The High-Yield Spread as a Predictor of Real Economic Activity: Evidence of a Financial Accelerator for the United States

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The High-Yield Spread as a Predictor of Real Economic Activity: Evidence of a Financial Accelerator for the United States"

Transcription

1 IMF Staff Papers Vol. 50, No International Monetary Fund The High-Yield Spread as a Predictor of Real Economic Activity: Evidence of a Financial Accelerator for the United States ASHOKA MODY and MARK P.TAYLOR * Previous studies find that the interest rate term spread predicts real U.S. economic activity. We show that this relationship breaks down for the 1990s and suggest that its earlier success was due to high and volatile inflation. We find, however, that the high-yield spread (HYS) between junk bond and government bond yields predicts real activity during the 1990s especially high levels of the HYS. We also find that the HYS works through both the demand and the supply side of the economy. We interpret our findings as supportive of a financial accelerator mechanism. [JEL E33, E44] The slope of nominal yield curve, or the term spread, was shown by studies published in the late 1980s and early 1990s to have significant predictive content for future real economic activity, both in the United States and in Europe. 1 Following the early work by Stock and Watson (1989) and Estrella and Hardouvelis (1991), 2 however, confidence in the predictive power of the term spread waned a little when it failed to predict the U.S. recession (see, for example, Dotsey, 1998). Nevertheless, further work by, among others, Estrella and Mishkin (1997) and Plosser and Rouwenhorst (1994) seemed to establish that its power as a leading indicator of real economic activity had not evaporated. This somewhat mixed evidence on the forecasting performance of the term spread remains in the literature. * Mark P. Taylor is Professor of Macroeconomics at the University of Warwick and a Fellow of the Centre for Economic Policy Research. He was a Visiting Scholar in the Research Department when this paper was written. Ashoka Mody is a Division Chief in the Research Department. We are grateful to two anonymous referees for helpful comments on an earlier version of the paper and also to Lutz Kilian for insightful comments and advice on our forecasting exercises. 1 See, for example, Stock and Watson (1989), Harvey (1989), Chen (1991), Estrella and Hardouvelis (1991), Hu (1993), Caporale (1994), Peel and Taylor (1998), and Bernard and Gerlach (1998). 2 See also Laurent (1988). 373

2 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor Dotsey (1998, p. 50), for example, in a paper that is generally supportive of the view that the term spread does indeed contain predictive information, notes that that conclusion must be tempered, however, by the observation that over more recent periods the spread has not been as informative as it has been in the past. Gertler and Lown (1999), drawing on the theory of the financial accelerator (see, for example, Bernanke and Gertler, 1995; Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist, 1999, and the references cited therein), argue that an alternative financial variable should also have predictive power for real economic activity this is the premium required on less than investment-grade corporate bonds (also referred to as highyield or junk bonds) over government debt or AAA-rated corporate bonds. Gertler and Lown (1999) provide some empirical support for this view based on correlation and impulse-response analysis, using data on the high-yield spread and a measure of the U.S. output gap. We seek in this paper to contribute to this literature in a number of ways. First, we examine the robustness of the term spread as a predictor of economic activity by estimating long-horizon regressions covering broadly three periods the 1960s, the 1970s and 1980s, and the 1990s. In brief, we find that the term spread does not predict real economic activity well for the most recent period, although it does perform well in this capacity for the 1970s and 1980s. Interestingly, however, we find that the predictive content of the term spread appears to be unique to the 1970s and 1980s, in that we also find it to be only weakly present in the data for the 1960s. We then move on to examine the predictive content of the high-yield spread. We believe this analysis to be the first using the long-horizon regression, which has been the standard tool for judging the predictive ability of the term spread. We find that the high-yield spread has a high predictive content. In addition, we find evidence of some nonlinearity, in that abnormally high levels of the high-yield spread have significant additional short-term predictive power. Also, despite the low power of out-of-sample tests of forecast accuracy (Inoue and Kilian, 2002), we find that out-of-sample forecasts of movements in economic activity based on the high-yield spread are significantly superior to those produced using the term spread during the 1990s. Finally, we break down our measure of real economic activity real industrial production into temporary and permanent components, using a variant of an econometric technique developed by Blanchard and Quah (1989). After estimating the long-horizon regressions with output purged of, respectively, its permanent (or supply ) and temporary (or demand ) components, we find that the highyield spread retains its predictive ability. The results suggest that the high-yield spread works through both, which we interpret as further evidence in support of a financial accelerator mechanism for the United States. Although the predictive content of the high-yield spread is of general interest, we were led to this investigation because of our finding in previous research that the high-yield spread is an important variable in the modeling of capital flows to emerging markets. It has been conventional wisdom, at least since a well-known paper by Calvo, Leiderman, and Reinhart (1996), that U.S. monetary policy through its influence on short-term interest rates has a significant influence on capital flows to developing economies. Recent events raise a question mark over this 374

3 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY stylized fact, however: while U.S. interest rates have fallen sharply, capital flows have at best remained stable. In previous research, we have proxied the influence of conditions in international capital markets by the U.S. high-yield spread rather than by U.S. interest rates. In particular, we find that a rise in the high-yield spread is associated with reduced supply of capital to emerging markets and the inclusion of this spread eliminates the influence of interest rates (Mody and Taylor, 2002a). A rise in the high-yield spread is also associated with increased regional vulnerability as observed in heightened exchange market pressure (Mody and Taylor, 2002b). Thus, movements in the U.S. high-yield spread clearly have an important bearing on emerging market access to international capital markets. In Mody and Taylor (2002a), we speculated that an international financial accelerator mechanism may be at work: high-yield spreads predict higher default rates and hence slower economic activity, which dampens access to credit, further reducing economic activity, and so on (see, for example, Bernanke and Gertler, 1995). Thus, the question we pose in this paper is whether a rise in high-yield spreads does in fact signal slower growth in the U.S., since establishing such a link would provide a firmer basis for understanding the implications of developments in the North for access to capital and vulnerability to currency crises in the South. I. Predicting Real Economic Activity: Theoretical Background The Term Spread as a Predictor of Real Activity Although several studies have found the term spread to contain information with respect to future economic activity, the theoretical basis for this relationship has remained unclear, as noted, for example, by Plosser and Rouwenhorst (1994) and Dotsey (1998). Thus, Estrella and Hardouvelis (1991), while documenting the predictive ability of the term spread, also cautioned that the relationship could easily wane. The slope of the yield curve may be influenced by factors such as expected real interest rates, current and expected inflation, and risk or term premiums. A starting point for the link between the term spread and real economic activity could therefore be the theoretical relationship between real interest rates and macroeconomic activity for example through consumption and investment (see Taylor, 1999, for a survey). One can use, for example, a simple optimizing model of consumption to derive a theoretical model of the link between future consumption and the real term structure as follows. Consider a representative agent whose real consumption in period t is C t, whose instantaneous utility function is U(.), and whose subjective rate of time preference is ρ. If the j-period real interest rate is i t ( j), then, making the usual assumptions such as additive separability of preferences, we can derive from the first-order conditions for the agent s optimal consumption plan Euler equations of the form: (1) 1 ( ) = ( 1+ )( 1+ ρ) ( ) U C i EU C t t t t + 2 ( ) = ( 1+ )( 1+ ρ) ( ) U C i EU C t t t t + (2), 2 1 (1) (2) 375

