Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity"

Transcription

1 Financial Analysts Journal Volume 68 Number CFA Institute Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity Clifford S. Asness, Andrea Frazzini, and Lasse H. Pedersen The authors show that leverage aversion changes the predictions of modern portfolio theory: Safer assets must offer higher risk-adjusted returns than riskier assets. Consuming the high risk-adjusted returns of safer assets requires leverage, creating an opportunity for investors with the ability to apply leverage. Risk parity portfolios exploit this opportunity by equalizing the risk allocation across asset classes, thus overweighting safer assets relative to their weight in the market portfolio. How should investors allocate their assets? The standard advice provided by the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) is that all investors should hold the market portfolio, levered according to each investor s risk preference. In recent years, however, a new approach to asset allocation called risk parity (RP) has been gaining in popularity among practitioners (see Asness 2010; Sullivan 2010). In our study, we attempted to fill what we believe is a hole in the current arguments in favor of RP investing by adding a theoretical justification based on investors aversion to leverage and by providing broad empirical evidence across and within countries and asset classes. RP investing starts with the observation that traditional asset allocations, such as the market portfolio or the 60/40 portfolio of stocks/bonds, are not well diversified when viewed from the perspective of how each asset class contributes to the overall risk of the portfolio. Because stocks are so much more volatile than bonds, movement in the stock market dominates the risk in the market portfolio. Thus, when viewed from a risk perspective, the market portfolio is mainly an equity portfolio because nearly all the variation in performance is explained by the variation in equity markets. In that sense, the market portfolio and the 60/40 portfolio Clifford S. Asness is managing and founding principal at AQR Capital Management, LLC, Greenwich, Connecticut. Andrea Frazzini is vice president at AQR Capital Management, LLC, Greenwich, Connecticut. Lasse H. Pedersen is the John A. Paulson Professor of Finance and Alternative Investments at New York University Stern School of Business and a principal at AQR Capital Management, LLC, Greenwich, Connecticut. Editor s Note: The authors are affiliated with AQR Capital Management, LLC, which offers risk parity funds. offer little diversification even though they look well balanced when viewed from the perspective of dollars invested in each asset class. RP advocates suggest a simple cure: Diversify, but diversify by risk, not by dollars that is, take a similar amount of risk in equities and in bonds. To diversify by risk, we generally need to invest more money in low-risk assets than in high-risk assets. As a result, even if return per unit of risk is higher, the total aggressiveness and expected return are lower than those of a traditional 60/40 portfolio. RP investors address this problem by applying leverage to the risk-balanced portfolio to increase both its expected return and its risk to desired levels. 1 Although applying leverage introduces its own risks and practical concerns, we now have the best of both worlds: We are truly risk (not dollar) balanced across the asset classes, and importantly, we are taking enough risk to generate sufficient returns. The details can vary tremendously (e.g., real-life RP is about much more than U.S. stocks and bonds), but the idea of diversifying by risk is the essence of RP investing. To further bolster the case for RP investing beyond the mere notion that more diversification must be better advocates point to the evidence showing that RP portfolios have historically done better than traditional portfolios. Figure 1 depicts the growth of $1 since 1926 in the 60/40 portfolio, the market portfolio (that weights each asset class by its market capitalization), and a simple version of an RP portfolio. Although Figure 1 shows only one scenario, the historical outperformance of RP is quite robust. In sum, the popular case for RP investing rests on (1) the intuitive superiority of balancing risk rather than dollars invested and (2) the historical evidence for this approach over traditional approaches. Although these arguments are alluring, they are insufficient. The intuition that a risk-balanced January/February

2 Financial Analysts Journal Figure 1. The Risk Parity, Market, and 60/40 Portfolios: Cumulative Returns, Log (total return, US$) 10,000 Risk Parity Portfolio 1,000 60/40 Portfolio Value-Weighted Market Portfolio 1 0 Jan/26 Jan/38 Jan/50 Jan/62 Jan/74 Jan/86 Jan/98 Jan/10 Notes: This figure shows total cumulative returns (log scale) of portfolios of U.S. stocks and bonds in our long sample. The value-weighted portfolio is a market portfolio weighted by total market capitalization and is rebalanced monthly to maintain value weights. The 60/40 portfolio allocates 60 percent to stocks and 40 percent to bonds and is rebalanced monthly to maintain constant weights. The risk parity portfolio targets an equal risk allocation across the available instruments and is constructed as follows: At the end of each calendar month, we set the portfolio weight in each asset class equal to the inverse of its volatility, estimated by using three-year monthly excess returns up to month t 1, and these weights are multiplied by a constant to match the ex post realized volatility of the value-weighted benchmark. portfolio is always better than the market portfolio relies on an implicit assumption about expected returns. If the expected return of stocks versus bonds were high enough (i.e., given a sufficiently high equity risk premium), we would gladly invest in a portfolio whose risk is equity dominated. The intuition that investors who weight each asset class by its market capitalization take too much risk in equities is accurate only if the equity risk premium versus bonds is not high enough to support such a large risk allocation. The more specific intuition of equal risk is accurate only if all assets are expected to provide equal risk-adjusted returns. In other words, we cannot simply assert that equal risk is optimal because it is better diversified; to believe that, we must also believe we are not getting paid enough in equities to be so concentrated in them. We cannot think of RP as merely a statement about divvying up risks because it is inherently also a statement about our views on expected returns. Instead of saying that equal risk is always the best policy regardless of expected returns, an RP investor should say, We do not believe expected returns on equities are high enough to give them a disproportionate part of our risk budget. This important distinction is missing from the discussion of RP in the literature. According to the CAPM, the risk premiums are such that the market portfolio is optimal; thus, RP investors need to explain how the CAPM fails in a way that justifies a larger allocation to low-risk assets than their allocation in the market portfolio. As for the empirical evidence showing that RP portfolios have outperformed traditional portfolios over the long term, it is indeed useful and relevant but it is also only one draw from history (though admittedly a fairly long one). We must ask ourselves whether this evidence is enough to be conclusive. Does the insufficiently large equity risk premium versus bonds over the past 80 years mean that it would not be large enough in the future? Ideally, we would all prefer some out-of-sample evidence, but waiting another 80 years is an unappealing strategy CFA Institute

3 Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity Therefore, we propose another route to increase our confidence. The missing links are (1) a theoretical justification for RP investing and (2) broad tests across and within the major asset classes and countries. Frazzini and Pedersen (2010) found these links. Following Black (1972), they showed that if some investors are averse to leverage, lowbeta assets will offer higher risk-adjusted returns and high-beta assets will offer lower risk-adjusted returns. Hence, leverage aversion breaks the standard CAPM, and according to this theory, the highest risk-adjusted return is achieved not by the market but, rather, by a portfolio that overweights safer assets. Thus, an investor who is less leverage averse (or less leverage constrained) than the average investor can benefit by overweighting low-beta assets, underweighting high-beta assets, and applying some leverage to the resulting portfolio. Frazzini and Pedersen (2010) found consistent empirical evidence of this theory of leverage aversion within each major asset class. They found that low-beta stocks have higher risk-adjusted returns than high-beta stocks in the United States (echoing Black, Jensen, and Scholes 1972) and in global stock markets, safer corporate bonds have higher riskadjusted returns than do riskier bonds, safer shortmaturity U.S. Treasuries offer higher risk-adjusted returns than do riskier long-maturity ones, and so on within several other asset classes. 2 With respect to RP, bonds are the low-beta asset and stocks the high-beta asset, and the benefit of overweighting bonds that we documented is another empirical success of the theory. The theory of leverage aversion not only constitutes a theoretical underpinning for RP but also highlights how additional out-of-sample empirical evidence can be found by comparing the risk-adjusted returns of safer versus riskier securities within each of the major asset classes. Leverage and margin constraints can also explain deviations from the Law of One Price (Garleanu and Pedersen 2011), the effects of central banks lending facilities (Ashcraft, Garleanu, and Pedersen 2010), and general liquidity dynamics (Brunnermeier and Pedersen 2009). That the theory holds up in other applications (without notable exception) that are completely separate from the asset allocation decision that we studied bolsters our confidence that the empirical superiority of RP is not a statistical fluke but, rather, one more empirical confirmation of the leverage aversion theory to add to the many in Frazzini and Pedersen (2010). 3 A Theory of Leverage Aversion Before delving further into leverage aversion, let us revisit the standard predictions of the modern portfolio theory (MPT) of Markowitz (1952) and the CAPM of Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966). MPT considers how an investor should choose a portfolio with a good trade-off between risk and expected return. This concept is often illustrated by using a mean volatility diagram, as in Figure 2. To estimate risk and expected returns, we used data on realized returns for U.S. stocks and Treasuries over Figure 2 shows that the overall stock market had an average annual return of 10.8 percent, with a volatility of 18.9 percent, whereas the overall bond market provided a lower average annual return of 5.2 percent, with a lower volatility of 3.4 percent. The hyperbola connecting these two points represents all possible portfolios of stocks and bonds. For example, the 60/40 portfolio represents an investment of 60 percent of capital in stocks and 40 percent of capital in bonds; this portfolio is rebalanced every month to these weights. Figure 2 also shows that the risk-free T-bill rate averaged 3.6 percent a year over the period, represented by the point on the y-axis. Combining investments in the risk-free asset with investments in risky assets produces lines that connect the risk-free point with the hyperbola. The best such line for an investor who prefers higher returns and lower risk is the line from the risk-free point to the so-called tangency portfolio namely, the portfolio with the highest possible realized Sharpe ratio. In our data, the ex post tangency portfolio invests 88 percent in bonds and 12 percent in stocks. MPT says that an optimal portfolio is somewhere on this line: Riskaverse investors portfolios should be between the tangency portfolio and the risk-free asset, investing some money in cash and the rest in the tangency portfolio; risk-tolerant investors should be on the segment that extends beyond the tangency portfolio, which means that they should use leverage (i.e., borrow at the risk-free rate rather than invest at the risk-free rate) to invest more than 100 percent of their capital in the tangency portfolio. The CAPM goes beyond MPT by assuming that all investors invest in this way and concludes that the tangency portfolio must be equal to the market portfolio that is, the value-weighted portfolio of all assets. Figure 2 illustrates the historical risk and return of the market portfolio. We can see that the historical performance of the market portfolio is quite different from that of the tangency portfolio. The market portfolio has realized a significantly lower Sharpe ratio than the tangency portfolio for two reasons: (1) The market weights of stocks relative to bonds have varied over time in such a way that the risk return characteristics of the market are inside the hyperbola, and (2) the market portfolio allocates a much larger fraction of its capital to stocks than what has been optimal historically. The January/February

