Time Variation in Liquidity: The Role of Market Maker Inventories and Revenues

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Time Variation in Liquidity: The Role of Market Maker Inventories and Revenues"

Transcription

1 Time Variation in Liquidity: The Role of Market Maker Inventories and Revenues Carole Comerton-Forde Terrence Hendershott Charles M. Jones Pamela C. Moulton Mark S. Seasholes * January 8, 2008 * Comerton-Forde is at University of Sydney (C.Comerton-Forde@econ.usyd.edu.au); Hendershott is at Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley (hender@haas.berkeley.edu); Jones is at Columbia Business School (cj88@columbia.edu); Moulton is at Fordham Graduate School of Business (pmoulton@fordham.edu); and Seasholes is at Santa Clara University (Mark.S.Seasholes@ ias.com). We thank the NYSE for providing data. We thank Yakov Amihud, Ekkehart Boehmer, Robin Greenwood, Joel Hasbrouck, Jerry Liu, Marios Panayides, Lubos Pastor, Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, Dimitri Vayanos, Vish Viswanathan, Masahiro Watanabe, Pierre-Olivier Weill, and participants at the NBER Market Microstructure meeting, Barclays Global Investors, Columbia, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Maryland, Michigan, Office of Economic Analysis of the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, University of Amsterdam, University of California Santa Barbara, University of Toronto, University of Utah, and University of Washington for helpful comments. Hendershott gratefully acknowledges support from the National Science Foundation. Part of this research was conducted while Moulton was an economist and Comerton-Forde and Hendershott were visiting economists at the New York Stock Exchange. This paper combines two working papers by subsets of the authors: Market Maker Inventories and Liquidity and Market Maker Revenues and Stock Market Liquidity. Preliminary Results Please Contact Authors Before Citing Results

2 Time Variation in Liquidity: The Role of Market Maker Inventories and Revenues Abstract We study time variation in stock market liquidity using an 11-year panel of daily NYSE specialist inventory positions and revenues. When specialists in aggregate have large positions or when they lose money, market-wide effective spreads widen. Results hold after controlling for recent stock returns and conditional volatility. Inventories and revenues for a given specialist firm explain changes in the liquidity of stocks assigned to that firm. The relationship between spreads, inventories, and revenues is stronger for stocks handled by specialist-owned firms than corporate-owned specialist firms. Mergers of specialist-owned firms with corporate-owned firms provide evidence consistent with deeper pockets easing financing constraints. The liquidity of high-volatility stocks is more sensitive to larger inventories and losses than is the liquidity of low-volatility stocks. Finally, we show that the liquidity effects of inventories and revenues are nonlinear and most prominent when inventories are high and revenues are low or negative. In total, our results suggest an important role for market makers financial positions in explaining the time variation of liquidity.

3 1. Introduction Asset market liquidity varies considerably over time. This matters to market participants, who typically worry about the cost of trading into or out of a desired position in a short period of time. Liquidity can affect asset prices, too. When markets are illiquid, for example, investors may demand higher rates of return to compensate. Despite the interest in aggregate liquidity from both of these angles, we know relatively little about exactly why market liquidity varies over time. Recent theoretical work by Gromb and Vayanos (2002, 2007) and Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2006), among others, postulates that limited market-maker capital can explain some of these empirical features of asset market liquidity. Data limitations have hampered empirical work in this area, making it difficult to demonstrate direct links between liquidity supplier behavior and capital constraints. In this paper, we provide direct evidence that shocks to market-maker balance sheets and income statements impact daily stock market liquidity. Using 11 years ( ) of New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) specialist inventory position and trading revenue data, we show for the first time that if specialists find themselves with large positions or lose money on their inventories, effective spreads widen, even after controlling for stock returns and volatility. This relationship holds at both the aggregate market level and the specialist-firm level. How are our findings consistent with the presence of market-maker financing constraints? In the short run at least, specialists and other market makers have limited capital. Lenders typically impose limits on leverage ratios (or equivalently fix required margins), and information problems can make it hard to raise equity quickly or cheaply. This means that market makers face short-term limits on their risk-bearing capacity. As their inventory positions grow larger (in either direction, long or short) and approach the constraint, market makers should reduce the amount of liquidity they are willing to provide. Similarly, losses from trading directly reduce the market maker s equity capital, and if leverage ratios remain fixed, then the market maker s position limits decrease proportionately. 1 Again, market makers should reduce the amount of liquidity they are willing to provide as they approach these limits. Specialist inventories and trading revenues vary considerably over time, so there is ample scope for shocks in these variables to force contractions in liquidity provision. Aggregate 1 Adrian and Shin (2007) show that there is relatively little variation in leverage ratios at investment banks and money-center commercial banks. 1

