholes model, traders must agree that the path of the stock price will have a realized volatility equal to a particular quantity, called sigma in the Black-Scholes model. Since volatility is not precisely predictable, the Black-Scholes model does not hold precisely in real-world trading. The microstructure arbitrage argument I have given above does not require competitive markets, does not require zero transactions cost, does not require one price at which all traders can trade, does not require traders to agree on zero-probability events (other than that the assumptions I have made failing to hold, e.g. all participants agree that the clearing house will not fail), does not require that markets have any particular degree of depth, does not require that the cash market function efficiently, and does not require that borrowing or lending markets function at all. Since I do not assume that credit markets function at all, I have assumed no mechanism that guarantees the usual convergence between cash prices and futures prices. I have only assumed that the futures contracts are priced identically to each other, not that they are priced in any particular manner in relationship to the cash market. Since I have assumed that the costs of trading the cash-settled and physical-delivery contracts are the same, these two contracts are fungible in the sense that a trader will achieve exactly the same economic outcome if he does all of his trading in physical delivery contracts, does all of his trading in cash-settled contracts, or uses a combination of both types of contracts. If one of the two contracts is discontinued and positions are replaced by the other type of contract, there will be no effect on the economic allocation of resources. What is required is that the traders understand the assumptions I have made above, which lead to the understanding that the contracts are exactly equivalent for trading purposes, even in imperfect market with imperfect liquidity and exercise of monopoly power affecting prices. For example, under the assumptions I have made, it is possible that transactions costs in the futures market are far lower than transactions costs in the cash market, as a result of which futures contracts have very high trading volume relative to the cash market. If the futures market were eliminated, this might result in a significant welfare loss to society, due to the higher costs of risk-transfer on trades being forced into an illiquid and perhaps non-transparent cash market. But if only one of the two futures contracts were eliminated (e.g. physical delivery abolished), but not the other (e.g., cash settlement allowed), then all traders could re-label every bid, every ask, and every transaction in the abolished contract with an economically equivalent transaction in the 10

12 allowed contract. After this re-labeling, all transactions would be economically equivalent to what happened with trading in both contracts allowed. For this reason, microstructure arbitrage leads to a strong Modigliani-Miller Equivalence results: Under the assumptions I have made, the economic allocation of resources will be equivalent, regardless of whether only cash-settled futures contracts are traded, only physical-delivery futures contracts are traded, or both types of futures contracts are allowed. This equivalence will occur regardless of whether markets are liquid or illiquid, competitive or non-competitive, manipulated or non-manipulated. Whatever the outcome with one set of contracts, it will be the same with the other. Another way of looking at the result is to realize that the trading platform and clearing house could make the contracts completely fungible by, say, matching a buy of the cash settled contract directly against a sell of the physically delivered contract. Indeed, a trader would not need to indicate whether he wants his contract to be a cashsettlement contract or a physical delivery contract until shortly before expiration. After the trader declares the type of contract he wants, the exchange assigns delivery notices to the traders who want physical delivery and places market-on-expiration orders for traders who want cash settlement. This leaves the clearing house with not net economic exposure since the settlement price of both contracts is the same. The market-onexpiration orders will give the traders who ask for cash settlement something economically equivalent to physical delivery. They can undo the physical delivery by making trades in the cash market on terms identical to traders who have physical delivery contracts, or by making additional trades in the futures contract, at or before expiration. They have the same set of economic opportunities as traders choosing physical delivery. RISK-TRANSFER AT EXPIRATION Futures trading is a mechanism for transferring risk. Although some futures markets are highly liquid, real futures markets do not offer a risk-transfer service for free. Instead, traders face costs associated when transferring risks to other traders. There are exchange fees and commissions, positive bid-asked spreads, and market impact or slippage costs associated with larger transactions. In other words, traders who demand liquidity for transferring risk are well-advised think about what they pay for this liquidity. Some traders may receive a reward for supplying liquidity. Usually, we think of an impatient trader as being willing to pay to demand liquidity and a patient trader as intending to profit by supplying liquidity. But thinking about the demand and supply of liquidity is not straightforward (and not the main subject of this paper). Patient traders who demand liquidity may trade very slowly and look like suppliers of liquidity. Impatient traders with private information may appear to demand liquidity, but they intend to make a profit doing so, as a result of which the traders who supplied the liquidity may unexpectedly lose money. This occurs when a market maker is picked off by an informed trader with short-lived information. 11

13 When a trader uses a market transaction to change his risk exposure, the trader demands or supplies liquidity. For example, a trader long 30 cash-settled contracts and short 10 physical-delivery contracts (with no position in the cash market) can be deemed to have an exposure of +20 contracts (30 10 = 20) in the futures market. If he sells 5 of his 30 cash-settled contracts, his exposure is reduced by 5 contracts to +15. The sale of 5 contracts results in a transfer of -5 contracts of risk, the minus sign representing that contract risk was sold, not bought. For the purpose of measuring exposure to risk, we might also aggregate positions in futures contracts with positions in economically similar cash market instruments. For example, if the same trader long 30 cash-settled futures contracts and short 10 physicaldelivery futures contracts is also short cash market instruments similar to 18 futures contracts, his net market position combining futures and cash positions is only +2 contracts ( = 2). In addition, he has a basis position (cash minus futures) of 18 contracts. He is incurring two sorts of risk, market risk and basis risk. These risks are different. For example, if the positions are in long-term bond futures and longterm cash market bonds of various coupons and maturities, the market risk is associated with overall movements in long-term interest rates. The basis risk is associated with movements in short term interest rates, i.e. the repo rates (including specials) associated with borrowing collateral to finance the short position in cash-market bonds. The trader may be vulnerable to a squeeze if the bond he is short is not the one deliverable into the futures contract. This vulnerability is part of his basis risk. There is no basis risk associated with offsetting positions in otherwise equivalent cash-settled and physicaldelivery futures contracts, because we showed above that these contracts always trade at the same equivalent prices. Making or taking delivery of a physical-delivery futures contract does not result in any transfer of risk. For example, if our trader short the 10 physical delivery contracts chooses to deliver them, his short position moves from the futures market into the cash market, but he is still short these same ten contracts and still has the same market risk. Similarly, replacing an expiring position in a cash-settled contract by placing market-on-expiration orders to buy equivalent quantities in the cash market for each expiring long positions and to sell in the cash market equivalent quantities of expiring short positions does not result in any transfer of risk. The market risk simply moves from the futures market to the cash market at the moment the contracts are cash-settled, but the overall market risk remains the same. In the example above, if the trader long 30 cash settled contracts and short 10 physical delivery contracts replaces the 30 cash-settled contracts with market-onexpiration orders and makes delivery on the 10 short physical-delivery contracts, he would wind up with an unchanged cash market position of +2 futures contract equivalents. Note that my assumptions imply that 10 of the 30 cash settled contracts he replaces by buying would be netted against his ten short positions he is obligated to deliver against the physical delivery contract. Thus, he would take delivery of 20 contracts and make delivery of none. If the 18 contract short position in the cash market 12