4 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor where U (.) denotes the first derivative of the utility function and hence marginal utility, and E t denotes the mathematical expectation operator conditional on information at time t. The intuition is standard: if the agent is optimizing, then it is impossible to improve the plan by, say, reducing consumption slightly today [at a cost of U (C t )], investing for j periods at the real interest rate i ( j) t, and increasing consumption in period j, yielding an expected gain, in period-t present-value terms, of [(1+ i ( j) t )(1 + ρ) j E t U (C t+j )] the cost just offsets the expected gain. From (1) and (2) we can, however, derive a close approximation: EU C (2) (1) t t ( i i t t ) ( ) + 1 = ( 1+ ρ) 1. (3) EU C t ( t+ 2) Equation (3) thus describes a very simple possibility for how movements in the real yield curve may affect future economic activity. An increase in the slope of the real term structure will induce optimizing agents to take advantage of the better yield available at longer maturities by reducing consumption in the short term and increasing consumption in the long term. With diminishing marginal utility, a rise in (i (2) t i (1) t ) requires a reduction in C t +1 and an increase in C t +2. Insofar as movements in the nominal term spread move with the real term spread, therefore, and insofar as increased consumption demand raises economic activity, this framework predicts that rises in the nominal term spread will indeed be associated with increases in future economic activity. Note, however, that this analysis is based on a consideration of Euler equations rather than proper reduced forms: these are conditions that must hold at the margin, rather than being reduced-form equations. Moreover, the issue becomes complicated when the move is made from considering the behavior of the representative agent to considering the behavior of the economy in aggregate. In fact, the implication of a large empirical literature on consumption is that the statistical link between real interest rates and aggregate consumption is extremely tenuous (Deaton, 1992; Taylor, 1999), suggesting that it is unlikely that the nominal term spread, by acting as a proxy for the real term spread, is predicting future shifts in consumption demand. A huge amount of empirical work on aggregate investment also concludes that the statistical link between real interest rates and investment demand is weak (Chirinko, 1993; Taylor, 1999), moreover, suggesting that searching for a theoretical link between the term spread and investment is also likely to be fruitless. Alternatively, we might explore the avenue that the term spread reflects expected future inflation. However, the long-term interest rates typically used in this connection are quite long horizon of the order of 10 years or more. Given that the term spread appears to have predictive content for at most a few years, it therefore seems unlikely that this forward-looking element plays a large role in this respect. With respect to term or risk premiums, empirical work has typically found no evidence of strong and statistically stable models (see, for example, Taylor, 1992). There seem to be two other remaining avenues through which the term spread may predict future real activity. First, insofar as a general monetary easing will be reflected in a fall in short-term interest rates and hence a steepening of the yield 376

5 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY curve, the term spread will be positively correlated with future movements in real activity brought about by the expansionary policy. The second possibility is that the term spread also reflects movements in the current rate of inflation. If a rise in current inflation leads to a rise in short-term interest rates and, hence, a flattening of the yield curve and if inflation and real activity are negatively correlated, a fall in the term spread will predict slower future real activity. The proposition that high inflation is likely to be associated with a weakening of economic activity is supported by recourse to standard economic theory. In a simple aggregate supply aggregate demand framework, for example, reductions in real output brought about by shifts in aggregate supply will be accompanied by a rise in prices and inflation as the economy moves along the aggregate demand schedule. If we introduce nominal wage inertia and a long-run vertical supply curve into such a framework, then aggregate demand shifts may also lead to negative correlation between inflation and growth since, while the short-run effect of a positive demand shock will be to raise output, prices will initially be largely unaffected because of nominal inertia. If the supply curve is vertical in the long run, moreover, then after a few periods the initial rise in output will begin to decline, just as the rise in prices is beginning to feed through, so that inflation and the change in output will tend to correlate negatively. In Appendix I, we set out a formal macroeconomic model with long-run monetary neutrality and nominal wage inertia induced through wage contracting, in which we show that the overall covariance between inflation and output growth may be negative. 3 If, further, we allow for the negative effects on economic activity from inflationary uncertainty and other distortions induced by an environment of high and volatile inflation, then a negative correlation between inflation and growth seems even more likely at least in a period of high inflation. In Figure 1 we have graphed the 12-month consumer price index inflation rate and the 12-month percentage growth in real industrial production for the United States. over the period 1958M1 2001M12 (see Section II for data sources). Two aspects of the graph are particularly striking. First, the rate of inflation is higher and more volatile during the 1970s and 1980s than it was during either the 1960s or the 1990s. Second, there appears to be stronger evidence of negative correlation between inflation and the rate of growth of industrial production during the 1970s and 1980s. In addition, as argued above, while demand shocks may induce, in certain circumstances, negative correlation between output growth and inflation, supply shocks will unambiguously do so, and this effect appears to be particularly marked following the first and second oil shocks of 1974 and In contrast, the behavior of inflation during the 1990s appears to have much more in common with that of the 1960s, in that it is generally much lower, less volatile, and apparently less negatively correlated with output growth. In light of our discussion of the possible underlying causes of the link between the term spread and future real activity, therefore, this suggests testing for the strength of the link during the 1960s, as well as during the 1990s, to see if the link is in fact significantly weaker during these two periods. 3 Fama (1981) argues that the fact that real stock price returns and inflation tend to be negatively correlated may be because inflation and (current and expected) real output may be negatively correlated. 377

6 Figure 1. U.S. Inflation and Output Growth, month inflation rate 12-month growth in output Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor M1 1962M1 1966M1 1970M1 1974M1 1978M1 1982M1 1986M1 1990M1 1994M1 1998M1 2002M1

7 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY The High-Yield Spread as a Predictor of Real Activity The theoretical underpinning of the high-yield spread as a predictor of real economic activity primarily relates to the theory of the financial accelerator (see, for example, Bernanke and Gertler, 1995; Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist 1999; and the references therein). While the details of these models differ, their central features are reasonably uniform and their key elements may be set out informally as follows. There is some friction present in the financial market, such as asymmetric information or costs of contract enforcement, which, for a wide class of industrial and commercial businesses, introduces a wedge between the cost of external funds and the opportunity cost of internal funds the premium for external funds. This premium is an endogenous variable that depends inversely on the balance sheet strength of the borrower, since the balance sheet is the key signal through which the creditworthiness of the firm is evaluated. However, balance sheet strength is itself a positive function of aggregate real economic activity, so that borrowers financial positions are procyclical and hence movements in the premium for external funds are countercyclical. Thus, as real activity expands, the premium on external funds declines, which, in turn, leads to an amplification of borrower spending, which further accelerates the expansion of real activity. This is the basic mechanism of the financial accelerator. A problem in testing the theory of the financial accelerator empirically in the past has, however, been the lack of any reliable data on a key central variable in the theory the premium on external funds. This is because firms that are subject to important financial constraints of this kind have typically relied on commercial bank loans as the chief source of external finance, and time series of relevant bank borrowing rates are not available. Moreover, as Gertler and Lown (1999) point out, even if they were, the fact that bank loans typically contain important nonprice terms would render these series very imperfect and noisy signals of the premium on external funds. Since the mid-1980s, however, the U.S. market for below-investment-grade debt, sometimes referred to as high-yield bonds or, less euphemistically, junk bonds, has developed enormously. Gertler and Lown (1999) note that firms raising funds in the high-yield bond market are likely to be precisely those that face the type of market frictions that the theory of the financial accelerator describes. Moreover, since the opportunity cost of internal funding for firms is likely to be close to the safe rate of interest such as that on government or AAA rated debt, the spread between high-yield bonds and government debt or AAA rated debt is likely to be a good indicator of the premium on external finance. If the theory of the financial accelerator works in practice, therefore, one would expect the high-yield spread to be a countercyclical predictor of future real activity. II. Data Monthly data for the United States for the period 1964M1 2001M12 were obtained on real industrial production, the consumer price index, the three-month Treasury bill rate, and the ten-year government bond yield from the International Monetary 379

8 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor Fund s International Financial Statistics database. A monthly series on the highyield spread was constructed as follows. First, we obtained data from the Merrill Lynch Global Bond Indices database, an index (in annualized yield terms) of the yields on corporate bonds publicly issued in the U.S. domestic market with a year or more to maturity that were rated BBB3 or lower. We then subtracted the ten-year government bond yield from this to construct the spread. Because the market for below-investment-grade debt only developed during the mid-1980s, a reliable series for the high-yield spread could be constructed only for the period of the 1990s. 4 III. Long-Horizon Regressions The dependent variable in the basic long-horizon regressions is the annualized cumulative percentage change in real industrial production: 1200 y ( y y ), k t+ k (4) k t+ k t where k denotes the forecasting horizon in quarters and y t is the logarithm of an index of real industrial production at time t. The k-period change in the logarithm of industrial output is multiplied by (1200/k) to ensure that the percentage growth rate is expressed in annualized terms, as the interest rates are. The slope of the nominal yield curve is measured by the difference between the yield on ten-year U.S. government bonds (R t ) and the three-month U.S. Treasury bill rate (r t ), while the high-yield spread is measured as the difference between the junk bond yield (Q t ) and the ten-year government bond yield (R t ). The basic regression equations are therefore of the form: ( ) + y = α + β R r η, k t+ k k k t t t+ k (5) for the term spread regressions, and ( ) + y = γ + δ Q R ε, k t+ k k k t t t+ k (6) for the high-yield spread regressions, where η t +k and ε t +k are the forecast errors. 4 Note that, since the index of yields on below-investment-grade corporate debt is constructed using a range of maturities, while we subtract the ten-year government bond yield to obtain a measure of the highyield spread, there is a possibility that our measure of the high-yield spread may contain some term structure effects. We would argue that this is not important for our analysis, however, on the following grounds. First, if term structure effects were important in our high-yield spread measure, then we should expect the predictive content of the two series to be similar whereas as we show below they behave quite differently. Second, the correlation between the two series is in fact very low: over the period 1991M1 2001M12 the correlation coefficient is We also experimented using high-yield spread measures constructed using government bond yields of different maturities and found that this made little difference to the results which is not surprising given the very high correlation of these alternative measures of the highyield spread and the measure used in this paper: using daily data from the end of 1987 until the beginning of 2003, we found that the correlation between the high-yield spreads using ten-year and two-year government bond yields was 0.93, while the correlation between the high-yield spreads using ten-year and threeyear government bond yields was