4 Financial Analysts Journal Figure 2. Efficient Frontier, Average Annual Return (%) Risk Parity Portfolio, Levered Stocks Tangency Portfolio Bonds Risk-Free Rate Risk Parity Portfolio, Unlevered 60/40 Portfolio Value-Weighted Market Portfolio Annual Standard Deviation (%) Notes: See notes to Figure 1. This figure shows the efficient frontier of portfolios of U.S. stocks and bonds in our long sample. The levered RP portfolio weights are multiplied by a constant to match the ex post realized volatility of the value-weighted benchmark. The unlevered RP portfolio weights are rescaled to sum to 1 at each rebalancing. average market weight over this sample ( ) was 68 percent in stocks and 32 percent in Treasury bonds, but we note that this long sample does not include other types of bonds, such as corporate bonds and mortgage bonds. As discussed later in the article, we found consistent evidence in a broader sample (with data starting in 1973) that includes all bonds as well as commodities. When all types of bonds are included, the current market portfolio consists of 42 percent stocks, 48 percent bonds (including credit), and 10 percent in commodities. Importantly, the empirical underperformance of the market portfolio relative to the tangency portfolio is robust and does not depend on the specific market weights. To see why, note that because stocks are so much riskier than bonds, stocks need to realize a much larger Sharpe ratio than bonds for the market portfolio to be optimal. But stocks have realized a lower Sharpe ratio than bonds, which makes any approximation of the market portfolio or the 60/40 portfolio underperform the tangency portfolio. That bonds have realized a higher Sharpe ratio and lower risk than stocks also explains why the tangency portfolio has such a large weight in bonds. Although these results are puzzling in light of the CAPM, we believe that they can be understood under a theory of leverage aversion. Consider an investor who would like a higher expected return than that of the tangency portfolio and is willing to accept the extra risk but is not willing (or allowed) to use any leverage. What portfolio will she choose? Preferring an unlevered portfolio with more stocks than the tangency portfolio, she may invest all her money in stocks. The presence of such investors changes the CAPM conclusions because they assume that everyone will invest on the line in the mean volatility diagram. Thus, the tangency portfolio is not equal to the market portfolio given the existence of leverage-averse investors. So, what exactly is the tangency portfolio? Although knowing what it is with certainty, at least ahead of time, is impossible (e.g., no one knew ex ante what the tangency portfolio in Figure 2 would turn out to be), a theory of equilibrium with leverage aversion can provide some guidance. Frazzini and Pedersen (2010) showed that the tangency portfolio overweights safer assets, as is the case empirically. This result is intuitive: Because some investors choose to overweight riskier assets in order to avoid leverage, the price of riskier assets is elevated or, equivalently, the expected return on riskier assets is reduced. In contrast, the safer assets CFA Institute

5 Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity are underweighted by these investors and thus trade at low prices (i.e., offer high expected returns). Hence, investors who are able and willing to apply leverage can earn higher risk-adjusted returns by effecting the opposite portfolio tilts namely, overweighting safer assets. In other words, leverage risk is rewarded in equilibrium through the relative pricing of securities, which is why the tangency portfolio includes a disproportionate amount of safer assets. The composition of the tangency portfolio depends on the number of leverage-constrained investors, which can change over time. Therefore, in practice, we cannot know for sure what the tangency portfolio will be ex ante. RP investing, however, offers a simple suggestion, which is in the direction suggested by the leverage aversion theory: RP investments allocate the same amount of risk to stocks and bonds. We can construct a simple RP portfolio as follows: At the end of each calendar month, we set the portfolio weight in each asset class equal to the inverse of its volatility (estimated by using threeyear monthly excess returns up to month t 1) and then multiply these weights by a constant to match the ex post realized volatility of the value-weighted benchmark. Note that this simple construction does not rely on covariance estimates. Over the full sample, our simple RP portfolio would invest, on average, 15 percent in stocks and 85 percent in bonds on an unlevered basis. The most recent RP allocations (as of June 2010) are 86 percent in bonds and 14 percent in stocks. Figure 2 shows that the historical performance of the RP portfolio is more similar to that of the tangency portfolio than to that of either the market portfolio or the 60/40 portfolio. Although not exactly ex post optimal, the RP portfolio has been a good approximation because overweighting safer assets has paid off. And even though we should not take too seriously the precise prescription to have exactly equal risk in stocks and bonds (parity), it is certainly a strong and accurate move in the right direction ex post. Frazzini and Pedersen (2010) laid out the leverage aversion theory more formally than we have done here, and they also presented several additional testable predictions. According to this theory, no one holds the market portfolio, but equilibrium is nevertheless achieved because some investors overweight safer assets whereas others overweight riskier assets. Both groups of investors are satisfied: Some accept low Sharpe ratios but earn high expected returns without leverage; others earn high expected returns with a better risk return trade-off by using leverage. Risk and Return across Asset Classes: Risk Parity vs. the Market vs. 60/40 To test our predicted implications of leverage aversion, we compared the historical performance of the value-weighted market portfolio, the RP portfolio, and the 60/40 stock/bond portfolio for three different data samples: Our long sample comprised U.S. stocks and bonds over ; our broad sample included global stocks, U.S. bonds, credit, and commodities over ; and our global sample consisted of stocks and bonds in the 11 countries covered by the J.P. Morgan Global Government Bond Index over Table 1 reports summary statistics, and Appendix A contains additional details on both the data and the portfolio construction. Table 2 shows the performance statistics for the long sample (Panel A) and the broad sample (Panel B). For each asset class, we used valueweighted return indices and then computed the overall market portfolio as the value-weighted average across asset classes. 4 In both samples, we can see that stocks have not only delivered higher average returns than bonds but also realized much higher volatility than bonds. As a result, the valueweighted market portfolio and the 60/40 portfolio have earned higher average returns than the unlevered RP portfolio. Therefore, an investor who cannot or will not use leverage may rationally prefer to hold the market portfolio, the 60/40 portfolio, or even all stocks despite all these portfolios having lower Sharpe ratios than RP. Again, such behavior can cause riskier assets to be overpriced relative to the standard CAPM. An investor who can use leverage, however, will prefer the historical performance of the RP portfolio because of its higher Sharpe ratio (riskadjusted return). Indeed, the levered RP portfolio has the same volatility as the market portfolio but a considerably higher average return. Figure 3 illustrates the significant improvement in the Sharpe ratio of the RP portfolio over that of the market and 60/40 portfolios. Note that the simulated performance of the levered RP portfolio does not reflect any adjustment of the returns for the costs of leverage, such as financing spreads and costs associated with deleveraging. At modest levels of leverage, any additional costs should be quite low; at high levels of leverage, the potential cost of forced deleveraging could be much more meaningful, especially for an investor with a large overall portfolio. Appendix B shows the robustness of our results with respect to various financing rates. January/February