4 specialist inventories have a standard deviation of roughly $100 million. Specialists in aggregate lose money on about 10% of the trading days during our sample, the average loss is about $4 million on these days, and these losses tend to cluster together in time. Because of their structural advantages, specialists usually earn positive trading revenue on short-term roundtrip transactions, but are exposed to the possibility of losses on inventories held for longer periods. This suggests that the revenues associated with longer-term inventories could be better indicators of whether financial constraints are easing or tightening. When we decompose revenues into intraday vs. longer-term components, we find that revenues associated with inventories held overnight are indeed the ones that are associated with future liquidity. This overnight breakpoint dovetails nicely with our story, because anecdotal evidence indicates that lenders and risk managers are most likely to evaluate financing terms and position limits based on daily P&L and end-of-day balance sheets. Interestingly, we find a long bias among specialists. Aggregate NYSE specialist positions are net long over 94 percent of the time, and individual specialist firms are net long over 83 percent of the time. Specialists also have an affirmative obligation to buffer order flow, buying when others want to sell and vice versa. This means that specialists tend to increase their inventory positions and lose money when the aggregate market declines. These losses may reduce the firm s available capital and thus its risk-bearing capacity; liquidity should be worse immediately thereafter. Thus, market-maker positions and losses might be able to account for the well-known fact that when the market declines, aggregate liquidity worsens (see, for example, Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2001), Chordia, Sarkar, and Subrahmanyam (2005), and Hameed, Kang, and Viswanathan (2006)). Fortunately, specialist inventories and trading revenues are not perfectly correlated with contemporaneous stock returns, so it is possible to find times when specialists have large positions or lose money without a corresponding price decline, or when specialists have relatively small inventories and earn positive trading revenue in a declining market. When all these variables appear in a predictive regression, larger specialist inventories and losses are still associated with wider spreads in the following period. Also, as predicted by financing constraints, the effects of inventories and revenues exhibit nonlinearity: The marginal effects are greater when inventories are highest and revenues lowest. 2

5 While the effects are strong at the aggregate level, the financing constraints relationship should actually operate at the specialist firm level. There should be a common component in liquidity for all stocks assigned to a particular specialist firm, and that firm s inventories and revenues should affect liquidity in those stocks. Coughenour and Saad (2004) demonstrate the former; here we show that a specialist firm s inventories and trading revenues predict future liquidity in that firm s assigned stocks. As with the aggregate results, the inventory and trading revenue effects are greatest when inventories are highest and revenues lowest. Next we identify cases where a specialist firm may be closer to a funding constraint a priori. To do so we examine specialist firms in which the specialists themselves supply the capital; such specialist-owned firms may face tighter financing constraints than corporate-owned specialist firms (Coughenour and Deli (2002)). We show that for stocks assigned to specialist-owned firms, liquidity is more sensitive to inventories and specialist-firm losses. During our sample period, these specialist-owned firms all merged with larger corporateowned specialist firms. These mergers provide a potentially exogenous positive shock to capital. When we follow the stocks assigned to the specialist-owned firm before the merger, we find that liquidity in these stocks becomes somewhat less sensitive to specialist inventories and revenues after the merger, consistent with deep pockets easing these financing constraints. Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2006) show that limited risk-bearing capacity can have a differential impact on high- and low-fundamental-volatility stocks. They use the term flight to quality to refer to the result that the liquidity differential between high- and low-volatility securities is bigger when market makers have taken on larger positions or when their wealth decreases. 2 We test these predictions by examining the relation between inventories and revenues and the liquidity of high- and low-volatility stocks. Supporting the theoretical prediction, the liquidity of high-volatility stocks is more sensitive to larger inventories and losses than is the liquidity of low-volatility stocks. We also show that when a specialist firm loses money on its overnight inventory, it is more likely to reduce its inventory position. This provides a mechanism for the illiquidity we observe in the data following a decline in trading revenues. 2 Flight to quality is also present in Pastor and Stambaugh (2003). 3