14 were in instruments exactly equivalent to the 20 net futures deliveries, these would also be further netted and the trader would wind up with net deliveries of 2 contracts, and no basis risk. If the 18 contract short position in the cash market were instruments not identical to the cash market instruments underlying the futures contract, the trader would potentially wind up with a long position of 20 contracts of one type of bond and a short position of 18 contracts of another type of bond. He would then have 18 contracts of basis risk involving cash market bonds, but he would still have 2 contracts of market risk. For example, if the trader were being squeezed on his short position in cash market bonds, and if the futures contract allowed substitution of one bond for another in the delivery process, based on a cheapest-to-deliver concept, then the squeezed trader might unexpectedly be delivered different bonds on his long futures positions from the ones he was short. This would leave him vulnerable to further financing his short cashbond position at special rates in the repo market. If a trader with a cash-settled contract wants to change his risk exposure at the time of expiration, he must do something different from replacing his 30-contract long position by placing a market-on-expiration order to buy 30 contracts in the cash market. If he wants to increase his exposure by 10 contracts, he must supplement the 30-contract market on expiration buy order with 10 additional purchases, either in the cash of futures markets. Including the 30 contract market-on-expiration order, he would need to purchase 40 contracts overall If he wants to reduce his exposure by 10 contracts, he must either reduce the 30-contract market-on-expiration order by ten contracts, or supplement the 30- contract market-on-expiration order by selling 10 additional contracts in the cash or futures market. According to our assumptions, the trader pays nothing to keep his underlying exposure to risk the same by placing the 30-contract market-on-expiration order to buy. But if the trader chooses to do something different, e.g. by increasing or decreasing his risk exposure 10 contracts, he would be well-advised to think about how much he is paying or being paid to demand or supply 10 contracts of liquidity. For example, suppose that the trader chooses to reduce his risk exposure by 10 contracts, at exactly the moment the cash-settled contract expires. He could do this by reducing the size of his market-on-expiration order in the cash market from 30 contracts to only 20 contracts. Interpreting such a 20-contract market-on-expiration order can be confusing. The trader is a net seller of 10 contracts, and not a net buyer at all. Since he is a net seller of 10 contracts, he is putting downward pressure on prices. Yet his order is an order to buy, not an order to sell. This feature of cash-settled futures contracts can lead to confusion. If the trader places no market-on-settlement order at all, he demands liquidity by becoming a net seller of 30 contracts. His long cash-settled futures position of 30 contracts is liquidated at the settlement prices in the cash market, and his market risk exposure is reduced by 30 contracts. In this sense, appearing to do nothing, by placing no orders, actually represents a demand for market liquidity. The trader is in fact placing downward pressure on prices, and should expect to incur a transactions cost as a result of doing so. A naive trader who expects his 30 contracts to be executed without any adverse effect on prices is likely to be surprised that he has to pay for the liquidity he is 13

15 demanding. A trader should not expect a speculative market to offer its risk-transfer service for free. What kind of trading behavior should we expect to see at the expiration of a cashsettled futures contract? Suppose that at the moment of expiration, there is some single market-clearing price in the cash market at which all traders are happy with their existing positions in the market, and no trader wishes to change its market exposure at that price. Then every trader will have an incentive to place market-on-expiration orders to replace their entire futures positions with positions in the cash market. All of the traders with long positions will place buy orders to replace their long positions, and all of the traders with short positions will place sell orders to replace their short positions. Since the number of long positions is always by definition exactly equal to the number of short positions in a futures contract, the buy orders will net out against the sell orders exactly, and there will be no net demand for liquidity in the cash market as a result of all traders replacing their expiring futures positions with cash market positions. These traders will all be faced with settling positions in the cash market. How difficult such settlement is depends on how the underlying cash market operates. For example, if the cash-settled futures contract is S&P 500 futures, then each trader will be faced with the prospect of making or taking delivery on baskets of odd-lots in approximately 500 individual stocks. In my assumptions, I have not assumed that making or taking delivery in the cash market is cheap or easy. If making or taking delivery in the cash market is complex and expensive process, I expect the traders who will choose to place the market-onexpiration orders will on average be experienced, sophisticated, well-capitalized entities with good interfaces into the cash market. This expectation is no different from a contract with physical delivery. If making or taking delivery on a physical delivery contract is complex and expensive, I would also expect traders who make or take delivery to be experienced, sophisticated, well-capitalized entities with good interfaces into the cash market as well. Suppose that some of the traders with positions in the market at expiration are not sophisticated enough to navigate the process of trading in the cash market. Such traders will demand liquidity from the cash market by not placing market-on-expiration orders. The forces of supply and demand will determine prices in the cash market at which the cash-settled contracts will be liquidated. The assumptions I have made in no way suggest that the futures contract will be well arbitraged against the cash market. For example, my assumptions allow high exchange fees and commissions associated with cash market transactions which are not market-on-expiration orders, wide bid-asked spreads and great illiquidity in cash market trading, a non-transparent cash market without price reporting or reporting of current bid and ask prices, unequal access to the market across traders, abuse of market power by various types of traders, and poorly functioning credit for financing arbitrage positions. Under these circumstances, a naïve futures trader who allows his cash settled-futures position to expire and be cash settled may obtain prices he considers poor. In other words, the cash market may supply liquidity to a trader who demands it by not replacing positions with market-on-expiration orders at a very high price. Before having pity on such a trader, notice that a trader who allows his cashsettled futures position to be liquidated by cash settlement, without placing market-on- 14