9 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY As is well known, even under the assumption of rational expectations, the fact that the sampling interval is smaller than the forecasting horizon generates a moving average forecast error of order one less than the number of sampling periods in the forecast horizon, because of common news items generating successive forecast errors. Hence, the forecast errors may be assumed to have a moving average representation of order k 1. This was allowed for by using an appropriate method-of-moments correction to the estimated covariance matrix (Hansen, 1982). As is also well known, however, tests for the significance of long-horizon parameters may also suffer from considerable size distortion in small samples. Accordingly, we constructed empirical marginal significance levels for the asymptotic t-ratios using bootstrapping techniques that allow for the small-sample empirical distribution of the test statistics to be constructed under the null hypothesis that the term spread or the high-yield spread does not predict economic activity. A brief description of this bootstrapping algorithm is given in Appendix II. 5 Term Spread Regressions The results of estimating equation (5) for forecast horizons up to 24 months ahead are given in Tables 1, 2, and 3 for various sample periods. In Table 1, we report the long-horizon regressions for the 1970s and 1980s i.e., for the sample period 1970M1 1990M12. These results are consistent with those reported in the literature for similar sample periods: the slope coefficient is strongly significantly different from zero, with t-ratios in every case of the order of around four and empirical marginal significance levels of zero to two decimal places. In Table 2, we report results for the same regressions applied to data for the mid- to late 1960s i.e., 1964M1 1970M12. Although the term spread does have some predictive power for real activity during this period, the slope coefficients are significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level only for horizons ranging from six to nine months. The value of the t-ratios, even for the significant estimated coefficients, is also much lower than for the 1970s and 1980s, ranging between 2.1 and 2.9. Table 3 shows the results of estimating the long-horizon term spread regressions for the most recent period, 1991M1 2001M12. The estimated slope coefficients are in every case insignificantly different from zero at the 5 percent level. The goodness of fit of the long-horizon regressions has also fallen dramatically at all horizons, relative to the corresponding levels for the 1970s and 1980s. Overall, therefore, the strong predictive content of the term spread with respect to future real economic activity seems to be largely confined to the period 5We also tested for the possibility of simultaneity in the long-horizon regressions, since it is feasible that shocks to current output (which enters the k-period change) may also affect the term spread or the highyield spread through, for example, a policy Taylor rule or because of an immediate effect of an output shock on the premium for external funds. To test for this we used Hausman s (1978) specification test, which tests for differences between OLS and instrumental variable estimators (since only the latter are consistent when there is simultaneity), using three lags of each of the change in output, the term spread, and the high-yield spread as instruments. In no case was there evidence of simultaneity at the 5 percent level. 381

10 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor Table 1. Term Spread Predictions of Industrial Production Growth, 1971M1 1990M12 Forecast s.e. Horizon k β k R 2 (percent) (4.080) [0.00] (3.566) [0.00] (3.625) [0.00] (3.734) [0.00] (3.833) [0.00] (3.870) [0.00] (3.954) [0.00] (3.938) [0.00] (3.868) [0.00] (3.928) [0.00] (3.864) [0.00] (4.218) [0.00] Notes: Estimation is by ordinary least squares, with a method-of-moments correction to the estimated co-variance matrix. k is the forecast horizon in months, R 2 denotes the coefficient in determination, and s.e. denotes the standard error of the regression. Figures in parentheses below coefficient estimates are asymptotic t-ratios and those in square brackets are the bootstrapped empirical marginal significance levels to two decimal places. An intercept term was also included in the regressions. 382

11 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY Table 2. Term Spread Predictions of Industrial Production Growth, 1964M1 1970M12 Forecast s.e. Horizon k β k R 2 (percent) (0.428) [0.80] (0.536) [0.71] (0.709) [0.58] (1.027) [0.37] (1.470) [0.17] (2.127) [0.04] (2.912) [0.01] (2.893) [0.01] (2.414) [0.02] (1.996) [0.06] (1.947) [0.06] (1.985) [0.06] Notes: Estimation is by ordinary least squares, with a method-of-moments correction to the estimated covariance matrix. k is the forecast horizon in months, R 2 denotes the coefficient in determination, and s.e. denotes the standard error of the regression. Figures in parentheses below coefficient estimates are asymptotic t-ratios and those in square brackets are the bootstrapped empirical marginal significance levels to two decimal places. An intercept term was also included in the regressions. 383

12 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor Table 3. Term Spread Predictions of Industrial Production Growth, 1991M1 2001M12 Forecast s.e. Horizon k β k R 2 (percent) (1.981) [0.06] (2.031) [0.06] (1.888) [0.08] (1.729) [0.11] (1.595) [0.32] (1.520) [0.16] (1.497) [0.17] (1.479) [0.17] (1.450) [0.18] (1.416) [0.30] (1.538) [0.16] (1.775) [0.11] Notes: Estimation is by ordinary least squares, with a method-of-moments correction to the estimated covariance matrix. k is the forecast horizon in months, R 2 denotes the coefficient in determination, and s.e. denotes the standard error of the regression. Figures in parentheses below coefficient estimates are asymptotic t-ratios and those in square brackets are the bootstrapped empirical marginal significance levels to two decimal places. An intercept term was also included in the regressions. 384

13 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY of the 1970s and 1980s. For the 1960s, the relationship appears to be much weakened, while for the 1990s the predictive power of the term spread appears to have virtually disappeared. High-Yield Spread Regressions Given that the market for below-investment-grade debt only developed in the United States in the mid-1980s, lack of availability of data on the high-yield spread forced us to consider only the most recent of the three sample periods, i.e., 1991M1 2001M12. The resulting long-horizon regressions are reported in Table 4. The sign of the estimated slope coefficient is negative in every case: a larger spread predicts a slowdown, exactly as suggested by the theory of the financial accelerator. The predictive content of the high-yield spread is, moreover, quite striking. In every case, the estimated slope coefficient is strongly significantly different from zero, with an empirical marginal significance level of virtually zero in every case, with t-ratios ranging in absolute value from around three to around nine. The goodness of fit, as measured by the coefficient of determination, is in nearly every case very much higher than the corresponding R 2 for the term spread regressions, even during the heyday of the term spread during the 1970s and 1980s, the two exceptions being at the 18- and 24-month horizons. Finally, since the theory of the financial accelerator suggests the possibility of nonlinear interactions between financial variables and real activity, we examined whether unusual levels of high-yield spreads convey additional information on real activity. Our proxy for unusual levels is a spread that is more than 1.5 standard deviations above the sample mean. To test for this, we adjusted the longhorizon regression (6) to: ( ) + ( ) y = γ + δ Q R θ I Q R ε, k t+ k k k t t k t t t t+ k where I t is a dummy variable that takes the value unity if the high-yield spread is more than 1.5 standard deviations above its mean over the sample period. The results of estimating this equation are shown in Table 5 and reveal that such abnormally high spreads do indeed predict an additional slowing down in growth at horizons of one to three months. It should be noted, however, that most of the abnormally large observations of the high-yield spread fall in the last year or so of the data sample. This was why we did not run the long-horizon regressions for horizons greater than 12 months. (7) IV. Out-of-Sample Predictions All of the tests of predictability that we have so far employed are in-sample tests in that they employ all of the data sample to estimate the long-horizon parameters. This contrasts with out-of-sample forecasting methods that typically either use a fixed post-estimation sample of data over which to forecast or else employ recursive or rolling (fixed window) regressions to forecast over a moving post-estimation sample. Typically, in macroeconomics and finance, researchers find it much easier 385