6 Financial Analysts Journal Table 1. Summary Statistics Weight in Market Portfolio Asset Class Mean Most Recent Index Start Year End Year A. Long sample Stocks CRSP Value-Weighted Index Bonds CRSP Value-Weighted Index B. Broad sample Stocks CRSP Value-Weighted Index Bonds Barclays Capital U.S. Treasury Index Barclays Capital Other Government Bond Index Credit Barclays Capital U.S. Corporate Index Barclays Capital U.S. Securitized Index Barclays Capital U.S. Corporate High-Yield Index Barclays Capital Eurodollar Index Barclays Capital EM Index Barclays Capital 144A Index Barclays Capital CMBS Index Barclays Capital Emerged Bonds Index Commodities S&P GSCI C. Global sample Stocks MSCI Index Bonds J.P. Morgan Global Government Bond Index Notes: This table reports the list of instruments included in our three samples long, broad, and global and the corresponding date ranges. It also reports the average weight and the most recent (i.e., September 2010) weight in the market portfolio for each asset class. When we apply leverage by using futures, the return series is clearly implementable and no assumption of the financing cost is needed because futures returns, F t /F t 1 1, are already excess returns. 5 Our results with futures returns are similar to those with cash securities, providing further evidence of their robustness. The strong historical performance of RP is evident in the cumulative return plot in Figure 1, as discussed earlier. To test the significance of this outperformance, we calculated the t-statistics of the RP portfolio s realized alpha, which is the intercept in a time-series regression of monthly excess returns on the value-weighted benchmark (see Table 2). The t-statistics are much greater than 2, which implies strong statistical significance. To test further, we constructed long short portfolios that go long the RP portfolio and go short the market portfolio (or go short the 60/40 portfolio) for each sample. These long short portfolios have statistically significant excess returns and alphas for both our long sample and our broad sample. Although one might worry that the superiority of RP is an artifact of the bond bull market over the past years, a look at the longer period reveals a near-perfect round trip in bond yields and a near doubling of the equity market s valuation (using the 10-year P/Es of Robert Shiller). 6 Thus, if anything, was a period biased in favor of equities over bonds, and yet we see that risk parity has been a superior strategy. Complementing the evidence from both our long and our broad U.S. samples, Table 3 reports evidence from 10 other countries. For each country, we can see that the RP portfolio has provided higher risk-adjusted returns than the 60/40 portfolio. The outperformance of the RP portfolio is statistically significant when all countries are pooled into a (value-weighted) global portfolio, with or without the United States. Figure 4 shows the relative performance of the RP portfolio vis-à-vis that of the 60/40 portfolio in each country. A classic illustration of the empirical failure of the standard CAPM is the notion that the security market line is too flat, as first pointed out by Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972) for U.S. stocks. The security market line is the connection between the actual excess return across securities and the CAPMpredicted excess return, given by beta times the market excess return. Rather than looking at the security market line across stocks, we are interested in the security market line across asset classes. Figure 5 shows the security market line for the asset classes CFA Institute

7 Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity Table 2. Historical Performance of the Risk Parity, Market, and 60/40 Portfolios Excess Return t-stat. of Excess Return t-stat. of Alpha Sharpe Ratio Excess Kurtosis Alpha Volatility Skewness A. Long sample (U.S. stocks and bonds, ) CRSP stocks 6.71%* % CRSP bonds 1.56* Value-weighted portfolio 3.84* /40 portfolio 4.65* RP, unlevered 2.20* %* RP 7.99* * RP minus value-weighted 4.15* * RP minus 60/ * * B. Broad sample (global stocks, U.S. bonds, credit, and commodities, ) Stocks 5.96%* % Bonds 2.72* Credit 3.03* S&P GSCI Value-weighted portfolio 4.31* RP, unlevered 3.39* %* RP 6.15* * RP minus value-weighted * Notes: This table shows calendar-time portfolio returns. Value-weighted portfolio is a market portfolio weighted by total market capitalization and rebalanced monthly to maintain value weights. RP and RP, unlevered are portfolios that target equal risk allocation across the available instruments and are constructed as follows: At the end of each calendar month, we set the portfolio weight in each asset class equal to the inverse of its volatility, estimated by using three-year monthly excess returns up to month t 1. For the RP portfolio, these weights are multiplied by a constant to match the ex post realized volatility of the value-weighted benchmark. For the unlevered RP portfolio, the weights are rescaled to sum to 1 at each rebalancing. 60/40 portfolio allocates 60 percent to stocks and 40 percent to bonds and is rebalanced monthly to maintain constant weights. Panel A reports returns of stocks and bonds only. Panel B includes all the available asset classes. In computing the aggregate value-weighted portfolio, instruments are weighted by total market capitalization each month. Returns are in U.S. dollars, and excess returns are above the U.S. T-bill rate. Alpha is the intercept in a regression of monthly excess returns. The explanatory variables are the monthly returns of the value-weighted benchmark. Excess kurtosis is equal to the kurtosis of monthly excess returns minus 3. Returns, alphas, and volatilities are annual percentages. Sharpe ratios are annualized. *Significant at the 5 percent level. in our broad sample, in which betas are the slopes of a time-series regression of monthly excess returns on the value-weighted benchmark. The CAPM predicts that securities will line up on the 45-degree line that is, securities expected returns will line up with their systematic risk. Figure 5, however, shows that the empirical security market line is flatter because safer asset classes (bonds, credit, and commodities) provide returns that are too high relative to the CAPM, whereas riskier asset classes (domestic and international stocks) provide returns that are too low relative to their risk. Note that although commodities (as captured by the S&P GSCI) have high volatility, their systematic beta risk is significantly lower than that of the stock market owing to commodities low correlation with stocks. The flatness of the security market line underlies the power of buying safer assets; the security market line is also flat in other countries and over our long sample (Figures 1 and 4). Risk and Return within Asset Classes: High Beta Is Low Alpha Our finding that the security market line is too flat holds not only across asset classes but also within asset classes. In other words, with respect to different securities within the same asset class and across asset classes, safer assets have higher risk-adjusted returns than riskier assets. Indeed, Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972) famously found that the security market line is too flat across U.S. stocks. Adding 40 years of out-of-sample evidence, Frazzini and Pedersen (2010) confirmed this finding: The security market line has remained remarkably flat since the study by Black, Jensen, and Scholes. Moreover, Frazzini and Pedersen found that the security market line is also too flat in all the other major asset classes. It is too flat in global stock markets, in 18 of 19 developed equity markets, across U.S. Treasuries, across corporate bonds, and even across futures. January/February

8 Financial Analysts Journal Figure 3. The Risk Parity, Market, and 60/40 Portfolios: Sharpe Ratios Annual Sharpe Ratio Stocks and Bonds, Stocks and Bonds, Stocks, Bonds, Commodities, and Credit, Value-Weighted Portfolio 60/40 Portfolio Risk Parity Portfolio Notes: See notes to Figure 1. This figure shows annualized Sharpe ratios for portfolios of stocks, bonds, credit, and commodities in both our long and our broad samples. The figure plots Sharpe ratios of a value-weighted portfolio, a 60/40 portfolio, and a risk parity portfolio. Table 3. Risk Parity vs. 60/40: Global Evidence Average Excess Return Sharpe Ratio 60/40 RP RP 60/40 (pps) t-stat. 60/40 RP RP 60/40 A. Levered RP vs. 60/40 benchmark by country, Austria 3.63% 4.40% Belgium Canada France Germany Italy Japan * Netherlands Spain United Kingdom United States * B. Global portfolio, Global 2.26% 4.62% 2.35* Global ex U.S * pps = percentage points. Notes: See notes to Table 2. This table shows calendar-time returns of portfolios of stocks and bonds within countries. The equity index is the MSCI country index, and the country bond index is the corresponding J.P. Morgan Global Government Bond Index. The global portfolio weights each country by its equity market capitalization. *Significant at the 5 percent level CFA Institute

9 Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity Figure 4. Risk Parity vs. 60/40 in Global Sample: Sharpe Ratios, Annual Sharpe Ratio Austria Belgium Canada France Germany Italy Japan Netherlands Spain United Kingdom United States 60/40 Portfolio Risk Parity Portfolio Notes: This figure shows annualized Sharpe ratios for RP and 60/40 portfolios of stocks and bonds in 11 countries. For each country in this global sample, the equity index is the MSCI country index, and the country bond index is the corresponding J.P. Morgan Global Government Bond Index. The within-asset-class results are important to the inherently across-asset-class results of risk parity because they represent strong out-of-sample confirmation that what is going on for asset classes is ubiquitous and thus less likely to be an artifact of data mining. Conclusion: You Can Eat Risk- Adjusted Returns Risk parity investing has become a popular alternative to traditional methods of strategic asset allocation. Existing justifications, however, are insufficient and fail to provide a consistent equilibrium theory. Simply to desire diversification by risk, not dollars however intuitive is not enough. If you were paid enough in expected returns to be dominated in risk space by a single asset class, you would gladly do so. To show that you have not historically been paid enough to be so dominated (the equivalent of a backtest showing that RP is historically superior to traditional allocations) is also not enough. Although historical evidence is always welcome, even long histories of asset class returns can be dominated by a few large data points or arise from data mining. But RP investors need not despair. Even though there are no certainties in finance, perhaps the closest we can ever come is a realistic theory that holds up consistently in out-ofsample tests across and within different asset classes and countries. Pioneered by Black (1972, 1993) and extended by Frazzini and Pedersen (2010), leverage aversion is such a theory. Assuming that some market participants are unable or unwilling to use leverage is not unrealistic. Leverage simply presents a risk that investors want to be compensated for bearing. Further, to obtain and manage leverage requires the acquisition of a certain technology. Indeed, obtaining leverage requires getting financing, using derivatives, and establishing counterparty relations. Managing leverage requires, among other things, adjusting margin accounts and trading the portfolio dynamically over time. Our capital markets offer plenty of examples of investors that are not allowed (or choose not) to use leverage to increase their returns. For example, the majority of mutual funds and many pension funds are not allowed to borrow or are limited in the January/February