16 expiration orders, is in exactly the same position as a trader in an otherwise equivalent physical-delivery contract who waits until after the futures contract expires, takes an unwanted delivery, then dumps the unwanted delivery into the cash market at whatever price the cash market happens to charge for this demand for liquidity. The price for this liquidity may be very high. Both the unsophisticated trader in the cash-settled contract and the unsophisticated trader in the physical-delivery futures contract are well-advised to liquidate their futures positions in the futures market before taking deliveries they do not have appropriate experience to deal with. THE CONFUSION IN THE ACADEMIC LITERATURE ON CASH SETTLEMENT The academic literature has become confused concerning the issue of whether cash-settled contracts offer something different from physical-delivery contracts. On the one hand, there are papers which recognize that cash settled contracts can be arbitraged against the cash market in a manner similarly to the way physical delivery contracts can be arbitraged. Papers by Dutt and Harris (2005), Stoll and Whaley (1997), Pirrong (2001), and Kumar and Seppi (1992) all recognize that there is a sense in which cash settled contracts are equivalent to physical-delivery contracts. All of this paper creates confusion, however, by analyzing cash-settled contracts in a manner which avoids confronting the equivalence which they all recognize and which I discussed above. Let us consider first an argument which is conceptually equivalent to one by Dutt and Harris (2005). Dutt and Harris examine a cash-settled contract in which the underlying is a weighted index of many assets, and they introduce conversion factors to convert prices to cash amounts and cash amounts to contract units. I will simplify his argument by assuming there is only one underlying asset, and I will ignore the various conversion factors by setting them all to 1. Suppose that just before the cash settled contract expires, a trader has a position of X contracts. Suppose that this trader believes that he faces a linear residual supply curve in the cash market against which he can trade at expiration by placing market-on-expiration orders. Since he thinks he knows the residual supply curve against which he trades, the trader thinks he knows the price at which a market-on-expiration order of any given size will be executed. Suppose the trader believes the fundamental value of the asset is 100, and he believes that if he acquires positions in the cash market by trading at expiration, then he will be able to liquidate these positions at the fundamental value of 100. The slope of the residual supply curve is denoted λ. Dutt and Harris go on to make the assumption that if the trader does not place a market on close order at all, and thus allows his entire position to cash-settle, then the trader expects the cash settlement price to be equal to the fundamental value of 100. As I will discuss below, I believe this assumption is unreasonable. As a result of this assumption, the trader believes that the cash-market price P, as a function of the size Q of his market-on-expiration order, is given by 15

17 P = λ*q. Under these assumptions, the total revenue a trader earns by placing an order of size Q is given by Total Revenue = (100 + λ*q)*x (100 + λq)*q + 100*Q. This equation says that the trader receives a payment of λq for each of his X cashsettled contracts, pays λq for each of the Q contracts he buys in the cash market, and receives 100 for each of the Q contracts he sells later in the cash market. Since total revenue is a quadratic function of Q, it is a simple calculus problem to show that the order size Q which maximizes total revenue is Q = X/2 = 10. In fact, for any positive value of the inverse depth parameter λ regardless of how small the amount purchased Q is always exactly one-half the size of the futures position which is about to be cashsettled. By placing a market-on-expiration order of size Q = X/2 rather than placing no market-on-expiration order at all, the trader increases his profit by λx. Dutt and Harris refer to choosing Q=X/2 instead of Q=0 as manipulation resulting from the trader s exercise of market power. Their intuition which also seems to be shared by Pirrong (2001), Kumar and Seppi (1992), and Stoll and Whaley (1997), but not by me is that the trader manipulates the cash market for the purpose of benefiting the cash settlement price of his futures position. According to the confusing intuition of these authors, relative to placing no order, the optimal cash market part of the transaction reduces profits by half as much money as the futures part of the transaction increases profits. Kumar and Seppi (1992) refer to this as punching the settlement price in the cash market for the purpose of benefiting the futures position. The CFTC also shared this confusion in the Avista case. In this case, there were OTC derivatives cash-settled against the NYMEX electricity futures contract, so NYMEX electricity futures play the role of the cash market and the OTC derivatives play the role of the futures market as far as cash settlement is concerned. The CFTC argued as follows: To the extent that Avista Energy s Traders could distort the price for futures contracts with an order at the Close on Options Expiration Day that was smaller than the positions created by Avista Energy s OTC derivatives contracts, Avista Energy s Traders thought that they might be able to profit via an artificially created increase in the value of its OTC derivatives contracts. This would be so because the value of those contracts would exceed any losses incurred from buying NYMEX Western U.S. electricity futures contracts at an artificially high price or selling futures contracts at an artificially low price. This captures precisely the punching-the-settlement-price intuition of Kumar and Seppi (1992) as well as the Dutt and Harris intuition. The Code of Market Conduct in the FSA s Handbook (1.6.15(2)) contains the following example of market abuse falling into the category of manipulating transactions: A trader buys a large volume of commodity futures, which are qualifying investments, (whose price will be relevant to the calculation of the settlement value of a derivatives position he holds) just before the close of trading. His purpose is to position 16

18 the price of the commodity futures at a false, misleading, abnormal or artificial level so as to make a profit from his derivatives position. This example also seems to capture intuition consistent with the punching-the-settlement argument of Kumar and Seppi (1992). What is wrong with this intuition? To see why this intuition is misleading, let us examine the economic substance of the transaction, taking into account our proof above that cash settled contracts are equivalent to ones with physical delivery. As we showed above, when the trader places a market order to buy Q contracts, he is increasing his market exposure by an amount equivalent to purchasing Q X contracts if Q > X, or decreasing his market position by an amount equivalent to selling X Q contracts if Q X < 0. If Q = X, the trader is neither demanding nor supplying liquidity. Thus, when the trader places a market-on-expiration order to buy only half his long position, Q = X/2 contracts (X > 0), he is in economic substance a net seller of X Q = X/2 contracts. What is the correct economic intuition motivating why the trader would like to be a net seller of X/2 contracts? If the trader does not demand or supply liquidity at all, he places a market-on-expiration order to buy X contracts, and the cash-settled futures contract settles at a price of λx, an amount which the trader perceives to be λx above its fundamental value. Evidently, the rest of the market is placing upward pressure on prices relative to what the all traders believe is likely to prevail later in the cash market. Like any supplier of liquidity, such as a typical large market maker in a normally functioning market, the trader sees an opportunity to make a profit by being a net seller at this attractively high price. The trader knows that the more he sells, the more he depresses the price. The trader maximizes his profits by being a net seller of half the number of contracts necessary to drive the price all the way back to its perceived fundamental value of 100. Thus, what the authors mentioned above refer to as manipulation is actually equivalent to ordinary market making by a market maker large enough to supply liquidity so aggressively that it would be feasible for him to drive his own profits to zero. Of course, a market maker will not willingly supply liquidity so aggressively that he tries to drive his profits from doing so to zero. Instead, he rations the amount of liquidity he supplies to maximize his profits. Precisely this issue was discussed in the Indiana Farm Bureau (****) case, where it was ruled (in the context of physical-delivery futures contracts) that it is not manipulative for a trader to seek to make a profit by restricting the amount of liquidity he supplies to the market. If the Indiana Farm Bureau logic is applied to cash settled futures contracts, it is not manipulative for a trader to replace his expiring cash-settled contracts by purchasing X contracts in the cash market. I believe that it is incorrect to refer to the behavior in the example discussed above as manipulation. The correct intuition becomes clearer when we re-write the problem in notation which consistent with the conventional use of supply and demand curves and conventional microstructure intuition. The relationship P = λq looks like a supply curve, but it is not a conventional supply curve. If the trader does not engage at risktransfer at expiration, then he places a market-on-expiration order to purchase X contracts. Letting P* denote this expected price with no risk transfer, we have P* =