6 Our data cover only one market maker per stock the specialist assigned by the NYSE to that stock but that liquidity provider is probably the most important one, given the structural advantages that accrued to the specialist over our sample period. In addition, specialist inventories and revenues may be good proxies for the inventories and trading revenues of other competing liquidity suppliers, such as market makers on regional exchanges, proprietary trading desks at various Wall Street firms, hedge funds following a market-making strategy, and so on. 3 While we have no direct evidence, it may be appropriate to think of our specialist inventory and revenue numbers as reflective of broader market-maker inventory and revenues. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews related literature. Section 3 provides a general description of our data and sample. Section 4 shows the basic relations between aggregate market-maker revenues, inventories, and market liquidity. Section 5 looks at the specialist-firm level. Sections 6 and 7 study the set of specialist-owned firms where we a priori expect financing constraints to bind. Section 6 makes the cross-sectional comparison; Section 7 studies the mergers of these firms. Section 8 investigates whether market makers demonstrate a flight to quality in their liquidity provision. Section 9 looks briefly at the behavior of inventories following declines in trading revenue, and Section 10 concludes. 2. Related Literature Most models of market liquidity focus on three types of trading costs: fixed, inventory, and information. 4 These classic models can themselves generate time variation in liquidity, as liquidity is typically driven by the volatility of fundamental values, which could presumably change over time. Thus we control for volatility changes in our empirical work. Theory focusing on funding costs and financing constraints is more recent. Kyle and Xiong (2001) show how convergence traders (arbitrageurs ) having decreasing risk aversion leads to correlated liquidations and higher volatility. Gromb and Vayanos (2002) study a model in which arbitrageurs face margin constraints and show how these arbitrageurs' liquidity provision 3 4 See Boehmer and Wu (2006) for evidence on relations among signed trading activity by different market participants at the NYSE. Kyle (1985) and Gloston and Milgrom (1985) examine the impact of private information. Stoll (1978), Amihud and Mendelson (1980), Ho and Stoll (1981, 1983), Mildenstein and Schleef (1983), and Grossman and Miller (1988) examine the impact of inventories. Inventory models without capital constraints predict that liquidity (the width of the bid-ask spread) is not affected by the market maker s inventory position. 4