10 Financial Analysts Journal Figure 5. Security Market Line across Asset Classes, Average Annual Excess Return (%) 6 5 GSCI Empirical SML Stocks 4 3 Credit 2 Bonds 1 45-Degree Line (theoretical SML) Beta Average Market Excess Return (%) Notes: This figure shows the theoretical and empirical security market lines (SMLs) of portfolios of stocks, bonds, credit, and commodities in our broad sample. Average market excess return is the excess return of a market portfolio weighted by total capitalization and rebalanced monthly to maintain value weights. Beta is the slope of a regression of monthly excess returns on the market excess return. The empirical SML is the fitted value of a cross-sectional regression of average excess returns on realized betas. amount of leverage they can take. In addition, mutual fund families typically provide suggested asset allocations for low- to high-risk-tolerant investors. The high-risk recommendations rarely use leverage but, rather, suggest a very high concentration in equities. Similarly, the rise of embedded leverage in exchange-traded funds shows that some investors choose not to use leverage directly but prefer instruments with embedded leverage. To put the magnitude of investors modelimplied leverage aversion in perspective, we can estimate the opportunity cost of investing in the value-weighted market portfolio instead of in the RP portfolio. Over , the RP portfolio realized a Sharpe ratio that was 0.27 higher than that of the market portfolio, meaning that an investor with an average volatility of 10 percent invested in the value-weighted market portfolio underperformed the RP portfolio by 2.7 percent a year. Although this number may not make investors with high leverage costs or a strong aversion to leverage switch to RP, other investors can benefit from using leverage. The findings of Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972) and of Frazzini and Pedersen (2010) show that the predictions of a theory of leverage aversion hold up in a wide variety of tests across and within many asset classes. Our finding that RP investing is yet another instance of this theory working out of sample greatly enhances our confidence that risk parity s superiority to traditional methods of strategic asset allocation is real and important and not a figment of the data. We thank Antti Ilmanen, Ronen Israel, Sarah Jiang, John Liew, Mike Mendelson, and Larry Siegel for helpful comments and discussions. The views and opinions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views and opinions of AQR Capital Management, LLC, its affiliates, or its employees. The information set forth herein has been obtained or derived from sources believed by the authors to be reliable. However, the authors do not make any representation or warranty, express or implied, as to the information s accuracy or completeness, nor do the authors recommend that the attached information serve as the basis of any investment decision. This document has been provided to you solely for informational purposes and does not constitute an offer or solicitation of an offer, or any advice or recommendation, to purchase any securities or other financial instruments, and may not be construed as such. This article qualifies for 1 CE credit CFA Institute

11 Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity Appendix A. Data and Portfolio Construction We tested our theory in several complementary ways. We used three samples: Our long sample consisted of U.S. stocks and government bonds over January 1926 June 2010; our broad sample comprised global stocks, bonds, corporate bonds, and commodities over January 1973 June 2010; and our global sample included stocks and bonds in the 11 countries covered by the J.P. Morgan Global Government Bond Index series over January 1986 June We obtained the return and market-capitalization data for the long sample from the CRSP database. We used the CRSP Value-Weighted Index return (including dividends) as the aggregate stock return. Similarly, our aggregate bond return was the valueweighted average of the unadjusted holding period return for each bond in the CRSP Monthly US Treasury Database. We weighted bonds by their outstanding face value. To include data on various types of government bonds, credit-risky bonds, and commodities in our broad sample, we needed to focus on the more recent period of January 1973 June In our broad sample, bonds were the sum of the Barclays Capital U.S. Treasury Index and Other Government Bond Index series from Barclays Capital s Bond Hub database. For credit, we used the sum of all credit-related and securitized series in the Barclays Capital Universal Index. The individual series are listed in Table 1. Finally, we used the S&P GSCI 7 as a benchmark for investment in commodity markets, which we obtained from Bloomberg. As a proxy for commodities total market capitalization, we used the annual total dollar value of commodity production, which we obtained from Merrill Lynch. 8 Because our commodity production data start in 1989, we used the 1989 weight over All returns and market-capitalization series are in U.S. dollars, and excess returns are above the U.S. Treasury bill rate. Our global sample consisted of stocks and bonds. Our global stock market proxy was the MSCI World indices provided by MSCI. 10 For bonds, we used the J.P. Morgan Global Government Bond Index series from Thomson Reuters Datastream. The global sample covered January 1986 June Constructing RP Portfolios We constructed simple RP portfolios that are rebalanced monthly so as to target an equal risk allocation across the available asset classes. To construct an RP portfolio, at the end of each calendar month, we estimated volatilities i of all the available asset classes (using data up to month t 1) and set the portfolio weight in asset class i to wti, kt 1 ti,, where i = 1,..., n. We estimated ti, as the threeyear rolling volatility of monthly excess returns, but we obtained similar results for other volatility estimates. The variable k t is the same for all assets and controls the amount of leverage (or the target volatility) of the RP portfolio. We considered two very simple RP portfolios (i.e., two choices for k t ): The first portfolio is an unlevered RP portfolio, obtained by setting 1 k t, 1 ti, i which corresponds to a simple value-weighted portfolio that overweights less volatile assets and underweights more volatile assets. The second portfolio is a levered RP portfolio obtained by keeping k t constant over time: kt k for all periods. Of course, because k is constant across periods, the exact level of k does not affect statistical inference. For comparison purposes, we set k such that the annualized volatility of this portfolio matches the ex post realized volatility of the benchmark (the value-weighted market portfolio or the 60/40 portfolio). This portfolio corresponds to a portfolio that targets a constant volatility in each asset class, levered up to match the volatility of the benchmark. (We obtained similar results by choosing k t to match the conditional volatility of the benchmark at the time of portfolio formation.) The portfolios are rebalanced every calendar month, and the monthly excess return over T-bills is given by rt RP wt 1, i rti, rft, i where r is the U.S.-dollar gross return in month t and rf is the one-month Treasury bill rate. Table 1 reports the list of instruments. Appendix B. Robustness and Financing Costs Our results on RP investment are robust. We calculated performance by using a long, a broad, and a global dataset, and we checked that our main conclusions are robust to slight modifications to our portfolio construction methodology (not reported here). January/February

12 Financial Analysts Journal As a further robustness check, this appendix reports performance on the basis of which interest rate is used as the risk-free rate. Whereas our main analysis follows the literature by using the T-bill rate, Table B1 also considers the repo, OIS, and federal funds rates, as well as LIBOR. Given that the RP portfolio is levered, its performance is reduced when the risk-free rate is higher. Nevertheless, the RP portfolio outperforms the market portfolio even with the most conservative LIBOR, as seen in the table. Note that leverage can be achieved by using futures contracts at an implicit cost that is lower than LIBOR. Financing costs and the ability to manage leverage over time may differ among investors. Indeed, some investors may display greater leverage aversion because they face greater financing costs and/or have less ability to manage leverage over time. Table B1. Robustness Check: RP Portfolio minus Value-Weighted Market Portfolio (Alternative Risk-Free Rates) Spread over T-Bills (bps) Excess Return t-stat. of Excess Return t-stat. of Alpha Volatility Sharpe Ratio Skewness Excess Kurtosis Alpha A. Long sample, (RP value-weighted) T-bills %* %* % Repo * * OIS * * Fed funds * LIBOR * B. Broad sample, (RP value-weighted) T-bills % %* % Repo * OIS * Fed funds * LIBOR Notes: See notes to Table 2. This table shows calendar-time portfolio returns of an RP portfolio minus the returns of a value-weighted portfolio. We report returns using different risk-free rates sorted by their average spread over one-month Treasury bills. Repo is the overnight repo rate. OIS is the overnight indexed swap rate. Fed funds is the effective federal funds rate. LIBOR is the one-month London Interbank Offered Rate. If the interest rate was unavailable over a date range, we used the one-month T-bill rate plus the average spread over the entire sample period. *Significant at the 5 percent level. Notes 1. Asness (1996) explored the role of leverage in the simpler case of levering the 60/40 portfolio versus the 100 percent equity portfolio. 2. This evidence complements the extensive literature that has empirically documented violations of the CAPM (see Fama and French 1992; Gibbons 1982; Kandel 1984; Karceski 2002; Shanken 1985). Given the strong assumptions that underlie the CAPM, perhaps we should not be surprised that it is rejected empirically. Indeed, the CAPM assumes that markets are without any frictions and that all investors can use any amount of leverage. According to the CAPM, everyone holds the market portfolio (possibly levered), which is clearly not the case in the real world. That these violations tend to go the same way, however returns on low-beta assets that are higher than forecasted is very interesting. 3. Naturally, other hypotheses can explain the higher riskadjusted returns of safer versus riskier assets. The alternatives include models of delegated portfolio management with benchmarked institutional investors (Brennan 1993; Baker, Bradley, and Wurgler 2011), mutual fund managers incentive to overweight high-beta stocks owing to the optionlike payoffs generated by the convexity of the flow performance relation (Falkenstein 1994; Karceski 2002), and money illusion (Cohen, Polk, and Vuolteenaho 2005). Our findings are also related to the low return to stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility (Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang 2006), although their finding applies only to the recent volatility of illiquid securities (Li and Sullivan 2010) whereas the beta effect is more robust (Frazzini and Pedersen 2010). Each of these alternatives delivers predictions that apply to a specific setting (e.g., the universe of active equity mutual fund managers) and can thus explain some, but not all, of the evidence within and across each of the major asset classes. Of course, they can also complement our unified leverage aversion theory. 4. We note that the average duration of the value-weighted U.S. Treasury bond index over our long sample is 5.6 years. Consistent with the theory of leverage aversion, CFA Institute