19 + λx. Let L denote the traders supply of liquidity, defined by L = Q X. Then the equation P = λq can be equivalently re-written in the form of a conventional supply curve as P = P* + λl. If the trader believes that the positions he acquires L can be liquidated at a price of 100, his profit from acquiring L contracts of risk in the market is given by Profit = (P 100) L = (P* + λl 100)*L. This equation is also quadratic in L, and the value of L which maximizes it is L = -(P* - 100) /(2λ). Using the definition of P*, it is easy to see that L = -X/2, i.e., the trader sells X/2 contracts. Note that number of contracts sold depends only the depth of the market λ and on price difference between the fundamental value of the asset, 100 in this case, and the price of the asset if the trader does not engage in risk transfer, P* in this case. Since the trader believes that the asset will be overvalued by P* if he does not trade, he supplies liquidity to the market by selling exactly half the quantity which would drive price exactly to its fundamental value. In other words, he acts like any market maker trying to make a profit. There is nothing intrinsically manipulative about such a trading strategy. For example, if the market is very deep, λ is likely to be a tiny number, implying that P* differs only very slightly from the fundamental value of 100. The tiny value of λ may be the result of competition among numerous market makers, none of whom drives the price all the way to fundamental value because all of them want to make a living. Furthermore, the quantity L may also be very tiny, e.g. 1 or 2 contracts in a broad deep market. The reason that the actual quantity traded X/2 depends on the size of the trader s position is that Dutt and Harris assume in their example that P* differs from 100 by an amount proportional to the size of the trader s initial position. This assumption is based on the underlying assumption that the liquidation price will be equal to the fundamental value of 100 if the trader liquidates his entire position by allowing it to cash-settle without placing a market-on-expiration order. Is this assumption reasonable? I believe that there is a confused regulatory agenda hiding behind this assumption. The regulatory agenda begins with the proposition that a trader with a position in a cash-settled futures contract should liquidate his position by allowing it to cash settle, without placing market-on-expiration orders. This proposition is economically equivalent to the proposition that a trader in a physical-delivery contract should not take delivery. Both propositions are inconsistent with the behavior of a conventional arbitrager. Consider, for example, a conventional arbitrager with a long position in the futures market and an equal an offsetting short position in the cash market. Such a conventional arbitrager would often want to take delivery in a physical-delivery contract or do the equivalent by placing market-on-expiration orders. It is precisely this behavior that enforces an arbitrage relationship between the cash and futures markets. If the principle is adopted that traders should not take deliveries or, equivalently, should not place market on expiration orders to replace cash settling positions the link between the cash market and 18

20 the futures market is fundamentally broken. Instead, the forces of supply and demand would be replaced by a debate among lawyers and regulators concerning what the fundamental value of the asset should be. Dutt and Harris try to short-circuit this debate by assuming that all traders agree that the fundamental value of the asset is 100. What happens if we allow each trader to exploit his monopoly power optimally in the context of the Dutt and Harris example? To keep things simple, consider two traders with positions in the market. One trader is long 20 contracts just before expiration and the other trader is short 20 contracts. There are also numerous other traders in the market, but none of them have positions. Suppose all traders agree that the correct, fundamental value of the asset is 100. Let us propose to both traders that they allow their positions to cash settle, and let us assume that all traders agree that if both traders liquidate their positions by allowing them to cash-settle, without placing market-onexpiration orders, that the price will be equal to the fundamental value of 100. In the simple example above taking as given the assumption that the other trader is going to liquidate half of his position each of the two traders has an incentive to exploit his monopoly power optimally by allowing only half of his position to cash-settle (replacing the other half with market-on-expiration orders or deliveries). Each trader conjectures that by supplying less liquidity to the other trader, he will be able to transact at favorable prices. To exploit his monopoly power optimally, the trader long 20 contracts chooses to buy 10 contracts and the trader short 20 contracts chooses to sell 10 contracts. In other words, both traders turn down the proposal to allow all of their positions to cash settle. What happens if each trader believes that the other trader will liquidate half his position? Then each trader will actually find it optimal to liquidate only half of half his position. The trader who is long 20 contracts will conjecture that the trader short 20 contracts will sell 10 contracts, thus demanding 10 contracts of liquidity. This will lead the trader long 20 contracts to supply 5 contracts of liquidity by placing a market order to buy 15 contracts. Following the same logic, the trader short 20 contracts will sell 15 contracts. It is easy to see that the only set of conjectures which can be fulfilled in equilibrium are that each trader replaces his entire position, the trader long 20 contracts by buying 20 contracts and the trader short 20 contracts by selling 20 contracts. If each trader demands to transfer half as much risk as the other trader expects, a trader s demands for risk transfer can only be consistent with the other trader s expectations if the demand for risk transfer is zero. Demand for risk transfer is zero when each trader replaces his entire position. In other words, the correct conjecture each trader makes about price formation is P = P* + λl. Where P* is defined by P* = 100, not by P* = 100 +λx. In other words, the equilibrium conjectures are for traders to believe that price will equal fundamental value if they replace their entire positions, not if they allow their entire positions to cash settle. If all traders believe that price will equal fundamental value if each replaces his entire position, then each trader will do so, since doing anything else is less profitable. 19

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs.

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs. OPTIONS THEORY Introduction The Financial Manager must be knowledgeable about derivatives in order to manage the price risk inherent in financial transactions. Price risk refers to the possibility of loss

More information

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures In the previous chapter we study financial forward and futures contracts and we concluded that are all alike. Each commodity forward, however, has some unique

More information

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS PROBLEM SETS 1. There is little hedging or speculative demand for cement futures, since cement prices are fairly stable and predictable. The trading activity necessary to support

More information

Treasury Bond Futures

Treasury Bond Futures Treasury Bond Futures Concepts and Buzzwords Basic Futures Contract Futures vs. Forward Delivery Options Reading Veronesi, Chapters 6 and 11 Tuckman, Chapter 14 Underlying asset, marking-to-market, convergence

More information

Learning Curve Interest Rate Futures Contracts Moorad Choudhry

Learning Curve Interest Rate Futures Contracts Moorad Choudhry Learning Curve Interest Rate Futures Contracts Moorad Choudhry YieldCurve.com 2004 Page 1 The market in short-term interest rate derivatives is a large and liquid one, and the instruments involved are

More information

RISK DISCLOSURE STATEMENT FOR SECURITY FUTURES CONTRACTS

RISK DISCLOSURE STATEMENT FOR SECURITY FUTURES CONTRACTS RISK DISCLOSURE STATEMENT FOR SECURITY FUTURES CONTRACTS This disclosure statement discusses the characteristics and risks of standardized security futures contracts traded on regulated U.S. exchanges.