7 benefits all investors. 5 However, because the arbitrageurs cannot capture all of the benefits, they fail to take the socially optimal level of risk. Weill (2006) examines dynamic liquidity provision by market makers and shows that if they have access to sufficient capital, the market makers provide the socially optimal amount of liquidity, but if capital is insufficient or too costly then market makers will undersupply liquidity. Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2006) construct a model along the lines of Grossman and Miller (1988) that also links market makers funding and market liquidity. 6 Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2000), Hasbrouck and Seppi (2001), and Huberman and Halka (2001) examine the common component in liquidity changes across stocks. Coughenour and Saad (2004) show that the co-movement in liquidity is stronger among stocks traded by the same NYSE specialist firm. Both liquidity supplier wealth (revenues) and the amount of capital committed by liquidity suppliers (inventories) play significant roles in the theoretical work on capital constraints and liquidity. 7 Prior data on market-maker inventories and trading typically cover relatively short periods of time and/or a limited number of securities. 8 While these limitations precluded testing for the relation between aggregate liquidity and limited market maker risk-bearing capacity at interday horizons, the microstructure literature has been successful in showing that inventories play an important role in intraday trading and price formation. For example, Madhavan and Smidt (1993), Hansch, Naik, and Viswanathan (1998), Reiss and Werner (1998), and Naik and Yadav (2003a) all find support for market makers controlling risk by mean reverting their inventory positions towards target levels. Hansch, Naik, and Viswanathan (1998) and Reiss and Werner (1998) show that differences in inventory positions across dealers determine which dealers offer the best prices and when dealers trade Yuan (2005) provides a model which shows a link between information asymmetry and liquidity when informed investors are constrained. This effect is more severe if market makers face market-liquidity-reducing predation (Attari, Mello, and Ruckes (2005) and Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2005)). Naik and Yadav (2003b) show that the contemporaneous relationship between government bond price changes and changes in market-maker inventories differs when market-maker inventories are very long or very short, but they do not directly examine liquidity. For examples using NYSE specialist data see Hasbrouck and Sofianos (1993), Madhavan and Smidt (1993), and Madhavan and Sofianos (1998). For examples using London Stock Exchange market-maker data see Hansch, Naik, and Viswanathan (1998), Reiss and Werner (1998), and Naik and Yadav (2003a). For futures markets data see Mann and Manaster (1996). For options market data see Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2005). For foreign exchange data see Lyons (2001) and Cao, Evans, and Lyons (2006). 5

8 A number of papers examine the profitability of specialists. 9 Hasbrouck and Sofianos (1993) decompose specialist profits by trading horizon and find that most profits are due to their high frequency (short-term) trading strategies. Coughenour and Harris (2004) extend this econometrically and examine how the tick size change from 1/16 to $0.01 impacts specialist profits. Panayides (2007) analyzes how specialists trading, inventory, and profitability depend on their obligations under NYSE rules. 3. Data and Descriptive Statistics We use three data sources CRSP, NYSE s Specialist Equity Trade Summary (SPETS), 10 and Trades and Quotes (TAQ) to construct a daily sample of liquidity, specialist trading revenues, inventories, returns, and volatility. We measure each of these quantities and conduct empirical work at two different levels of aggregation: market-wide and at the specialist-firm level. Market-level daily time series extend from 1994 to 2004 (2,770 days) and are denoted with subscript m. The specialist-firm level analysis is conducted using an unbalanced panel denoted with subscript f. The panel is unbalanced because there is substantial consolidation among specialist firms over our 11-year sample period. There were 41 specialist firms in 1994, declining to seven by 2004, and over the sample period a total of 55 distinct specialist firms operated at the NYSE. 11 The specialist-firm level analysis includes the 37 specialist firms that have at least 750 days of trading data (about three years), and every day we update the set of common stocks assigned to each specialist firm. The resulting panel incorporates 96.7% of the stock-day observations used in the market-wide time-series analysis. Liquidity: To measure liquidity at both the market level and specialist-firm level, we construct a daily effective spread measure. The effective spread is the difference between an estimate of the true value of the security (the midpoint of the bid and ask quotes) and the actual transaction Market-maker profits have also been examined in other markets. For example, Hansch, Naik, and Viswanathan (1999) examine how London Stock Exchange market-maker trading profits vary depending on whether the trade is preferenced or internalized. As its name suggests, SPETS provides a daily summary of specialist activity. The file records, on a stock-bystock basis, daily specialist purchases in dollars and shares, daily specialist sales in dollars and shares, and opening and closing specialist inventory positions. SPETS data is also employed by Madhavan and Sofianos (1998) and Hendershott and Seasholes (2007). See Hatch and Johnson (2002) for a discussion of specialist firm consolidation. See Corwin (2004) for a discussion of the allocation of stocks to specialist firms. 6