13 Leverage Aversion and Risk Parity longer-term Treasuries have realized lower Sharpe ratios than have shorter-term ones, and so our results would be stronger with shorter-term bonds and weaker with longerterm bonds. The value-weighted average of Treasury bonds is the natural benchmark, just as we use the valueweighted average of stocks (e.g., rather than using only high-beta stocks). 5. The difference between computing the return of a leveraged cash instrument and that of a futures instrument is as follows: The return of an x-times leveraged cash instrument is xr (x 1)rf PB, where r is the cash return and rf PB is the rate at which you borrow from your prime broker (PB). Hence, the excess return over the risk-free rate, rf, is given by xr (x 1)rf PB rf = x(r rf) (x 1)(rf PB rf), where the last term is the financing spread the difference between the PB rate and the risk-free money market rate. The excess return of an x-times leveraged futures instrument is computed as x(f t /F t 1 1), where F is the futures price. The point is that this return is already an excess return that is, a return on a self-financing position. In other words, the futures price embeds the financing rate, which allows a simple calculation of an implementable leveraged excess return. (A possible margin with the Futures Commission Merchant can be posted as T-bills earning the riskfree rate, which does not change the calculation.) 6. The data can be downloaded at ~shiller/data.htm. 7. Formerly, the Goldman Sachs Commodity Index. 8. We thank Merrill Lynch Commodities for making these data available to us. 9. Our results are robust to dropping commodities over , a period for which we did not have total dollar production data. 10. The data can be downloaded at References Ang, Andrew, Robert J. Hodrick, Yuhang Xing, and Xiaoyan Zhang The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns. Journal of Finance, vol. 61, no. 1 (February): Ashcraft, Adam, Nicolae Garleanu, and Lasse Heje Pedersen Two Monetary Tools: Interest Rates and Haircuts. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 25, no. 1 (May): Asness, Clifford S Why Not 100 Percent Equities. Journal of Portfolio Management, vol. 22, no. 2 (Winter): Speculative Leverage: A False Cure for Pension Woes : A Comment. Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 66, no. 5 (September/October): Baker, Malcolm, Brendan Bradley, and Jeffrey Wurgler Benchmarks as Limits to Arbitrage: Understanding the Low- Volatility Anomaly. Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 67, no. 1 (January/February): Black, Fischer Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing. Journal of Business, vol. 45, no. 3 (July): Beta and Return. Journal of Portfolio Management, vol. 20, no. 1 (Fall):8 18. Black, Fischer, Michael C. Jensen, and Myron S. Scholes The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Some Empirical Tests. In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets. Edited by Michael C. Jensen. New York: Praeger. Brennan, Michael J Agency and Asset Pricing. Working paper, University of California, Los Angeles. Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Lasse Heje Pedersen Market Liquidity and Funding Liquidity. Review of Financial Studies, vol. 22, no. 6 (June): Cohen, Randolph B., Christopher Polk, and Tuomo Vuolteenaho Money Illusion in the Stock Market: The Modigliani-Cohn Hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 120, no. 2 (May): Falkenstein, Eric G Mutual Funds, Idiosyncratic Variance, and Asset Returns. Dissertation, Northwestern University. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French The Cross- Section of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Finance, vol. 47, no. 2 (June): Frazzini, Andrea, and Lasse Heje Pedersen Betting Against Beta. NBER Working Paper (December). Garleanu, Nicolae, and Lasse Heje Pedersen Margin- Based Asset Pricing and Deviations from the Law of One Price. Review of Financial Studies, vol. 24, no. 6: Gibbons, Michael R Multivariate Tests of Financial Models: A New Approach. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 10, no. 1 (March):3 27. Kandel, Shmuel The Likelihood Ratio Test Statistic of Mean Variance Efficiency without a Riskless Asset. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 13, no. 4 (December): Karceski, Jason J Returns-Chasing Behavior, Mutual Funds, and Beta s Death. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, vol. 37, no. 4 (December): Li, Xi, and Rodney N. Sullivan The Limits to Arbitrage Revisited: The Low-Risk Anomaly. Working paper, Boston College. Lintner, John The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 47, no. 1 (February): Markowitz, Harry Portfolio Selection. Journal of Finance, vol. 7, no. 1 (March): Mossin, Jan Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market. Econometrica, vol. 34, no. 4 (October): Shanken, Jay Multivariate Tests of the Zero-Beta CAPM. Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 14, no. 3 (September): Sharpe, William F Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk. Journal of Finance, vol. 19, no. 3 (September): Sullivan, Rodney N Speculative Leverage: A False Cure for Pension Woes. Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 66, no. 3 (May/June):6 8. January/February

14 Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation Appendix B. Additional empirical results and robustness tests This Appendix contains additional empirical results and robustness tests. B.1. Sharpe ratios of beta-sorted portfolios Fig. B1 plots the Sharpe

More information

Betting Against Beta

Betting Against Beta Betting Against Beta Andrea Frazzini AQR Capital Management LLC Lasse H. Pedersen NYU, CEPR, and NBER Preliminary Copyright 2010 by Andrea Frazzini and Lasse H. Pedersen Motivation Background: Security

More information

Rethinking Fixed Income

Rethinking Fixed Income Rethinking Fixed Income Challenging Conventional Wisdom May 2013 Risk. Reinsurance. Human Resources. Rethinking Fixed Income: Challenging Conventional Wisdom With US Treasury interest rates at, or near,

More information

Benchmarking Low-Volatility Strategies

Benchmarking Low-Volatility Strategies Benchmarking Low-Volatility Strategies David Blitz* Head Quantitative Equity Research Robeco Asset Management Pim van Vliet, PhD** Portfolio Manager Quantitative Equity Robeco Asset Management forthcoming

More information

Journal of Exclusive Management Science May 2015 -Vol 4 Issue 5 - ISSN 2277 5684

Journal of Exclusive Management Science May 2015 -Vol 4 Issue 5 - ISSN 2277 5684 Journal of Exclusive Management Science May 2015 Vol 4 Issue 5 ISSN 2277 5684 A Study on the Emprical Testing Of Capital Asset Pricing Model on Selected Energy Sector Companies Listed In NSE Abstract *S.A.

More information

ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT

ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT T H 1RD CANADIAN EDITION W. SEAN CLEARY Queen's University CHARLES P. JONES North Carolina State University JOHN WILEY & SONS CANADA, LTD. CONTENTS PART ONE Background CHAPTER 1

More information

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Model a logical extension of portfolio selection theory is to consider the equilibrium asset pricing consequences of investors individually

More information

The problems of being passive

The problems of being passive The problems of being passive Evaluating the merits of an index investment strategy In the investment management industry, indexing has received little attention from investors compared with active management.

More information

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6 PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT A. INTRODUCTION RETURN AS A RANDOM VARIABLE E(R) = the return around which the probability distribution is centered: the expected value or mean of the probability distribution of possible

More information

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Prof. Alex Shapiro Lecture Notes 9 The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems II. III. IV. Introduction: from Assumptions to Implications The Market Portfolio Assumptions

More information

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns.

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory. 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. Chapter 5 Conditional CAPM 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory 5.1.1 Risk According to the CAPM The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns. In the 40+ years of its history, many systematic deviations

More information

What Level of Incentive Fees Are Hedge Fund Investors Actually Paying?