More information

Learning Curve Forward Rate Agreements Anuk Teasdale

Learning Curve Forward Rate Agreements Anuk Teasdale Learning Curve Forward Rate Agreements Anuk Teasdale YieldCurve.com 2004 Page 1 In this article we review the forward rate agreement. Money market derivatives are priced on the basis of the forward rate,

More information

Trading in Treasury Bond Futures Contracts and Bonds in Australia

Trading in Treasury Bond Futures Contracts and Bonds in Australia Trading in Treasury Bond Futures Contracts and Bonds in Australia Belinda Cheung* Treasury bond futures are a key financial product in Australia, with turnover in Treasury bond futures contracts significantly

More information

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income 2. Forwards, Options, and Hedging This lecture covers the basic derivatives contracts: forwards (and futures), and call and put options. These basic contracts are

More information

Futures Price d,f $ 0.65 = (1.05) (1.04)

Futures Price d,f $ 0.65 = (1.05) (1.04) 24 e. Currency Futures In a currency futures contract, you enter into a contract to buy a foreign currency at a price fixed today. To see how spot and futures currency prices are related, note that holding

More information

BOND FUTURES. 1. Terminology... 2 2. Application... 11. FINANCE TRAINER International Bond Futures / Page 1 of 12

BOND FUTURES. 1. Terminology... 2 2. Application... 11. FINANCE TRAINER International Bond Futures / Page 1 of 12 BOND FUTURES 1. Terminology... 2 2. Application... 11 FINANCE TRAINER International Bond Futures / Page 1 of 12 1. Terminology A future is a contract to either sell or buy a certain underlying on a specified

More information

Introduction to Futures Contracts

Introduction to Futures Contracts Introduction to Futures Contracts September 2010 PREPARED BY Eric Przybylinski Research Analyst Gregory J. Leonberger, FSA Director of Research Abstract Futures contracts are widely utilized throughout

More information

Chapter Five: Risk Management and Commodity Markets

Chapter Five: Risk Management and Commodity Markets Chapter Five: Risk Management and Commodity Markets All business firms face risk; agricultural businesses more than most. Temperature and precipitation are largely beyond anyone s control, yet these factors

More information

BEAR: A person who believes that the price of a particular security or the market as a whole will go lower.

BEAR: A person who believes that the price of a particular security or the market as a whole will go lower. Trading Terms ARBITRAGE: The simultaneous purchase and sale of identical or equivalent financial instruments in order to benefit from a discrepancy in their price relationship. More generally, it refers

More information

Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards

Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards 5 Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards In this chapter we will learn about Eurodollar Deposits Eurodollar Futures Contracts, Hedging strategies using ED Futures, Forward Rate Agreements, Pricing FRAs. Hedging

More information

Claiming a Fails Charge for a Settlement Fail in U.S. Treasury Securities

Claiming a Fails Charge for a Settlement Fail in U.S. Treasury Securities Claiming a Fails Charge for a Settlement Fail in U.S. Treasury Securities January 5, 2009 During the past several months, transactions in U.S. Treasury securities have exhibited widespread and chronic

More information

General Forex Glossary

General Forex Glossary General Forex Glossary A ADR American Depository Receipt Arbitrage The simultaneous buying and selling of a security at two different prices in two different markets, with the aim of creating profits without

More information

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS 1. a. The closing price for the spot index was 1329.78. The dollar value of stocks is thus $250 1329.78 = $332,445. The closing futures price for the March contract was 1364.00,

More information

June 2008 Supplement to Characteristics and Risks of Standardized Options

June 2008 Supplement to Characteristics and Risks of Standardized Options June 2008 Supplement to Characteristics and Risks of Standardized Options This supplement supersedes and replaces the April 2008 Supplement to the booklet entitled Characteristics and Risks of Standardized

More information

POLICY STATEMENT Q-22

POLICY STATEMENT Q-22 POLICY STATEMENT Q-22 DISCLOSURE DOCUMENT FOR COMMODITY FUTURES CONTRACTS, FOR OPTIONS TRADED ON A RECOGNIZED MARKET AND FOR EXCHANGE-TRADED COMMODITY FUTURES OPTIONS 1. In the case of commodity futures

More information

XIV. Additional risk information on forward transactions in CFDs

XIV. Additional risk information on forward transactions in CFDs XIV. Additional risk information on forward transactions in CFDs The following information is given in addition to the general risks associated with forward transactions. Please read the following information

More information

Brief Overview of Futures and Options in Risk Management

Brief Overview of Futures and Options in Risk Management Brief Overview of Futures and Options in Risk Management Basic Definitions: Derivative Security: A security whose value depends on the worth of other basic underlying variables. E.G. Futures, Options,

More information

Futures Contract Introduction

Futures Contract Introduction Futures Contract Introduction 1 The first futures exchange market was the Dojima Rice exchange in Japan in the 1730s, to meet the needs of samurai who being paid in rice and after a series of bad harvests

More information

Fundamentals of Futures and Options (a summary)

Fundamentals of Futures and Options (a summary) Fundamentals of Futures and Options (a summary) Roger G. Clarke, Harindra de Silva, CFA, and Steven Thorley, CFA Published 2013 by the Research Foundation of CFA Institute Summary prepared by Roger G.

More information

Guidance Note Capital Requirements Directive Market Risk

Guidance Note Capital Requirements Directive Market Risk Guidance Note Capital Requirements Directive Issued : 18 December 2007 Revised: 13 March 2013 V3 Please be advised that this Guidance Note is dated and does not take into account any changes arising from

More information

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011.

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011. Two-State Options John Norstad j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011 Abstract How options are priced when the underlying asset has only two possible

More information

5. Foreign Currency Futures

5. Foreign Currency Futures 5. Foreign Currency Futures Futures contracts are designed to minimize the problems arising from default risk and to facilitate liquidity in secondary dealing. In the United States, the most important

More information

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics Session IX: Stock Options: Properties, Mechanics and Valuation Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo Module: Economics of Financial Markets MSc. Financial Economics Department of Economics, City University, London Stock

More information

Finance 350: Problem Set 6 Alternative Solutions

Finance 350: Problem Set 6 Alternative Solutions Finance 350: Problem Set 6 Alternative Solutions Note: Where appropriate, the final answer for each problem is given in bold italics for those not interested in the discussion of the solution. I. Formulas

More information

Delivery options. Originally, delivery options refer to the options available to the seller of a bond

Delivery options. Originally, delivery options refer to the options available to the seller of a bond Delivery options Originally, delivery options refer to the options available to the seller of a bond futures contract, including the quality option, the timing option, and the wild card option. Delivery

More information

Chapter 10 Forwards and Futures

Chapter 10 Forwards and Futures Chapter 10 Forwards and Futures Road Map Part A Introduction to finance. Part B Valuation of assets, given discount rates. Part C Determination of risk-adjusted discount rate. Part D Introduction to derivatives.