14 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor Table 4. High-Yield Spread Predictions of Industrial Production Growth, 1991M1 2001M12 Forecast s.e. Horizon k δ k R 2 (percent) ( 8.744) [0.00] ( 7.120) [0.00] ( 5.488) [0.00] ( 4.427) [0.00] ( 3.950) [0.00] ( 3.620) [0.00] ( 3.368) [0.00] ( 3.212) [0.00] ( 3.105) [0.00] ( 3.097) [0.001] ( 3.859) [0.00] ( 7.258) [0.00] Notes: Estimation is by ordinary least squares, with a method-of-moments correction to the estimated covariance matrix. k is the forecast horizon in months, R 2 denotes the coefficient in determination, and s.e. denotes the standard error of the regression. Figures in parentheses below coefficient estimates are asymptotic t-ratios and those in square brackets are the bootstrapped empirical marginal significance levels to two decimal places. An intercept term was also included in the regressions. 386

15 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY Table 5. Threshold Effects in High Yield Spread Predictions of Industrial Production, 1991M1 2001M12 Forecast s.e. Horizon k δ k θ k R 2 (percent) ( 2.635) ( 2.144) [0.00] [0.03] ( 2.483) ( 2.430) [0.01] [0.01] ( 2.699) ( 2.121) [0.00] [0.03] ( 2.685) ( 1.657) [0.00] [0.09] ( 2.621) ( 1.193) [0.00] [0.23] ( 2.720) ( 0.751) [0.00] [0.45] ( 2.671) ( 0.514) [0.00] [0.60] ( 2.150) ( 0.650) [0.03] [0.51] ( 2.007) ( 0.683) [0.04] [0.49] ( 1.750) ( 0.223) [0.07] [0.82] Notes: Estimation is by ordinary least squares, with a method-of-moments correction to the estimated covariance matrix. k is the forecast horizon in months, R 2 denotes the coefficient in determination, and s.e. denotes the standard error of the regression. Figures in parentheses below coefficient estimates are asymptotic t-ratios and those in square brackets are the bootstrapped empirical marginal significance levels to two decimal places. An intercept term was also included in the regressions. 387

16 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor to reject the null hypothesis of no predictability using in-sample tests than they do with out-of-sample tests. This stylized fact appears to have generated a widely accepted belief that in-sample tests are biased in favor of detecting spurious predictability. In fact, as noted in a recent paper by Inoue and Kilian (2002), This perception has led to a tendency to discount significant evidence in favor of predictability based on in-sample tests, if this evidence cannot be supported by out-of-sample tests. Inoue and Kilian go on, however, to challenge this view, through a formal analysis of the size and power characteristics of in-sample and out-of-sample tests of predictability. They demonstrate, inter alia, that although in-sample and out-ofsample tests are asymptotically equally reliable under standard assumptions, 6 insample tests may have much greater power to reject a false null hypothesis of no predictability in small samples. Indeed, these authors show that out-of-sample tests may have less than 50 percent of the power of in-sample tests, thus providing an alternative explanation of the observed tendency of in-sample tests to reject the null of no predictability more often than out-of-sample tests. It is clear, however, that the striking findings of Inoue and Kilian should not be taken as an excuse not to conduct out-of-sample tests but, rather, should be taken into account when interpreting the findings of in-sample and out-of-sample tests of forecast failure. In particular, and especially in cases such as the present analysis where there is not an issue of data mining, the low power of out-of-sample tests means that their failure to reject a null hypothesis of no predictability (or of equal predictive ability of two alternative methods) does not necessarily imply that insample evidence of predictability is spurious. On the other hand, if the null hypothesis of no predictability or of equal forecasting ability of methods can be rejected at standard significance levels using out-of-sample tests, then, given their low power, this should be taken as very strong corroborating evidence of the in-sample findings. Accordingly, we proceeded to construct out-of-sample tests to compare the ability of movements in the high-yield spread to predict economic activity over the 1990s with that of movements in the term spread. We did this in two ways. In our first investigation of relative out-of-sample predictive ability, we used a fixed post-estimation sample of three years, 1999M1 2001M12, to construct a portmanteau test of the equality of the predictive ability of the term spread and the high-yield spread. We used data over the sample period 1991M1 1998M12 to estimate the long-horizon equations (5) and (6) for k =1,2, We then obtained two sets of 36 forecast errors over the postestimation sample, based alternately on the high-yield spread or the term spread in 1998M12, as (1) ) ) ζ = y α β R r, k,,... k k M k k k( M M ) = (8) for the term spread, and 6That is, under the null of no predictability, and provided that no data mining has taken place, and in the absence of unmodeled structural change. The authors also show that both in-sample and out-of-sample tests are susceptible to size distortions arising from data mining. 388

17 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY (2) ) ) ζ = y γ δ Q R, k,,... k k M k k k( M M ) = (9) for the high-yield spread, where hats over the parameters denote that they were estimated using data for the period 1991M1 1998M12. We then used these errors to construct measures of the mean square error and mean absolute error over the 36 months, and in turn used these to construct a test for equal predictive ability based on the Diebold-Mariano (1995) test statistic for equality of forecast accuracy. The Diebold-Mariano statistic is defined as DM = d 2π f ), ( 0) N (10) where d is an average over N forecast periods of a general loss differential function d k such as the difference in squared forecast errors (d k =[ζ (1) k ] 2 [ζ (2) k ] 2 ) or, in absolute errors (d k = ζ (1) k ζ (2) k ), i.e., 1 N d = d N k = 1 k for N = 36 in the present application, and f ) (0) is a consistent estimate of the spectral density of the loss differential function at frequency zero. 7 Under certain regularity conditions, DM will be distributed as standard normal under the null hypothesis of equal forecast accuracy. 8 Our second set of tests involved assessing the relative predictive ability of the high-yield spread and the term spread by comparing the forecast accuracy of the multi-step-ahead predictions of the long-horizon models (5) and (6) using recursive estimation over the period 1999M1 2001M12 (with initial estimates using data for 1991M1 1998M12) for the same values of k as used in our long-horizon in-sample exercises, i.e., k = 1 12, 18, 24. For the long-horizon regression model of horizon k, this generates a sequence of 36 k-step-ahead forecast errors of the form ( k,1) ) ) ζ = y α τ 1 β τ 1 R r, τ 1, τ k 1998M12+ τ k k 1998M12+ τ k 1998M12+ τ k for the term spread, and ( ) ( ) ( k,2) ) ) ζ = y γ τ 1 δ τ 1 Q R, τ 1, ( ) ( ) ( ) = ( ) = τ k 1998M12+ τ k k 1998M12+ τ k 1998M12+ τ k (11) (12) 7A consistent estimate of the spectral density at frequency zero was obtained using the method of Newey and West (1987), with the truncation lag selected using the Andrews (1991) AR(1) rule. 8It is well known that problems may arise in using the DM statistic in small samples (see e.g., West, 1996; West and McCracken, 1998; McCracken, 2000; Clarida and others, 2002; and Kilian and Taylor, 2003). In the present application, particularly in the construction of our portmanteau test statistic where we are dealing with various multi-step-ahead forecasts, the asymptotic distribution of the DM statistic is unknown so that the marginal significance levels we report for this statistic should be treated with caution. 389