What Level of Incentive Fees Are Hedge Fund Investors Actually Paying? What Level of Incentive Fees Are Hedge Fund Investors Actually Paying? Abstract Long-only investors remove the effects of beta when analyzing performance. Why shouldn t long/short equity hedge fund investors

More information

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Jesse Väisänen EMBEDDED LEVERAGE AND PERFORMANCE OF HEDGE FUND SHARE CLASSES

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Jesse Väisänen EMBEDDED LEVERAGE AND PERFORMANCE OF HEDGE FUND SHARE CLASSES OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL Jesse Väisänen EMBEDDED LEVERAGE AND PERFORMANCE OF HEDGE FUND SHARE CLASSES Master s Thesis Department of Finance August 2013 UNIVERSITY OF OULU Oulu Business School Unit Department

More information

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio 1 2 Identifying the Tangent Portfolio Sharpe Ratio: Measures the ratio of reward-to-volatility provided by a portfolio Sharpe Ratio Portfolio Excess Return E[ RP ] r

More information

THE GREAT RISK/RETURN INVERSION - WHO LOSES OUT?

THE GREAT RISK/RETURN INVERSION - WHO LOSES OUT? THE GREAT RISK/RETURN INVERSION - WHO LOSES OUT? ANDREA BUFFA DIMITRI VAYANOS PAUL WOOLLEY LSE, SEPTEMBER 2014 Risk and return go hand in hand as companion variables central to the teaching and practice

More information

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*:

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*: Problem 1. Consider a risky asset. Suppose the expected rate of return on the risky asset is 15%, the standard deviation of the asset return is 22%, and the risk-free rate is 6%. What is your optimal position

More information

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully Review for Exam Instructions: Please read carefully The exam will have 1 multiple choice questions and 5 work problems. Questions in the multiple choice section will be either concept or calculation questions.

More information

Emini Education - Managing Volatility in Equity Portfolios

Emini Education - Managing Volatility in Equity Portfolios PH&N Trustee Education Seminar 2012 Managing Volatility in Equity Portfolios Why Equities? Equities Offer: Participation in global economic growth Superior historical long-term returns compared to other

More information

Low Volatility Equity Strategies: New and improved?

Low Volatility Equity Strategies: New and improved? Low Volatility Equity Strategies: New and improved? Jean Masson, Ph.D Managing Director, TD Asset Management January 2014 Low volatility equity strategies have been available to Canadian investors for

More information

Low-Risk Investing Without Industry Bets

Low-Risk Investing Without Industry Bets Low-Risk Investing Without Industry Bets Cliff Asness, Andrea Frazzini, and Lasse H. Pedersen * First Draft: June 6, 2012 This draft: March 20, 2013 Abstract The strategy of buying safe low-beta stocks

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

The Low Beta Anomaly: A Decomposition into Micro and Macro Effects. Malcolm Baker * Brendan Bradley Ryan Taliaferro. September 13, 2013.

The Low Beta Anomaly: A Decomposition into Micro and Macro Effects. Malcolm Baker * Brendan Bradley Ryan Taliaferro. September 13, 2013. The Low Beta Anomaly: A Decomposition into Micro and Macro Effects Malcolm Baker * Brendan Bradley Ryan Taliaferro September 13, 2013 Abstract Low beta stocks have offered a combination of low risk and

More information

Answers to Concepts in Review

Answers to Concepts in Review Answers to Concepts in Review 1. A portfolio is simply a collection of investments assembled to meet a common investment goal. An efficient portfolio is a portfolio offering the highest expected return

More information

Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA

Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA This article appears in the January/February 1998 issue of Valuation Strategies. Executive Summary This article explores one

More information

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study But I will offer a review, with a focus on issues which arise in finance 1 TYPES OF FINANCIAL

More information

THE LOW-VOLATILITY ANOMALY: Does It Work In Practice?

THE LOW-VOLATILITY ANOMALY: Does It Work In Practice? THE LOW-VOLATILITY ANOMALY: Does It Work In Practice? Glenn Tanner McCoy College of Business, Texas State University, San Marcos TX 78666 E-mail: tanner@txstate.edu ABSTRACT This paper serves as both an

More information

The Equity Premium in India

The Equity Premium in India The Equity Premium in India Rajnish Mehra University of California, Santa Barbara and National Bureau of Economic Research January 06 Prepared for the Oxford Companion to Economics in India edited by Kaushik

More information

Evolution of GTAA Investment Styles. In This Issue: June 2012

Evolution of GTAA Investment Styles. In This Issue: June 2012 June 2012 ALPHA GROUP TOPIC The Alpha Group researches investment managers. In This Issue: n Evolution of GTAA Investment Styles n Risk-Parity vs. GTAA Managers n Implementation n Investing in a GTAA Strategy

More information

Investment Insight Diversified Factor Premia Edward Qian PhD, CFA, Bryan Belton, CFA, and Kun Yang PhD, CFA PanAgora Asset Management August 2013

Investment Insight Diversified Factor Premia Edward Qian PhD, CFA, Bryan Belton, CFA, and Kun Yang PhD, CFA PanAgora Asset Management August 2013 Investment Insight Diversified Factor Premia Edward Qian PhD, CFA, Bryan Belton, CFA, and Kun Yang PhD, CFA PanAgora Asset Management August 2013 Modern Portfolio Theory suggests that an investor s return

More information

Risk and return in Þxed income arbitrage: Nickels in front of a steamroller?

Risk and return in Þxed income arbitrage: Nickels in front of a steamroller? Risk and return in Þxed income arbitrage Université d Evry June 2005 1 Risk and return in Þxed income arbitrage: Nickels in front of a steamroller? Jefferson Duarte University of Washington Francis Longstaff

More information

Portfolio Performance Measures

Portfolio Performance Measures Portfolio Performance Measures Objective: Evaluation of active portfolio management. A performance measure is useful, for example, in ranking the performance of mutual funds. Active portfolio managers

More information

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully Review for Exam 2 Instructions: Please read carefully The exam will have 25 multiple choice questions and 5 work problems You are not responsible for any topics that are not covered in the lecture note

More information

The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule

The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) Massachusetts Institute of Technology CAPM Slide 1 of NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule Discussed NPV and time value of money Choice of discount rate influences

More information

New Frontiers In Index Investing

New Frontiers In Index Investing New Frontiers In Index Investing An examination of fundamental indexation by Jason C. Hsu and Carmen Campollo Illustration by Jonathan Evans 32 January/February 2006 Indexing is a powerful model for equity

More information

How Many Days Equal A Year? Non-trivial on the Mean-Variance Model

How Many Days Equal A Year? Non-trivial on the Mean-Variance Model How Many Days Equal A Year? Non-trivial on the Mean-Variance Model George L. Ye, Dr. Sobey School of Business Saint Mary s University Halifax, Nova Scotia, Canada Christine Panasian, Dr. Sobey School of

More information

Single Manager vs. Multi-Manager Alternative Investment Funds

Single Manager vs. Multi-Manager Alternative Investment Funds September 2015 Single Manager vs. Multi-Manager Alternative Investment Funds John Dolfin, CFA Chief Investment Officer Steben & Company, Inc. Christopher Maxey, CAIA Senior Portfolio Manager Steben & Company,

More information

Models of Risk and Return

Models of Risk and Return Models of Risk and Return Aswath Damodaran Aswath Damodaran 1 First Principles Invest in projects that yield a return greater than the minimum acceptable hurdle rate. The hurdle rate should be higher for

More information

An Attractive Income Option for a Strategic Allocation

An Attractive Income Option for a Strategic Allocation An Attractive Income Option for a Strategic Allocation Voya Senior Loans Suite A strategic allocation provides potential for high and relatively steady income through most credit and rate cycles Improves

More information

Defensive equity. A defensive strategy to Canadian equity investing

Defensive equity. A defensive strategy to Canadian equity investing Defensive equity A defensive strategy to Canadian equity investing Adam Hornung, MBA, CFA, Institutional Investment Strategist EXECUTIVE SUMMARY: Over the last several years, academic studies have shown

More information

Porter, White & Company

Porter, White & Company Porter, White & Company Optimizing the Fixed Income Component of a Portfolio White Paper, September 2009, Number IM 17.2 In the White Paper, Comparison of Fixed Income Fund Performance, we show that a

More information

Chapter 11, Risk and Return

Chapter 11, Risk and Return Chapter 11, Risk and Return 1. A portfolio is. A) a group of assets, such as stocks and bonds, held as a collective unit by an investor B) the expected return on a risky asset C) the expected return on

More information

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, 2011. A. Huang

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, 2011. A. Huang AFM 472 Midterm Examination Monday Oct. 24, 2011 A. Huang Name: Answer Key Student Number: Section (circle one): 10:00am 1:00pm 2:30pm Instructions: 1. Answer all questions in the space provided. If space