More information

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. EXAM FM SAMPLE QUESTIONS Financial Economics

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. EXAM FM SAMPLE QUESTIONS Financial Economics SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES EXAM FM FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS EXAM FM SAMPLE QUESTIONS Financial Economics June 2014 changes Questions 1-30 are from the prior version of this document. They have been edited to conform

More information

Chapter 20 Understanding Options

Chapter 20 Understanding Options Chapter 20 Understanding Options Multiple Choice Questions 1. Firms regularly use the following to reduce risk: (I) Currency options (II) Interest-rate options (III) Commodity options D) I, II, and III

More information

Chapter 15 OPTIONS ON MONEY MARKET FUTURES

Chapter 15 OPTIONS ON MONEY MARKET FUTURES Page 218 The information in this chapter was last updated in 1993. Since the money market evolves very rapidly, recent developments may have superseded some of the content of this chapter. Chapter 15 OPTIONS

More information

Learning Curve Using Bond Futures Contracts for Trading and Hedging Moorad Choudhry

Learning Curve Using Bond Futures Contracts for Trading and Hedging Moorad Choudhry Learning Curve Using Bond Futures Contracts for Trading and Hedging Moorad Choudhry YieldCurve.com 2004 Page 1 A widely used risk management instrument in the debt capital markets is the government bond

More information

Overlapping ETF: Pair trading between two gold stocks

Overlapping ETF: Pair trading between two gold stocks MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Overlapping ETF: Pair trading between two gold stocks Peter N Bell and Brian Lui and Alex Brekke University of Victoria 1. April 2012 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/39534/

More information

19. Interest Rate Swaps

19. Interest Rate Swaps 19. Interest Rate Swaps Reading: Stigum 19 on Swaps. See also Hull who builds from the idea (mentioned in Stigum) that swaps are like a portfolio of forward contracts. Daily Financial Times includes bid-ask

More information

Basic Strategies for Managing U.S. Dollar/Brazilian Real Exchange Rate Risk for Dollar-Denominated Investors. By Ira G. Kawaller Updated May 2003

Basic Strategies for Managing U.S. Dollar/Brazilian Real Exchange Rate Risk for Dollar-Denominated Investors. By Ira G. Kawaller Updated May 2003 Basic Strategies for Managing U.S. Dollar/Brazilian Real Exchange Rate Risk for Dollar-Denominated Investors By Ira G. Kawaller Updated May 2003 Brazilian Real futures and options on futures at Chicago

More information

Computational Finance Options

Computational Finance Options 1 Options 1 1 Options Computational Finance Options An option gives the holder of the option the right, but not the obligation to do something. Conversely, if you sell an option, you may be obliged to

More information

SAVI TRADING 2 KEY TERMS AND TYPES OF ORDERS. SaviTrading LLP 2013

SAVI TRADING 2 KEY TERMS AND TYPES OF ORDERS. SaviTrading LLP 2013 SAVI TRADING 2 KEY TERMS AND TYPES OF ORDERS 1 SaviTrading LLP 2013 2.1.1 Key terms and definitions We will now explain and define the key terms that you are likely come across during your trading careerbefore

More information

Introduction to Equity Derivatives on Nasdaq Dubai NOT TO BE DISTRIUTED TO THIRD PARTIES WITHOUT NASDAQ DUBAI S WRITTEN CONSENT

Introduction to Equity Derivatives on Nasdaq Dubai NOT TO BE DISTRIUTED TO THIRD PARTIES WITHOUT NASDAQ DUBAI S WRITTEN CONSENT Introduction to Equity Derivatives on Nasdaq Dubai NOT TO BE DISTRIUTED TO THIRD PARTIES WITHOUT NASDAQ DUBAI S WRITTEN CONSENT CONTENTS An Exchange with Credentials (Page 3) Introduction to Derivatives»

More information

Nadex Multiply Your Trading Opportunities, Limit Your Risk

Nadex Multiply Your Trading Opportunities, Limit Your Risk Nadex Multiply Your Trading Opportunities, Limit Your Risk Discover a product set that: Allows you to trade in very small size (risking no more than a few dollars) Gives you the security of trading on

More information

THE UNDAMENTALS AND ECHNIQUES RADING OMMODITY PREADS. c s

THE UNDAMENTALS AND ECHNIQUES RADING OMMODITY PREADS. c s c s THE UNDAMENTALS AND ECHNIQUES OF RADING OMMODITY PREADS The purpose of this booklet is to give you a better understanding of various aspects of spread trading in the futures market. Center for Futures

More information

Risk Disclosure Statement for CFDs on Securities, Indices and Futures

Risk Disclosure Statement for CFDs on Securities, Indices and Futures Risk Disclosure on Securities, Indices and Futures RISK DISCLOSURE STATEMENT FOR CFDS ON SECURITIES, INDICES AND FUTURES This disclosure statement discusses the characteristics and risks of contracts for

More information

Introduction, Forwards and Futures

Introduction, Forwards and Futures Introduction, Forwards and Futures Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Fall, 2007 (Hull chapters: 1,2,3,5) Liuren Wu Introduction, Forwards & Futures Option Pricing, Fall, 2007 1 / 35

More information

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING OPTION PRICING Options are contingency contracts that specify payoffs if stock prices reach specified levels. A call option is the right to buy a stock at a specified price, X, called the strike price.

More information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation The Cournot and Bertrand models are the two basic templates for models of oligopoly; industry structures with a small number of firms. There are a number

More information

Chapter 2 An Introduction to Forwards and Options

Chapter 2 An Introduction to Forwards and Options Chapter 2 An Introduction to Forwards and Options Question 2.1. The payoff diagram of the stock is just a graph of the stock price as a function of the stock price: In order to obtain the profit diagram

More information

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING Darden Graduate School of Business Administration University of Virginia BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING Binomial option pricing is a simple but powerful technique that can be used to solve many complex option-pricing

More information

Practice Set #1: Forward pricing & hedging.