18 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor for the high-yield spread, where λ ) (τ 1) k denotes the estimated value of the longhorizon parameter λ k using data for the period 1991M1 to 1998M12 + τ 1,for λ = α,β,γ,δ.we then again used the Diebold-Mariano statistic (10) to test for equality of the forecast accuracy of the models for each value of k, based on the difference in squared errors or in absolute errors (dτ k =[ζ (k,1) τ ] 2 [ζ (k,2) τ ] 2 or dτ k = ζ (k,1) τ ζ (k,2) τ and 1 d = N N d k τ = 1 τ for the k-horizon model one-step-ahead forecasts). The results of the out-of-sample portmanteau test of equality of forecast accuracy of the high-yield spread and term spread models are given in Table 6 and show that the high-yield spread regressions easily and significantly dominate the term spread regressions in terms of out-of-sample forecast accuracy. This result is echoed, moreover, in the k-step-ahead forecast results for each of the individual long-horizon regressions, as shown in Table 7: the high-yield spread model forecasts are in every case superior in terms of either mean square error or mean absolute error, and strongly significantly so in every case except for the k =1 and k =2 regression models, based on mean square error. Given our earlier remarks concerning the relatively low power of out-of-sample forecast tests, this is indeed a strong vindication of the superiority of the high-yield spread as a predictor of economic activity over the 1990s relative to the term spread. V. Supply and Demand Innovations in Real Output Given the apparent importance of the high-yield spread as a predictor of real economic activity during the last decade or so, we carried out some further investigations as to whether the spread is able to predict the cumulative growth in output when it is stripped of, alternately, its demand-side and supply-side components or, to be precise, its temporary and permanent components. Permanent and temporary output movements may be variously interpreted according to the underlying theoretical framework employed. In the traditional aggregate demand aggregate supply (ADAS) model with a long-run vertical supply curve, for example, aggregate demand disturbances result in a temporary rise Table 6. Portmanteau Tests of Equality of Out-of-Sample Forecast Accuracy over the Period 1999M1 2001M12 Forecasts Based on Forecasts Based on Diebold-Mariano High-Yield Spread Term Spread Statistic Mean square error (0.00) Mean absolute error (0.00) Notes: See Section IV on the construction of these statistics. Figures in parentheses are marginal significance levels to two decimal places. 390

19 391 Table 7. Out-of-Sample Tests of Equality of Forecast Accuracy over the Period 1999M1 2001M12, k-step-ahead Forecasts Mean Square Mean Square Mean Absolute Long- Error from Error from Diebold-Mariano Error from Mean Absolute Diebold-Mariano Horizon Forecasts Forecasts Statistic Based Forecasts Based Error from Statistic Based Regression Based on Based on on Mean on High-Yield Forecasts Based on Mean Model, k High-Yield Spread Term Spread Square Error Spread on Term Spread Absolute Error (0.23) (0.02) (0.11) (0.01) (0.04) (0.02) (0.01) (0.02) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) Notes: See Section IV on the construction of these statistics. Figures in parentheses are marginal significance levels to two decimal places. THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY

20 Ashoka Mody and Mark P. Taylor in output, while aggregate supply disturbances permanently affect the level of aggregate output. Blanchard and Quah (1989) use an ADAS framework in their analysis and associate aggregate supply shocks with permanent shocks and aggregate demand shocks with temporary shocks. In this paper we shall follow their taxonomy. While it is possible that demand disturbances may have permanent effects on the real side of the economy, we concur with Blanchard and Quah that shocks having a permanent effect on output are likely to be due mostly, if not wholly, to supply-side factors, while those having only a temporary effect are likely to be due mostly, if not wholly, to demand-side factors. If the permanent long-run effects of demand disturbances are small relative to the long-run permanent effects of supply disturbances, then the Blanchard-Quah taxonomy is a useful organizing principle for empirical purposes. Readers rejecting this taxonomy, however, may simply reinterpret our analysis as investigating whether nominal spreads affect the permanent or the temporary components of real output movements. Given this taxonomy of permanent and temporary shocks to output, supply and demand shocks to real economic activity can be identified by imposing appropriate restrictions on the Wold representation of time series for real and nominal macroeconomic variables. In particular, consider the Wold representation for annualized percentage changes in the logarithm of output and the logarithm of prices: y (13) = φ φ 1 t j 11j 12 j ς1 t L, p φ φ 1 t j= 1 21j 22 j ς2t where the φ imj are the parameters of the multivariate moving average representation and ς 1t and ς 2t are white-noise innovations. We can identify ς 1t and ς 2t as demand and supply innovations in the following way. Write ς t =(ς 1t ς 2t ), and denote the bivariate vector of innovations recovered from the vector autoregressive representation for ( 1 y t 1 p t ) as υ t. Since the vector autoregressive (VAR) representation is simply an inversion of the Wold representation (13), υ t will in general be a linear function of ς t, υ t =Aς t,say,where A is a 2 2 matrix of constants. To recover the underlying demand and supply innovations from the VAR residuals then requires that the four elements of A be identified, which requires four identifying restrictions. Three restrictions can be obtained by normalizing the variances of ς 1t and ς 2t to unity and setting their covariances to zero. (See Blanchard and Quah, 1989, for a defense of these restrictions.) The fourth, crucial identifying restriction, which effectively identifies ς 1t as the demand innovation (or temporary output innovation), is the requirement that ς 1t have no long-run effect on the (log-) level of real output, although it may affect the long-run price level. The latter restriction on the Wold representation (13) may be written: φ 11 j j= 1 = 0. (14) 392

21 THE HIGH-YIELD SPREAD AS A PREDICTOR OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY These four restrictions are then sufficient to recover the underlying temporary and permanent innovations to output, which, as we discussed above, may be interpreted as underlying demand and supply innovations, respectively. 9 Having identified the supply and demand innovations, we can then partition the moving average representation for real industrial output into counterfactual series, corresponding to the path that would have obtained in the absence of demand innovations and the path that would have obtained in the absence of supply innovations over the estimation period. We can then utilize these counterfactual series in tests of the predictive power of the high-yield spread. We applied this method to the monthly series in the logarithm of industrial production and the consumer price index for the whole sample period, 1964M1 2001M12. Preliminary unit root (Augmented Dickey Fuller) tests on the data (not reported) showed the change in the logarithm of real industrial output and the change in the logarithm of the consumer price index to be stationary processes. There was also no evidence of cointegration between industrial production and prices. This implies that output growth and inflation can be modeled as a bivariate moving average representation, which can be inverted to a pure autoregression not involving error correction terms. We therefore proceeded to estimate a vector autoregressive representation for the vector time series ( 1 y t 1 p t ). The order of the VAR was chosen by sequentially excluding the highest lags of both series, starting from a twelfth-order VAR and testing the exclusion restrictions on the system using a likelihood ratio test. This process was stopped when the exclusion restrictions were jointly significant at the 5 percent level. This led to a choice of lag depth of six. The residuals from the estimated equations were judged to be approximately white noise, using either individual Ljung Box statistics or Hosking s multivariate portmanteau statistic. In fact, this choice of lag depth coincided with the lag depth chosen by minimizing the Akaike Information Criterion. In Figure 2 we have graphed the impulse response functions for the log-levels of output and prices in response to the identified supply and demand innovations. By construction, the long-run impact of demand shocks on real output is zero, but the shape of each of the impulse response functions in each case accords with simple economic priors in that a positive demand shock raises both output (in the short run) and prices (in both the short run and the long run), while a positive supply shock raises output and depresses prices (in both the short run and the long run). 10 VI. Counterfactual Analysis We then used the Blanchard-Quah estimation results to break down the series for U.S. real industrial production into counterfactual series, corresponding to the 9 For further details of the decomposition, see Blanchard and Quah (1989), Bayoumi and Taylor (1995), or Taylor (2003). Taylor (2003) discusses recursive restrictions of this type in the general multivariate case. 10 Taylor (2003) notes that, in general, there will be multiple solutions to recursive restrictions of the type suggested by Blanchard and Quah (1989) and that informal or qualitative identifying restrictions of this kind are necessary in order to achieve full identification. 393

Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B

Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B Economics Letters 82 (2004) 167 172 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B Ashoka Mody a,1, Mark P. Taylor b,c, * a Research Department,

More information

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector by Wensheng Peng, Kitty Lai, Frank Leung and Chang Shu of the Research Department A rise in the Hong Kong dollar risk premium,

More information

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds International Department Working Paper Series 00-E-3 Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds Yoshihito SAITO yoshihito.saitou@boj.or.jp Yoko TAKEDA youko.takeda@boj.or.jp

More information

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? International Review of Economics and Finance 9 (2000) 387 415 Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? Mathias Binswanger* Institute for Economics and the Environment, University

More information

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits Technical Paper Series Congressional Budget Office Washington, DC FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits Albert D. Metz Microeconomic and Financial Studies

More information

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? No. 11-1 Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? Geoffrey M.B. Tootell Abstract: This public policy brief examines the relationship between trend inflation and commodity price increases and

More information

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Karl Walentin Sveriges Riksbank 1. Background This paper is part of the large literature that takes as its starting point the

More information

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015 DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53 What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015 *University of Modena and Reggio Emilia RECent (Center for Economic Research) Address:

More information

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series.