9 price. 12 We use effective spreads because specialists and floor brokers are sometimes willing to trade at prices within quoted bid and ask prices. The wider the effective spread, the less liquid is the stock. [ Insert Figure 1 Here] To get a market-level or specialist firm-level liquidity measure, effective spreads for each stock are averaged each day using share volume weights and then averaged across stocks using market capitalization weights. Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2001), Jones (2006), and Hameed, Kang, and Viswanathan (2006) document a downward trend in average effective spreads over much of our sample period. Figure 1 highlights the narrowing trend along with two sharp declines due to reductions in the minimum tick size. The first reduction was from eighths to sixteenths on June 24, 1997 and the second was from sixteenths to pennies on January 29, To account for these trends, we define the dollar effective spread measure Spr($) t as the effective spread on day t relative to its average value in the recent past (subscripts m and f suppressed): Spr($) t = ES($) t j= 6 ES ($), (1) where ES($) t refers to the market-wide effective spread (subscript m) or the average effective spread on the set of stocks assigned to the specialist firm (subscript f) on day t. Proportional effective spreads (Spr(%) t ) are defined analogously; please see Appendix A for full details. Lags 6 through 10 are used because many of our specifications predict future effective spreads using specialist revenues, inventories, and returns at lags 1 through 5 as explanatory variables. We want to ensure that our effective spread measure is not affected by contemporaneous correlation among these right-hand side variables. t j Specialist Trading Revenues: For each stock i on each day t, we decompose specialist gross trading revenues into two parts. The first part reflects revenues related to inventories held overnight and equals the mark-to-market profits on day t-1 inventory (the starting position on day t) plus mark-to-market profits on the net change in inventory from day t-1 to day t. The 12 Other liquidity measures such as quoted spreads yield very similar results. 7

10 second part corresponds to intraday trading and equals the revenues earned on all round-trip transactions on day t. Please see Appendix B for details related to specialist profit decomposition. Specialist revenues are aggregated each day at the market level or for each specialist firm and then demeaned. There are four regimes for demeaning, since specialist participation rates and the nature of specialist trading change markedly when the minimum tick size changes and at the beginning of We also envisage sustained losses affecting liquidity more than a oneday temporary loss. Therefore, our analysis sums revenues over five-day periods, and we define the gross trading revenue measure RevGr t-1, the revenue from inventories measure RevInv t-1, and the intraday round-trip revenue measure RevTr t-1 as the sum of the relevant daily revenue over the interval [t-5, t-1], with the following decomposition (subscripts m or f suppressed): RevGr t-1 = RevInv t-1 + RevTr t-1 (2) Inventories: We obtain the specialist dollar inventory I for each stock i at the end of day t. Inventories are summed cross-sectionally each day at the market level or for each specialist firm, as appropriate. Figure 2 graphs market-level specialist inventories between 1994 and [ Insert Figure 2 Here ] The average aggregate inventory position over the 11 years is $196 million, with a range of - $331 million to $988 million and a daily standard deviation of $137 million. Inventory is negative on only 163 of the 2,770 days in our sample, so that specialists in aggregate are net long 94% of the time. Similar calculations at the specialist-firm level indicate that a specialist firm is on average net long 83% of the time. To measure the amount of risk assumed by market makers, we aggregate (signed) dollar inventories up to the specialist-firm level or the market level and then take the absolute value to get the magnitude of the overall position (subscripts m or f suppressed): 13 In early 2003, the NYSE and SEC begin to investigate the trading behavior of specialists, leading to criminal indictments of individual specialists and fines for specialist firms see Ip and Craig (2003). In addition to the two dates related to tick-size changes, we also use January 1, 2003 to mark a regime change. 8