Practice Set #1: Forward pricing & hedging. Derivatives (3 credits) Professor Michel Robe What to do with this practice set? Practice Set #1: Forward pricing & hedging To help students with the material, eight practice sets with solutions shall

More information

Interest Rate Options

Interest Rate Options Interest Rate Options A discussion of how investors can help control interest rate exposure and make the most of the interest rate market. The Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) is the world s largest

More information

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model These notes consider the single-period model in Kyle (1985) Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading, Econometrica 15,

More information

Futures Contracts. Futures. Forward Contracts. Futures Contracts. Delivery or final cash settlement usually takes place

Futures Contracts. Futures. Forward Contracts. Futures Contracts. Delivery or final cash settlement usually takes place Futures 1 Futures Contracts Forward Contracts Futures Contracts Forwards Private contract between 2 parties Not standardized Usually one specified contract date Settled at end of contract Delivery or final

More information

Forwards and Futures

Forwards and Futures Prof. Alex Shapiro Lecture Notes 16 Forwards and Futures I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems II. Forward Contracts III. Futures Contracts IV. Forward-Spot Parity V. Stock Index Forward-Spot Parity

More information

Understanding ETF Liquidity

Understanding ETF Liquidity Understanding ETF Liquidity SM 2 Understanding the exchange-traded fund (ETF) life cycle Despite the tremendous growth of the ETF market over the last decade, many investors struggle to understand the

More information

Strategies in Options Trading By: Sarah Karfunkel

Strategies in Options Trading By: Sarah Karfunkel Strategies in Options Trading By: Sarah Karfunkel Covered Call Writing: I nvestors use two strategies involving stock options to offset risk: (1) covered call writing and (2) protective puts. The strategy

More information

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements How credit analysts view and use the financial statements Introduction Traditionally it is viewed that equity investment is high risk and bond investment low risk. Bondholders look at companies for creditworthiness,

More information

January 2011 Supplement to Characteristics and Risks of Standardized Options The February 1994 version of the booklet entitled Characteristics and Risks of Standardized Options (the Booklet ) is amended

More information

Fixed Income Portfolio Management. Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity

Fixed Income Portfolio Management. Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity Fixed Income ortfolio Management Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity assive bond portfolio management Active bond portfolio management Interest rate swaps 1 Interest rate sensitivity, duration,

More information

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 1 - Introduction Chapter 1 - Introduction Derivative securities Futures contracts Forward contracts Futures and forward markets Comparison of futures and forward contracts Options contracts Options markets Comparison of

More information

An Introduction to Nadex

An Introduction to Nadex An Introduction to Nadex AN INTODUCTION TO NADEX MULTIPLY YOUR TRADING OPPORTUNITIES, LIMIT YOUR RISK Discover a product set that: Allows you to trade in very small size (risking no more than a few dollars)

More information

FIN 472 Fixed-Income Securities Forward Rates

FIN 472 Fixed-Income Securities Forward Rates FIN 472 Fixed-Income Securities Forward Rates Professor Robert B.H. Hauswald Kogod School of Business, AU Interest-Rate Forwards Review of yield curve analysis Forwards yet another use of yield curve forward

More information

Lecture 5: Forwards, Futures, and Futures Options

Lecture 5: Forwards, Futures, and Futures Options OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 5: Forwards, Futures, and Futures Options Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis Spot (cash) market Forward contract Futures contract Options on futures Copyright

More information

FIN 684 Fixed-Income Analysis From Repos to Monetary Policy. Funding Positions

FIN 684 Fixed-Income Analysis From Repos to Monetary Policy. Funding Positions FIN 684 Fixed-Income Analysis From Repos to Monetary Policy Professor Robert B.H. Hauswald Kogod School of Business, AU Funding Positions Short-term funding: repos and money markets funding trading positions

More information

MONEY MARKET FUTURES. FINANCE TRAINER International Money Market Futures / Page 1 of 22

MONEY MARKET FUTURES. FINANCE TRAINER International Money Market Futures / Page 1 of 22 MONEY MARKET FUTURES 1. Conventions and Contract Specifications... 3 2. Main Markets of Money Market Futures... 7 3. Exchange and Clearing House... 8 4. The Margin System... 9 5. Comparison: Money Market

More information

LOCKING IN TREASURY RATES WITH TREASURY LOCKS

LOCKING IN TREASURY RATES WITH TREASURY LOCKS LOCKING IN TREASURY RATES WITH TREASURY LOCKS Interest-rate sensitive financial decisions often involve a waiting period before they can be implemen-ted. This delay exposes institutions to the risk that

More information

Factors Affecting Option Prices

Factors Affecting Option Prices Factors Affecting Option Prices 1. The current stock price S 0. 2. The option strike price K. 3. The time to expiration T. 4. The volatility of the stock price σ. 5. The risk-free interest rate r. 6. The

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

Oil Speculation by Jussi Keppo July 8, 2008

Oil Speculation by Jussi Keppo July 8, 2008 Oil Speculation by Jussi Keppo July 8, 2008 The increase in the oil spot price seems to be mainly driven by the global demand. According to the U.S. Energy Information Administration, in 1999 the global

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. ECON 4110: Sample Exam Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) Economists define risk as A) the difference between the return on common

More information

Determination of Forward and Futures Prices. Chapter 5

Determination of Forward and Futures Prices. Chapter 5 Determination of Forward and Futures Prices Chapter 5 Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets, 8th Ed, Ch 5, Copyright John C. Hull 2013 1 Consumption vs Investment Assets Investment assets are assets

More information

Interest Rate Futures. Chapter 6

Interest Rate Futures. Chapter 6 Interest Rate Futures Chapter 6 1 Day Count Convention The day count convention defines: The period of time to which the interest rate applies. The period of time used to calculate accrued interest (relevant

More information

Lecture 7: Bounds on Options Prices Steven Skiena. http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena

Lecture 7: Bounds on Options Prices Steven Skiena. http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena Lecture 7: Bounds on Options Prices Steven Skiena Department of Computer Science State University of New York Stony Brook, NY 11794 4400 http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena Option Price Quotes Reading the

More information

CFA Level -2 Derivatives - I

CFA Level -2 Derivatives - I CFA Level -2 Derivatives - I EduPristine www.edupristine.com Agenda Forwards Markets and Contracts Future Markets and Contracts Option Markets and Contracts 1 Forwards Markets and Contracts 2 Pricing and

More information

Market Microstructure: An Interactive Exercise

Market Microstructure: An Interactive Exercise Market Microstructure: An Interactive Exercise Jeff Donaldson, University of Tampa Donald Flagg, University of Tampa ABSTRACT Although a lecture on microstructure serves to initiate the inspiration of

More information

Financial Markets and Institutions Abridged 10 th Edition

Financial Markets and Institutions Abridged 10 th Edition Financial Markets and Institutions Abridged 10 th Edition by Jeff Madura 1 12 Market Microstructure and Strategies Chapter Objectives describe the common types of stock transactions explain how stock transactions