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series. Cointegration The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series. Economic theory, however, often implies equilibrium

More information

Dynamic Probit Models and Financial Variables in Recession Forecasting

Dynamic Probit Models and Financial Variables in Recession Forecasting ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers Dynamic Probit Models and Financial Variables in Recession Forecasting Henri Nyberg University of Helsinki and HECER

More information

Causes of Inflation in the Iranian Economy

Causes of Inflation in the Iranian Economy Causes of Inflation in the Iranian Economy Hamed Armesh* and Abas Alavi Rad** It is clear that in the nearly last four decades inflation is one of the important problems of Iranian economy. In this study,

More information

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem Chapter Vector autoregressions We begin by taking a look at the data of macroeconomics. A way to summarize the dynamics of macroeconomic data is to make use of vector autoregressions. VAR models have become

More information

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates 518 Chapter 11 INFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY Thus, the monetary policy that is consistent with a permanent drop in inflation is a sudden upward jump in the money supply, followed by low growth. And, in

More information

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Emily Polito, Trinity College In the past two decades, there have been many empirical studies both in support of and opposing

More information

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER PROBLEMS WITHOUT ASTERISKS

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER PROBLEMS WITHOUT ASTERISKS Part III Answers to End-of-Chapter Problems 97 CHAPTER 1 ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER PROBLEMS WITHOUT ASTERISKS Why Study Money, Banking, and Financial Markets? 7. The basic activity of banks is to accept

More information

Learning From History: Examining Yield Spreads as a Predictor of Real Economic Activity

Learning From History: Examining Yield Spreads as a Predictor of Real Economic Activity 11 Learning From History: Examining Yield Spreads Nicholas Barnett 1 University of Minnesota-Twin Cities Abstract Economists often use complicated models in an attempt to predict economic activity; however,

More information

INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP?

INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP? 107 INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP? Maurice K. Shalishali, Columbus State University Johnny C. Ho, Columbus State University ABSTRACT A test of IFE (International

More information

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION 7 The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION Since the 1970s one of the major issues in macroeconomics has been the extent to which low output and high unemployment

More information

12.1 Introduction. 12.2 The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

12.1 Introduction. 12.2 The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve Chapter 12 Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve By Charles I. Jones Media Slides Created By Dave Brown Penn State University The short-run model summary: Through the MP curve the nominal interest rate

More information

Monetary Policy and Credit Cards: Evidence from a Small-Open Economy

Monetary Policy and Credit Cards: Evidence from a Small-Open Economy Monetary Policy and Cards: Evidence from a Small-Open Economy by Hakan Yilmazkuday Department of Economics DETU Working Paper 1-1 September 21 131 Cecil B. Moore Avenue, Philadelphia, PA 19122 http://www.temple.edu/cla/economics/

More information

Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models

Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models 1 Contents: Lehrstuhl für Department Empirische of Wirtschaftsforschung Empirical Research and und Econometrics Ökonometrie IV.1 Vector Autoregressive Models (VAR)...

More information

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth Pasquale Foresti 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/2962/ MPRA Paper No. 2962, posted

More information

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 9 The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Chapter Outline The FE Line: Equilibrium in the Labor Market The IS Curve: Equilibrium in the Goods Market The LM Curve:

More information

Working Papers. Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market. Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek. No. 2/2012 (68)

Working Papers. Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market. Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek. No. 2/2012 (68) Working Papers No. 2/2012 (68) Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market Warsaw 2012 Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market

More information

Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler *

Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler * Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler * In recent decades, asset booms and busts have been important factors in macroeconomic fluctuations in both

More information

Import Prices and Inflation

Import Prices and Inflation Import Prices and Inflation James D. Hamilton Department of Economics, University of California, San Diego Understanding the consequences of international developments for domestic inflation is an extremely

More information

Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data

Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data Patrick D Arcy and Emily Poole* This article discusses how bond, equity and foreign exchange markets have responded to the surprise component of Australian

More information

Analyzing the Effect of Change in Money Supply on Stock Prices

Analyzing the Effect of Change in Money Supply on Stock Prices 72 Analyzing the Effect of Change in Money Supply on Stock Prices I. Introduction Billions of dollars worth of shares are traded in the stock market on a daily basis. Many people depend on the stock market

More information

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2 Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2.1. The Keynesian Consumption Function 2.2. The Complete Keynesian Model 2.3. The Keynesian-Cross Model 2.4. The IS-LM Model 2.5. The Keynesian AD-AS Model 2.6. Conclusion

More information

Project LINK Meeting New York, 20-22 October 2010. Country Report: Australia

Project LINK Meeting New York, 20-22 October 2010. Country Report: Australia Project LINK Meeting New York, - October 1 Country Report: Australia Prepared by Peter Brain: National Institute of Economic and Industry Research, and Duncan Ironmonger: Department of Economics, University

More information

Relationship among crude oil prices, share prices and exchange rates

Relationship among crude oil prices, share prices and exchange rates Relationship among crude oil prices, share prices and exchange rates Do higher share prices and weaker dollar lead to higher crude oil prices? Akira YANAGISAWA Leader Energy Demand, Supply and Forecast

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 213-23 August 19, 213 The Price of Stock and Bond Risk in Recoveries BY SIMON KWAN Investor aversion to risk varies over the course of the economic cycle. In the current recovery,

More information

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model 1 September 004 A. Introduction and assumptions The classical normal linear regression model can be written

More information

Strategy Document 1/03

Strategy Document 1/03 Strategy Document / Monetary policy in the period 5 March to 5 June Discussed by the Executive Board at its meeting of 5 February. Approved by the Executive Board at its meeting of 5 March Background Norges

More information

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

VI. Real Business Cycles Models VI. Real Business Cycles Models Introduction Business cycle research studies the causes and consequences of the recurrent expansions and contractions in aggregate economic activity that occur in most industrialized

More information

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes Why the drivers of migration matter for the labour market AN26/2 Jed Armstrong and Chris McDonald April 26 Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note Series

More information

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts.

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts. Agenda What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycles.. 11-1 11-2 Business cycles are the short-run fluctuations in aggregate economic activity around its long-run growth path. Y Time 11-3 11-4 1 Components

More information

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS 1. The short-run aggregate supply curve is horizontal at: A) a level of output determined by aggregate demand. B) the natural level of output. C) the level of output at which the

More information

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge Stefano Eusepi, Marc Giannoni and Bruce Preston The views expressed are those of the authors and are not necessarily re

More information

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics. 1 Module C: Fiscal Policy and Budget Deficits Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics. Fiscal and monetary policies are the two major tools

More information

The information content of lagged equity and bond yields

The information content of lagged equity and bond yields Economics Letters 68 (2000) 179 184 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase The information content of lagged equity and bond yields Richard D.F. Harris *, Rene Sanchez-Valle School of Business and Economics,

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES PROBLEM SETS.. In general, the forward rate can be viewed as the sum of the market s expectation of the future

More information

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle?

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle? Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle? Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University, Ithaca, N.Y. yw57@cornell.edu Abstract Consumption in the US leads output at the business cycle frequency.

More information

THE IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC FACTORS ON NON-PERFORMING LOANS IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

THE IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC FACTORS ON NON-PERFORMING LOANS IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA Abstract THE IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC FACTORS ON NON-PERFORMING LOANS IN THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA Dorina CLICHICI 44 Tatiana COLESNICOVA 45 The purpose of this research is to estimate the impact of several

More information

The Liquidity Trap and U.S. Interest Rates in the 1930s

The Liquidity Trap and U.S. Interest Rates in the 1930s The Liquidity Trap and U.S. Interest Rates in the 1930s SHORT SUMMARY Christopher Hanes Department of Economics School of Business University of Mississippi University, MS 38677 (662) 915-5829 chanes@bus.olemiss.edu

More information

INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE. Thursday 4 th February 2016. Opening remarks by the Governor

INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE. Thursday 4 th February 2016. Opening remarks by the Governor INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE Thursday 4 th February 2016 Opening remarks by the Governor Good afternoon. At its meeting yesterday, the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) voted 9-0 to maintain Bank Rate

More information

Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate?

Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate? University of Wollongong Research Online Faculty of Commerce - Papers (Archive) Faculty of Business 2013 Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate? Abbas

More information

PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU

PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU The t -Test If x 1,..., x n are independent and identically distributed with mean 0, and n is not too small, then t = x 0 s n has a standard

More information

Testing The Quantity Theory of Money in Greece: A Note

Testing The Quantity Theory of Money in Greece: A Note ERC Working Paper in Economic 03/10 November 2003 Testing The Quantity Theory of Money in Greece: A Note Erdal Özmen Department of Economics Middle East Technical University Ankara 06531, Turkey ozmen@metu.edu.tr

More information

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves Economics 7344, Spring 2013 Bent E. Sørensen INTEREST RATE THEORY We will cover fixed income securities. The major categories of long-term fixed income securities are federal government bonds, corporate

More information

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Randi Næs, Johannes A. Skjeltorp and Bernt Arne Ødegaard This Internet appendix contains additional material to the paper Stock Market

More information

EUROSYSTEM STAFF MACROECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR THE EURO AREA

EUROSYSTEM STAFF MACROECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR THE EURO AREA EUROSYSTEM STAFF MACROECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR THE EURO AREA On the basis of the information available up to 22 May 2009, Eurosystem staff have prepared projections for macroeconomic developments in the

More information

Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty

Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty 1 Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty Appendix to the speech given by Ben Broadbent, External Member of the Monetary Policy Committee, Bank of England At the London Business School,

More information

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely Long-Term Interest Rates and Inflation: A Fisherian Approach Peter N. Ireland In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely on long-term bond yields to measure the public s long-term

More information

Current Issues. Before each of the last six recessions, shortterm

Current Issues. Before each of the last six recessions, shortterm Volume 12, Number 5 July/August 26 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK www.newyorkfed.org/research/current_issues Current Issues IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE www.newyorkfed.org/research/current_issues The Yield

More information

2. Linear regression with multiple regressors

2. Linear regression with multiple regressors 2. Linear regression with multiple regressors Aim of this section: Introduction of the multiple regression model OLS estimation in multiple regression Measures-of-fit in multiple regression Assumptions

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES Chapter - The Term Structure of Interest Rates CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES PROBLEM SETS.. In general, the forward rate can be viewed as the sum of the market s expectation of the future

More information

Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs. and. Economic Activity

Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs. and. Economic Activity Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs and Economic Activity Mark Gertler and Peter Karadi NYU and ECB BIS, March 215 The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the offi

More information

18 ECB FACTORS AFFECTING LENDING TO THE PRIVATE SECTOR AND THE SHORT-TERM OUTLOOK FOR MONEY AND LOAN DYNAMICS

18 ECB FACTORS AFFECTING LENDING TO THE PRIVATE SECTOR AND THE SHORT-TERM OUTLOOK FOR MONEY AND LOAN DYNAMICS Box 2 FACTORS AFFECTING LENDING TO THE PRIVATE SECTOR AND THE SHORT-TERM OUTLOOK FOR MONEY AND LOAN DYNAMICS The intensification of the financial crisis in the fourth quarter of 211 had a considerable

More information

TEMPORAL CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN STOCK MARKET CAPITALIZATION, TRADE OPENNESS AND REAL GDP: EVIDENCE FROM THAILAND

TEMPORAL CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN STOCK MARKET CAPITALIZATION, TRADE OPENNESS AND REAL GDP: EVIDENCE FROM THAILAND I J A B E R, Vol. 13, No. 4, (2015): 1525-1534 TEMPORAL CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN STOCK MARKET CAPITALIZATION, TRADE OPENNESS AND REAL GDP: EVIDENCE FROM THAILAND Komain Jiranyakul * Abstract: This study

More information

Module 5: Multiple Regression Analysis

Module 5: Multiple Regression Analysis Using Statistical Data Using to Make Statistical Decisions: Data Multiple to Make Regression Decisions Analysis Page 1 Module 5: Multiple Regression Analysis Tom Ilvento, University of Delaware, College

More information

Debt, Delinquencies, and Consumer Spending Jonathan McCarthy

Debt, Delinquencies, and Consumer Spending Jonathan McCarthy February 1997 Volume 3 Number 3 Debt, Delinquencies, and Consumer Spending Jonathan McCarthy The sharp rise in household debt and delinquency rates over the last year has led to speculation that consumers

More information

Chapter 11. Keynesianism: The Macroeconomics of Wage and Price Rigidity. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Chapter 11. Keynesianism: The Macroeconomics of Wage and Price Rigidity. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 11 Keynesianism: The Macroeconomics of Wage and Price Rigidity Chapter Outline Real-Wage Rigidity Price Stickiness Monetary and Fiscal Policy in the Keynesian Model The Keynesian Theory of Business

More information

I. Basic concepts: Buoyancy and Elasticity II. Estimating Tax Elasticity III. From Mechanical Projection to Forecast

I. Basic concepts: Buoyancy and Elasticity II. Estimating Tax Elasticity III. From Mechanical Projection to Forecast Elements of Revenue Forecasting II: the Elasticity Approach and Projections of Revenue Components Fiscal Analysis and Forecasting Workshop Bangkok, Thailand June 16 27, 2014 Joshua Greene Consultant IMF-TAOLAM

More information

On the long run relationship between gold and silver prices A note

On the long run relationship between gold and silver prices A note Global Finance Journal 12 (2001) 299 303 On the long run relationship between gold and silver prices A note C. Ciner* Northeastern University College of Business Administration, Boston, MA 02115-5000,

More information

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns.

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. Chapter 5 Conditional CAPM 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. In the 40+ years of its history, many systematic deviations

More information

Exchange rates and long-term bonds

Exchange rates and long-term bonds Exchange rates and long-term bonds Annika Alexius and Peter Sellin April 2002 Abstract Tentative evidence suggests that the empirical failure of uncovered interest parity (UIP) is confined to short-term

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

Potential research topics for joint research: Forecasting oil prices with forecast combination methods. Dean Fantazzini.

Potential research topics for joint research: Forecasting oil prices with forecast combination methods. Dean Fantazzini. Potential research topics for joint research: Forecasting oil prices with forecast combination methods Dean Fantazzini Koper, 26/11/2014 Overview of the Presentation Introduction Dean Fantazzini 2 Overview

More information

Asian Economic and Financial Review DETERMINANTS OF THE AUD/USD EXCHANGE RATE AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS

Asian Economic and Financial Review DETERMINANTS OF THE AUD/USD EXCHANGE RATE AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS Asian Economic and Financial Review ISSN(e): 2222-6737/ISSN(p): 2305-2147 journal homepage: http://www.aessweb.com/journals/5002 DETERMINANTS OF THE AUD/USD EXCHANGE RATE AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS Yu Hsing

More information

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model University of California-Davis Economics 1B-Intro to Macro Handout 8 TA: Jason Lee Email: jawlee@ucdavis.edu I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model In this chapter we develop a model

More information

BANK OF UGANDA. Good afternoon ladies and gentlemen, 1. Introduction

BANK OF UGANDA. Good afternoon ladies and gentlemen, 1. Introduction BANK OF UGANDA Speech by Prof. E. Tumusiime-Mutebile, Governor, Bank of Uganda, at the Dialogue on the Impact of Oil Price Volatility and its Implications for the Economy and for Macroeconomic Stability,

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE BOND SPREADS AND REAL ACTIVITY IN THE EURO AREA LEAST ANGLE REGRESSION FORECASTING AND THE PROBABILITY OF THE RECESSION

WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE BOND SPREADS AND REAL ACTIVITY IN THE EURO AREA LEAST ANGLE REGRESSION FORECASTING AND THE PROBABILITY OF THE RECESSION Working Paper Series No 1286 / JAnuary 2011 Corporate bond spreads and real activity in the euro Area least angle regression forecasting and the probability of the recession by Marco Buchmann WORKING PAPER

More information

Jarle Bergo: Monetary policy and the outlook for the Norwegian economy

Jarle Bergo: Monetary policy and the outlook for the Norwegian economy Jarle Bergo: Monetary policy and the outlook for the Norwegian economy Speech by Mr Jarle Bergo, Deputy Governor of Norges Bank, at the Capital markets seminar, hosted by Terra-Gruppen AS, Gardermoen,