More information

The Risk-Free Rate s Impact on Stock Returns with Representative Fund Managers

The Risk-Free Rate s Impact on Stock Returns with Representative Fund Managers School of Economics and Management Department of Business Administration FEKN90 Business Administration- Degree Project Master of Science in Business and Economics Spring term of 2013 The Risk-Free Rate

More information

EVALUATING THE PERFORMANCE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE CBOE S&P 500 PUTWRITE INDEX

EVALUATING THE PERFORMANCE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE CBOE S&P 500 PUTWRITE INDEX DECEMBER 2008 Independent advice for the institutional investor EVALUATING THE PERFORMANCE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE CBOE S&P 500 PUTWRITE INDEX EXECUTIVE SUMMARY The CBOE S&P 500 PutWrite Index (ticker symbol

More information

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1,

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1, XVII. SECURITY PRICING AND SECURITY ANALYSIS IN AN EFFICIENT MARKET Consider the following somewhat simplified description of a typical analyst-investor's actions in making an investment decision. First,

More information

NorthCoast Investment Advisory Team 203.532.7000 info@northcoastam.com

NorthCoast Investment Advisory Team 203.532.7000 info@northcoastam.com NorthCoast Investment Advisory Team 203.532.7000 info@northcoastam.com NORTHCOAST ASSET MANAGEMENT An established leader in the field of tactical investment management, specializing in quantitative research

More information

Disentangling value, growth, and the equity risk premium

Disentangling value, growth, and the equity risk premium Disentangling value, growth, and the equity risk premium The discounted cash flow (DCF) model is a theoretically sound method to value stocks. However, any model is only as good as the inputs and, as JASON

More information

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING Evidence for the London Stock Exchange Timo Hubers (358022) Bachelor thesis Bachelor Bedrijfseconomie Tilburg University May 2012 Supervisor: M. Nie MSc Table of Contents Chapter

More information

The active/passive decision in global bond funds

The active/passive decision in global bond funds The active/passive decision in global bond funds Vanguard research November 213 Executive summary. This paper extends the evaluation of active versus passive management to global bond funds. Previous Vanguard

More information

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices ANDREA M. BUFFA DIMITRI VAYANOS PAUL WOOLLEY Boston University London School of Economics London School of Economics September, 2013 Abstract We study

More information

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36)

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36) Readings Chapters 9 and 10 Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock 1. The investor s expected return 2. Valuation as the Present Value (PV) of dividends and the growth of dividends 3. The investor s required

More information

Interest Rates and Inflation: How They Might Affect Managed Futures

Interest Rates and Inflation: How They Might Affect Managed Futures Faced with the prospect of potential declines in both bonds and equities, an allocation to managed futures may serve as an appealing diversifier to traditional strategies. HIGHLIGHTS Managed Futures have

More information

Total-Return Investment Pool (TRIP) Asset Allocation & Investment Policy Review and Recommendations

Total-Return Investment Pool (TRIP) Asset Allocation & Investment Policy Review and Recommendations ATTACHMENT 2 Total-Return Investment Pool (TRIP) Asset Allocation & Investment Policy Review and Recommendations May 27, 2015 Office of the Chief Investment Officer Contents For Discussion at Committee

More information

11.3% -1.5% Year-to-Date 1-Year 3-Year 5-Year Since WT Index Inception

11.3% -1.5% Year-to-Date 1-Year 3-Year 5-Year Since WT Index Inception WisdomTree ETFs WISDOMTREE HIGH DIVIDEND FUND DHS Nearly 10 years ago, WisdomTree launched its first dividend-focused strategies based on our extensive research regarding the importance of focusing on

More information

Risk and Return Models: Equity and Debt. Aswath Damodaran 1

Risk and Return Models: Equity and Debt. Aswath Damodaran 1 Risk and Return Models: Equity and Debt Aswath Damodaran 1 First Principles Invest in projects that yield a return greater than the minimum acceptable hurdle rate. The hurdle rate should be higher for

More information

TOTAL RETURN INVESTMENT POOL (TRIP) INVESTMENT POLICY

TOTAL RETURN INVESTMENT POOL (TRIP) INVESTMENT POLICY Effective: July 23, 2015 Replaces version effective: August 1, 2013 TOTAL RETURN INVESTMENT POOL (TRIP) INVESTMENT POLICY The purpose for this investment policy ( Policy ) is to clearly state the investment

More information

RISK PARITY ABSTRACT OVERVIEW

RISK PARITY ABSTRACT OVERVIEW MEKETA INVESTMENT GROUP RISK PARITY ABSTRACT Several large plans, including the San Diego County Employees Retirement Association and the State of Wisconsin, have recently considered or decided to pursue

More information

Fixed-income opportunity: Short duration high yield

Fixed-income opportunity: Short duration high yield March 2014 Insights from: An income solution for a low or rising interest-rate environment Generating income is a key objective for many investors, and one that is increasingly difficult to achieve in

More information

The Evolution of Investing

The Evolution of Investing Bringing the Best of Academic Research to Real-World Investment Strategies The Science of Investing from the Halls of Academia An enormous Industry has developed over the years that s very familiar to

More information

Performance Evaluation on Mutual Funds

Performance Evaluation on Mutual Funds Performance Evaluation on Mutual Funds Dr.G.Brindha Associate Professor, Bharath School of Business, Bharath University, Chennai 600073, India Abstract: Mutual fund investment has lot of changes in the

More information

SYSTEMATIC DIVERSIFICATION USING BETA

SYSTEMATIC DIVERSIFICATION USING BETA August 2015 Paul Bouchey Parametric CIO Vassilii Nemtchinov Director of Research - Equity Strategies Tianchuan Li Quantitative Analyst SYSTEMATIC DIVERSIFICATION USING BETA Beta is a measure of risk representing

More information

Daily vs. monthly rebalanced leveraged funds

Daily vs. monthly rebalanced leveraged funds Daily vs. monthly rebalanced leveraged funds William Trainor Jr. East Tennessee State University ABSTRACT Leveraged funds have become increasingly popular over the last 5 years. In the ETF market, there

More information

Glossary of Investment Terms

Glossary of Investment Terms online report consulting group Glossary of Investment Terms glossary of terms actively managed investment Relies on the expertise of a portfolio manager to choose the investment s holdings in an attempt

More information

15.401 Finance Theory

15.401 Finance Theory Finance Theory MIT Sloan MBA Program Andrew W. Lo Harris & Harris Group Professor, MIT Sloan School Lecture 13 14 14: : Risk Analytics and Critical Concepts Motivation Measuring Risk and Reward Mean-Variance

More information

Tilted Portfolios, Hedge Funds, and Portable Alpha

Tilted Portfolios, Hedge Funds, and Portable Alpha MAY 2006 Tilted Portfolios, Hedge Funds, and Portable Alpha EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH Many of Dimensional Fund Advisors clients tilt their portfolios toward small and value stocks. Relative

More information

A Test Of The M&M Capital Structure Theories Richard H. Fosberg, William Paterson University, USA

A Test Of The M&M Capital Structure Theories Richard H. Fosberg, William Paterson University, USA A Test Of The M&M Capital Structure Theories Richard H. Fosberg, William Paterson University, USA ABSTRACT Modigliani and Miller (1958, 1963) predict two very specific relationships between firm value

More information

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM)

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM) CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM) Answers to Concepts Review and Critical Thinking Questions 1. Some of the risk in holding any asset is unique to the asset in question.

More information

Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 5-1 a. Stand-alone risk is only a part of total risk and pertains to the risk an investor takes by holding only one asset. Risk is

More information

THE LOW-VOLATILITY EFFECT: A COMPREHENSIVE LOOK

THE LOW-VOLATILITY EFFECT: A COMPREHENSIVE LOOK THE LOW-VOLATILITY EFFECT: A COMPREHENSIVE LOOK AUGUST 2012 CONTRIBUTORS Aye M. Soe, CFA Director Index Research & Design aye.soe@spdji.com 1: INTRODUCTION Among the long-standing anomalies in modern investment

More information

Most investors would agree that

Most investors would agree that Portfolio Risk Consequences of Fixed-Income Exposures GEOFF WARREN The Journal of Portfolio Management 2009.35.4:52-59. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by Ricky Husaini on 09/26/09. GEOFF WARREN is

More information

RISK MANAGEMENT TOOLS

RISK MANAGEMENT TOOLS RISK MANAGEMENT TOOLS Pavilion Advisory Group TM Pavilion Advisory Group is a trademark of Pavilion Financial Corporation used under license by Pavilion Advisory Group Ltd. in Canada and Pavilion Advisory

More information

Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary. 12 April 2016

Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary. 12 April 2016 Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary 12 April 2016 Introduction welcome If you are reading this, it is likely that you are in regular contact with KPMG on the topic of valuations. The goal of this

More information

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MSCI EMERGING MARKETS INDEX, mini MSCI EMERGING MARKETS INDEX FUTURES AND THE ishares MSCI EMERGING MARKETS ETF

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MSCI EMERGING MARKETS INDEX, mini MSCI EMERGING MARKETS INDEX FUTURES AND THE ishares MSCI EMERGING MARKETS ETF WHITE PAPER THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MSCI EMERGING MARKETS INDEX, mini MSCI EMERGING MARKETS INDEX FUTURES AND THE ishares MSCI EMERGING MARKETS ETF Sponsored by Table of Contents Executive Summary 1 What

More information

ON THE RISK ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE FOR DETERMINING LIFE OFFICE APPRAISAL VALUES BY M. SHERRIS B.A., M.B.A., F.I.A., F.I.A.A. 1.