More information

Harvard Electricity Policy Group Market Power and Market-Makers

Harvard Electricity Policy Group Market Power and Market-Makers Harvard Electricity Policy Group Market Power and Market-Makers Makers Richard A. Shilts Acting Director Division of Economic Analysis Commodity Futures Trading Commission Types of Transactions in Commodity

More information

General Risk Disclosure

General Risk Disclosure General Risk Disclosure Colmex Pro Ltd (hereinafter called the Company ) is an Investment Firm regulated by the Cyprus Securities and Exchange Commission (license number 123/10). This notice is provided

More information

Lecture 3: Forward Contracts Steven Skiena. http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena

Lecture 3: Forward Contracts Steven Skiena. http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena Lecture 3: Forward Contracts Steven Skiena Department of Computer Science State University of New York Stony Brook, NY 11794 4400 http://www.cs.sunysb.edu/ skiena Derivatives Derivatives are financial

More information

1. HOW DOES FOREIGN EXCHANGE TRADING WORK?

1. HOW DOES FOREIGN EXCHANGE TRADING WORK? XV. Important additional information on forex transactions / risks associated with foreign exchange transactions (also in the context of forward exchange transactions) The following information is given

More information

PUREDMA TRADING MANUAL

PUREDMA TRADING MANUAL PUREDMA TRADING MANUAL Contents 1. An Introduction to DMA trading 02 - What is DMA? 02 - Benefits of DMA 02 2. Getting Started 02 - Activating DMA 02 - Permissions & Data Feeds 03 3. Your DMA Deal Ticket

More information

Options Pricing. This is sometimes referred to as the intrinsic value of the option.

Options Pricing. This is sometimes referred to as the intrinsic value of the option. Options Pricing We will use the example of a call option in discussing the pricing issue. Later, we will turn our attention to the Put-Call Parity Relationship. I. Preliminary Material Recall the payoff

More information

CHAPTER 11 INTRODUCTION TO SECURITY VALUATION TRUE/FALSE QUESTIONS

CHAPTER 11 INTRODUCTION TO SECURITY VALUATION TRUE/FALSE QUESTIONS 1 CHAPTER 11 INTRODUCTION TO SECURITY VALUATION TRUE/FALSE QUESTIONS (f) 1 The three step valuation process consists of 1) analysis of alternative economies and markets, 2) analysis of alternative industries

More information

The Options Clearing Corporation

The Options Clearing Corporation PROSPECTUS M The Options Clearing Corporation PUT AND CALL OPTIONS This prospectus pertains to put and call security options ( Options ) issued by The Options Clearing Corporation ( OCC ). Certain types

More information

6. Federal Funds: Final Settlement

6. Federal Funds: Final Settlement 6. Federal Funds: Final Settlement Stigum (p. 507) says The primary job of the manager of a bank s fed funds desk is to ensure (1) that the bank settles with the Fed and (2) that in doing so, it hold no

More information

Lecture 12. Options Strategies

Lecture 12. Options Strategies Lecture 12. Options Strategies Introduction to Options Strategies Options, Futures, Derivatives 10/15/07 back to start 1 Solutions Problem 6:23: Assume that a bank can borrow or lend money at the same

More information

Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures

Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures Question 5.1. Four different ways to sell a share of stock that has a price S(0) at time 0. Question 5.2. Description Get Paid at Lose Ownership of Receive Payment

More information

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options.

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options. Chapter 11 Options Road Map Part A Introduction to finance. Part B Valuation of assets, given discount rates. Part C Determination of risk-adjusted discount rate. Part D Introduction to derivatives. Forwards

More information

For example, someone paid $3.67 per share (or $367 plus fees total) for the right to buy 100 shares of IBM for $180 on or before November 18, 2011

For example, someone paid $3.67 per share (or $367 plus fees total) for the right to buy 100 shares of IBM for $180 on or before November 18, 2011 Chapter 7 - Put and Call Options written for Economics 104 Financial Economics by Prof Gary R. Evans First edition 1995, this edition September 24, 2011 Gary R. Evans This is an effort to explain puts

More information

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008. Options

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008. Options FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Options These notes describe the payoffs to European and American put and call options the so-called plain vanilla options. We consider the payoffs to these

More information

Practice set #4 and solutions

Practice set #4 and solutions FIN-465 Derivatives (3 credits) Professor Michel Robe Practice set #4 and solutions To help students with the material, seven practice sets with solutions will be handed out. They will not be graded: the

More information

Understanding Futures on the DTCC GCF Repo Index

Understanding Futures on the DTCC GCF Repo Index Understanding Futures on the DTCC GCF Repo Index White Paper June 2014 This material may not be reproduced or redistributed in whole or in part without the express, prior written consent of Intercontinental

More information

1 Introduction to Option Pricing

1 Introduction to Option Pricing ESTM 60202: Financial Mathematics Alex Himonas 03 Lecture Notes 1 October 7, 2009 1 Introduction to Option Pricing We begin by defining the needed finance terms. Stock is a certificate of ownership of

More information

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC MARKET STRUCTURE AND INSIDER TRADING WASSIM DAHER AND LEONARD J. MIRMAN Abstract. In this paper we examine the real and financial effects of two insiders trading in a static Jain Mirman model (Henceforth

More information

DERIVATIVES IN INDIAN STOCK MARKET

DERIVATIVES IN INDIAN STOCK MARKET DERIVATIVES IN INDIAN STOCK MARKET Dr. Rashmi Rathi Assistant Professor Onkarmal Somani College of Commerce, Jodhpur ABSTRACT The past decade has witnessed multiple growths in the volume of international

More information

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r). Chapter 4 Put-Call Parity 1 Bull and Bear Financial analysts use words such as bull and bear to describe the trend in stock markets. Generally speaking, a bull market is characterized by rising prices.

More information

TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II + III

TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II + III TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II III Instructions 1. Only one problem should be treated on each sheet of paper and only one side of the sheet should be used. 2. The solutions folder

More information

Manual for SOA Exam FM/CAS Exam 2.

Manual for SOA Exam FM/CAS Exam 2. Manual for SOA Exam FM/CAS Exam 2. Chapter 7. Derivatives markets. c 2009. Miguel A. Arcones. All rights reserved. Extract from: Arcones Manual for the SOA Exam FM/CAS Exam 2, Financial Mathematics. Fall

More information

Forward Contracts and Forward Rates

Forward Contracts and Forward Rates Forward Contracts and Forward Rates Outline and Readings Outline Forward Contracts Forward Prices Forward Rates Information in Forward Rates Reading Veronesi, Chapters 5 and 7 Tuckman, Chapters 2 and 16

More information