More information

Determinants of the Hungarian forint/ US dollar exchange rate

Determinants of the Hungarian forint/ US dollar exchange rate Theoretical and Applied Economics FFet al Volume XXIII (2016), No. 1(606), Spring, pp. 163-170 Determinants of the Hungarian forint/ US dollar exchange rate Yu HSING Southeastern Louisiana University,

More information

Lars Nyberg: The Riksbank's monetary policy strategy

Lars Nyberg: The Riksbank's monetary policy strategy Lars Nyberg: The Riksbank's monetary policy strategy Speech by Mr Lars Nyberg, Deputy Governor of the Sveriges Riksbank, at the Foreign Banker s Association, Stockholm, 14 September 2006. Introduction

More information

Monetary Policy and Long-term Interest Rates

Monetary Policy and Long-term Interest Rates Monetary Policy and Long-term Interest Rates Shu Wu The University of Kansas First Draft: July 2004 This version: March 2005 Abstract This paper documents some new empirical results about the monetary

More information

Supply and Demand in the Market for Money: The Liquidity Preference Framework

Supply and Demand in the Market for Money: The Liquidity Preference Framework APPENDIX 3 TO CHAPTER 4 Supply and Demand in the arket for oney: The Liquidity Preference Framework Whereas the loanable funds framework determines the equilibrium interest rate using the supply of and

More information

Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP?

Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP? Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP? Raffaella Basile, Ministry of Economy and Finance, Dept. of Treasury Bruno Chiarini, University of Naples Parthenope,

More information

EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER

EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER NAME: IOANNA KOULLOUROU REG. NUMBER: 1004216 1 Term Paper Title: Explain what is meant by the term structure of interest rates. Critically evaluate

More information

Session 12. Aggregate Supply: The Phillips curve. Credibility

Session 12. Aggregate Supply: The Phillips curve. Credibility Session 12. Aggregate Supply: The Phillips curve. Credibility v Potential Output and v Okun s law v The Role of Expectations and the Phillips Curve v Oil Prices and v US Monetary Policy and World Real

More information

INDIRECT INFERENCE (prepared for: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition)

INDIRECT INFERENCE (prepared for: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition) INDIRECT INFERENCE (prepared for: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition) Abstract Indirect inference is a simulation-based method for estimating the parameters of economic models. Its

More information

Are the US current account deficits really sustainable? National University of Ireland, Galway

Are the US current account deficits really sustainable? National University of Ireland, Galway Provided by the author(s) and NUI Galway in accordance with publisher policies. Please cite the published version when available. Title Are the US current account deficits really sustainable? Author(s)

More information

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2014, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Homework Assignment #2

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2014, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Homework Assignment #2 THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2014, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Homework Assignment #2 Assignment: 1. Consumer Sentiment of the University of Michigan.

More information

Edmonds Community College Macroeconomic Principles ECON 202C - Winter 2011 Online Course Instructor: Andy Williams

Edmonds Community College Macroeconomic Principles ECON 202C - Winter 2011 Online Course Instructor: Andy Williams Edmonds Community College Macroeconomic Principles ECON 202C - Winter 2011 Online Course Instructor: Andy Williams Textbooks: Economics: Principles, Problems and Policies, 18th Edition, by McConnell, Brue,

More information

René Garcia Professor of finance

René Garcia Professor of finance Liquidity Risk: What is it? How to Measure it? René Garcia Professor of finance EDHEC Business School, CIRANO Cirano, Montreal, January 7, 2009 The financial and economic environment We are living through

More information

Sample Size and Power in Clinical Trials

Sample Size and Power in Clinical Trials Sample Size and Power in Clinical Trials Version 1.0 May 011 1. Power of a Test. Factors affecting Power 3. Required Sample Size RELATED ISSUES 1. Effect Size. Test Statistics 3. Variation 4. Significance

More information

Does the term structure of corporate interest rates predict business cycle turning points? Jordan Fixler. Senior Thesis Advisor: Ben Eden

Does the term structure of corporate interest rates predict business cycle turning points? Jordan Fixler. Senior Thesis Advisor: Ben Eden Does the term structure of corporate interest rates predict business cycle turning points? Jordan Fixler Senior Thesis Advisor: Ben Eden Abstract The Treasury Yield Curve has been a very accurate leading

More information

An introduction to Value-at-Risk Learning Curve September 2003

An introduction to Value-at-Risk Learning Curve September 2003 An introduction to Value-at-Risk Learning Curve September 2003 Value-at-Risk The introduction of Value-at-Risk (VaR) as an accepted methodology for quantifying market risk is part of the evolution of risk

More information

Econometric Modelling for Revenue Projections

Econometric Modelling for Revenue Projections Econometric Modelling for Revenue Projections Annex E 1. An econometric modelling exercise has been undertaken to calibrate the quantitative relationship between the five major items of government revenue

More information

Performing Unit Root Tests in EViews. Unit Root Testing

Performing Unit Root Tests in EViews. Unit Root Testing Página 1 de 12 Unit Root Testing The theory behind ARMA estimation is based on stationary time series. A series is said to be (weakly or covariance) stationary if the mean and autocovariances of the series

More information

How To Invest In High Yield Bonds

How To Invest In High Yield Bonds Investment Perspectives For high-yield bonds, market volatility can bring new opportunities Kevin Lorenz and Jean Lin, portfolio managers for TIAA-CREF High-Yield Fund Article Highlights: The decline in

More information

Corporate Defaults and Large Macroeconomic Shocks

Corporate Defaults and Large Macroeconomic Shocks Corporate Defaults and Large Macroeconomic Shocks Mathias Drehmann Bank of England Andrew Patton London School of Economics and Bank of England Steffen Sorensen Bank of England The presentation expresses

More information

Supplemental Unit 5: Fiscal Policy and Budget Deficits

Supplemental Unit 5: Fiscal Policy and Budget Deficits 1 Supplemental Unit 5: Fiscal Policy and Budget Deficits Fiscal and monetary policies are the two major tools available to policy makers to alter total demand, output, and employment. This feature will

More information

Bank of Japan Review. Global correlation among government bond markets and Japanese banks' market risk. February 2012. Introduction 2012-E-1

Bank of Japan Review. Global correlation among government bond markets and Japanese banks' market risk. February 2012. Introduction 2012-E-1 Bank of Japan Review 212-E-1 Global correlation among government bond markets and Japanese banks' market risk Financial System and Bank Examination Department Yoshiyuki Fukuda, Kei Imakubo, Shinichi Nishioka

More information

ANALYSIS OF EUROPEAN, AMERICAN AND JAPANESE GOVERNMENT BOND YIELDS

ANALYSIS OF EUROPEAN, AMERICAN AND JAPANESE GOVERNMENT BOND YIELDS Applied Time Series Analysis ANALYSIS OF EUROPEAN, AMERICAN AND JAPANESE GOVERNMENT BOND YIELDS Stationarity, cointegration, Granger causality Aleksandra Falkowska and Piotr Lewicki TABLE OF CONTENTS 1.

More information

Risk Decomposition of Investment Portfolios. Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Webinar January 2014

Risk Decomposition of Investment Portfolios. Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Webinar January 2014 Risk Decomposition of Investment Portfolios Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Webinar January 2014 Main Concepts for Today Investment practitioners rely on a decomposition of portfolio risk into factors to guide

More information

A Trading Strategy Based on the Lead-Lag Relationship of Spot and Futures Prices of the S&P 500

A Trading Strategy Based on the Lead-Lag Relationship of Spot and Futures Prices of the S&P 500 A Trading Strategy Based on the Lead-Lag Relationship of Spot and Futures Prices of the S&P 500 FE8827 Quantitative Trading Strategies 2010/11 Mini-Term 5 Nanyang Technological University Submitted By:

More information

Chapter 12. Unemployment and Inflation. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Chapter 12. Unemployment and Inflation. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation Chapter Outline Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-Off? The Problem of Unemployment The Problem of Inflation 12-2 Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a

More information

Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples

Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, UiO 18 August 2009 Lecture plan and web pages for this course The lecture plan is at http://folk.uio.no/rnymoen/econ3410_h08_index.html,

More information