ON THE RISK ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE FOR DETERMINING LIFE OFFICE APPRAISAL VALUES BY M. SHERRIS B.A., M.B.A., F.I.A., F.I.A.A. 1. ON THE RISK ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE FOR DETERMINING LIFE OFFICE APPRAISAL VALUES BY M. SHERRIS B.A., M.B.A., F.I.A., F.I.A.A. 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1 A number of papers have been written in recent years that

More information

Introduction, Forwards and Futures

Introduction, Forwards and Futures Introduction, Forwards and Futures Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Fall, 2007 (Hull chapters: 1,2,3,5) Liuren Wu Introduction, Forwards & Futures Option Pricing, Fall, 2007 1 / 35

More information

Best Styles: Harvesting Risk Premium in Equity Investing

Best Styles: Harvesting Risk Premium in Equity Investing Strategy Best Styles: Harvesting Risk Premium in Equity Investing Harvesting risk premiums is a common investment strategy in fixed income or foreign exchange investing. In equity investing it is still

More information

Estimating the Market Risk Premium for Australia using a Benchmark Approach

Estimating the Market Risk Premium for Australia using a Benchmark Approach Appendix B Estimating the Market Risk Premium for Australia using a Benchmark Approach 1 The market risk premium ( MRP ) for Australia in 2005 and going forward is set in an international market. Investment

More information

Financial Evolution and Stability The Case of Hedge Funds

Financial Evolution and Stability The Case of Hedge Funds Financial Evolution and Stability The Case of Hedge Funds KENT JANÉR MD of Nektar Asset Management, a market-neutral hedge fund that works with a large element of macroeconomic assessment. Hedge funds

More information

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. The commodity related sectors of Energy and Metals & Mining suffered the most damage.

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. The commodity related sectors of Energy and Metals & Mining suffered the most damage. HIGH YIELD MARKET UPDATE May 2016 Christopher C. Langs, CFA Vice President Taxable Bond Portfolio Manager EXECUTIVE SUMMARY The severe commodity selloff that began in late 2014 has had a profound impact

More information

Obligation-based Asset Allocation for Public Pension Plans

Obligation-based Asset Allocation for Public Pension Plans Obligation-based Asset Allocation for Public Pension Plans Market Commentary July 2015 PUBLIC PENSION PLANS HAVE a single objective to provide income for a secure retirement for their members. Once the

More information

We are motivated to test

We are motivated to test James X. Xiong is head of quantitative research at Morningstar Investment Management in Chicago, IL. james.xiong@morningstar.com Thomas M. Idzorek is the president of Morningstar Investment Management

More information

Evolving beyond plain vanilla ETFs

Evolving beyond plain vanilla ETFs SCHWAB CENTER FOR FINANCIAL RESEARCH Journal of Investment Research Evolving beyond plain vanilla ETFs Anthony B. Davidow, CIMA Vice President, Alternative Beta and Asset Allocation Strategist, Schwab

More information

Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report

Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report Norges Bank s Expert Group on Principles for Risk Adjustment of Performance Figures Final Report November 16, 2015 Magnus Dahlquist Professor, Stockholm School of Economics Christopher Polk Professor,

More information

fi360 Asset Allocation Optimizer: Risk-Return Estimates*

fi360 Asset Allocation Optimizer: Risk-Return Estimates* fi360 Asset Allocation Optimizer: Risk-Return Estimates* Prepared for fi360 by: Richard Michaud, Robert Michaud, Vitaliy Ryabinin New Frontier Advisors LLC Boston, MA 02110 February 2016 * 2016 New Frontier

More information

PERSPECTIVES. Reasonable Expectations for the Long-Run U.S.Equity Risk Premium. Roger G. Clarke, Ph.D and Harindra de Silva, Ph.D.

PERSPECTIVES. Reasonable Expectations for the Long-Run U.S.Equity Risk Premium. Roger G. Clarke, Ph.D and Harindra de Silva, Ph.D. Risk Management PERSPECTIVES April 2003 Reasonable Expectations for the Long-Run U.S.Equity Risk Premium Expectations for the long-run equity risk premium play an important role in asset allocation decisions

More information

DCF and WACC calculation: Theory meets practice

DCF and WACC calculation: Theory meets practice www.pwc.com DCF and WACC calculation: Theory meets practice Table of contents Section 1. Fair value and company valuation page 3 Section 2. The DCF model: Basic assumptions and the expected cash flows

More information

Commodity Trading Advisors. AQF 2005 Nicolas Papageorgiou

Commodity Trading Advisors. AQF 2005 Nicolas Papageorgiou Commodity Trading Advisors AQF 2005 Nicolas Papageorgiou Market size The current size of the global capital markets is estimated to be about $55 trillion, according to Anjilvel, Boudreau, Johmann, Peskin

More information

The Merits of a Sector-Specialist, Sector-Neutral Investing Strategy

The Merits of a Sector-Specialist, Sector-Neutral Investing Strategy leadership series investment insights July 211 The Merits of a Sector-Specialist, Sector-Neutral Investing Strategy Perhaps the primary concern faced by asset managers, investors, and advisors is the need

More information

Yao Zheng University of New Orleans. Eric Osmer University of New Orleans

Yao Zheng University of New Orleans. Eric Osmer University of New Orleans ABSTRACT The pricing of China Region ETFs - an empirical analysis Yao Zheng University of New Orleans Eric Osmer University of New Orleans Using a sample of exchange-traded funds (ETFs) that focus on investing

More information

Commodities Portfolio Approach

Commodities Portfolio Approach Commodities Portfolio Approach Los Angeles Fire and Police Pension System February 2012 Summary The Board approved a 5% allocation to Commodities, representing approximately $690 million of the $13.75

More information

Chapter 5. Risk and Return. Copyright 2009 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.

Chapter 5. Risk and Return. Copyright 2009 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 Risk and Return Learning Goals 1. Understand the meaning and fundamentals of risk, return, and risk aversion. 2. Describe procedures for assessing and measuring the risk of a single asset. 3.

More information

Models of Asset Pricing The implications for asset allocation

Models of Asset Pricing The implications for asset allocation Models of Asset Pricing The implications for asset allocation 2004 Finance & Investment Conference 28 June 2004 Tim Giles CHARLES RIVER ASSOCIATES Vice President CRA London CRA 2004 Agenda New orthodoxy

More information

CHAPTER 6. Topics in Chapter. What are investment returns? Risk, Return, and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

CHAPTER 6. Topics in Chapter. What are investment returns? Risk, Return, and the Capital Asset Pricing Model CHAPTER 6 Risk, Return, and the Capital Asset Pricing Model 1 Topics in Chapter Basic return concepts Basic risk concepts Stand-alone risk Portfolio (market) risk Risk and return: CAPM/SML 2 What are investment

More information

State of the Art Virtual Portfolio Management: Building Skills that Matter

State of the Art Virtual Portfolio Management: Building Skills that Matter State of the Art Virtual Portfolio Management: Building Skills that Matter There are many ways for students to play stock market games or more generally, participate in a virtual portfolio simulation:

More information

2013 Investment Seminar Colloque sur les investissements 2013

2013 Investment Seminar Colloque sur les investissements 2013 2013 Investment Seminar Colloque sur les investissements 2013 Session/Séance: Volatility Management Speaker(s)/Conférencier(s): Nicolas Papageorgiou Associate Professor, HEC Montréal Derivatives Consultant,

More information

SEI s Approach to Asset Allocation

SEI s Approach to Asset Allocation SEI s Approach to Asset Allocation Presented by: Jim Smigiel Managing Director and Portfolio Manager Portfolio Strategies Group What is diversification? Sharpe ratio? Peak Sharpe Ratio Loss of efficiency:

More information

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas 0802869. Words: 3441

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas 0802869. Words: 3441 Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas 0802869 Words: 3441 1 1. Introduction In this paper I present Black, Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973) (BSM) general

More information

Active Management in Swedish National Pension Funds

Active Management in Swedish National Pension Funds STOCKHOLM SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Active Management in Swedish National Pension Funds An Analysis of Performance in the AP-funds Sara Blomstergren (20336) Jennifer Lindgren (20146) December 2008 Master Thesis

More information