11 Inv t-1 = Ii, t 1 (3) Dynamic models with market-maker inventories, e.g., Amihud and Mendelson (1980) and Madhavan and Smidt (1993), predict that market makers mean revert their inventory levels to a target level. Madhavan and Smidt (1993) find empirically that the target level is greater than zero, which we also find. We have also calculated inventories as the deviation from the average inventory level (a proxy for the target inventory level). When we do this, positive demeaned inventories predict higher future spreads, while negative demeaned inventories have no predictive power for future spreads. This suggests that simply taking the absolute value is the right way to proceed, consistent with the idea that lenders are concerned with the absolute risk that an inventory position entails, rather than the risk associated with a deviation from a target position. i Returns: We measure the daily return on the value-weighted portfolio of NYSE common stocks, as well as the return on the value-weighted portfolio of common stocks assigned to each specialist firm. Lagged returns r are logged and summed over five days (t-1 to t-5) and used as a predictor variable in our analysis (subscript m or f suppressed): 5 1 Ret t-1 = ln( 1+ t j ) 5 j= 1 r (4) Volatility: To measure changes in volatility we estimate the asymmetric GARCH(1,1) model of Glosten, Jagannathan, and Runkle (1993) on daily log stock returns on the market or on the specialist firm portfolio (subscript m or f suppressed): h t 2 2 = + δ ht 1 + α ut 1 + φ ut 1I t 1 κ, (5) where u t = r t μ is distributed N(0, h t ), and I t-1 = 1 if u t-1 0 and I t-1 = 0 otherwise. In order to match the treatment of effective spreads, we define the conditional return variance measure as: 9

12 VarRet t = h t j= 6 h (6) t j Many of the variables in the regressions are calculated relative to recent means over the interval [t-10, t-6]. This is a kind of hybrid approach, as it is somewhere between working with levels and working with first differences. First differences are not appropriate, since there is no theoretical reason to believe that any of the variables here contain a unit root. Levels are not appropriate in the presence of apparent non-stationarity. While we are not aware of any econometric theory that directly addresses our approach, subtracting off recent means is a common approach in other areas of finance (cf. the relative T-bill yield, introduced by Campbell (1991) and now common in the return predictability literature). The hybrid approach induces a modest amount of moving average behavior, which requires the use of autocorrelation-consistent standard errors throughout Descriptive statistics Table 1 contains correlations and standard deviations for the market-wide variables used in this paper. Aggregate specialist revenues (RevGr m,t-1 ) are fairly volatile, with a standard deviation of $16.1 million around the regime means. Note that all revenue variables are aggregated over five trading days in the regressions, so the standard deviations essentially refer to weekly trading revenues. Revenues from intraday round-trips (RevTr m,t-1 ) are more volatile than revenues from overnight inventory (RevInv m,t-1 ), with a daily standard deviation of $13.9 million vs. $7.7 million. As a result, the 0.88 contemporaneous correlation between RevTr m,t-1 and gross trading revenues is much higher than the 0.50 correlation between RevInv m,t-1 and RevGr m,t-1. Interestingly, the two components of specialist revenue are virtually uncorrelated with each other (ρ = 0.03), while revenues from overnight inventory are strongly correlated with contemporaneous stock market returns (ρ = 0.61). The latter correlation makes sense given our earlier observation that aggregate specialist inventories are almost always net long. Given that we are using absolute values of inventories and specialist trading revenues as proxies for financing constraints, we expect the two measures to be negatively related. This is indeed the case, especially for revenues from overnight inventory positions. While the correlation between inventories and RevGr m,t-1 or RevTr m,t-1 are a modest 0.15 or 0.08, 10

13 respectively, the correlation with RevInv m,t-1 is a much stronger This correlation is a function of the average long specialist position combined with the specialist s liquidity provision role. Specialists tend to find themselves with even bigger long positions when the market declines, and they lose money in the process (the correlation between ending inventories on day t and the 5-day market return ending on day t is 0.52). [ Insert Table 1 Here ] 4. Market Liquidity and Market Maker Inventories and Revenues The main empirical goal of the paper is to see if economic state variables related to financing constraints can account for the observed time-series variation in stock market liquidity. Our main innovation is the use of specialist revenues and specialist inventories as a proxy for financial constraints faced by intermediaries, but we also benchmark the findings by examining other possible mechanisms, such as the standard theoretical link between conditional volatility and market liquidity that is present in most microstructure models. We start by simply regressing market-wide effective spreads on day t on aggregate gross trading revenues summed over the interval [t 5, t 1]. The results are in the first column of each panel of Table 2. Panel A examines proportional effective spreads; Panel B examines dollar effective spreads. In both cases, the coefficients are only marginally different from zero. At first glance, this would seem to provide little support for a financing constraints story, because it is aggregate losses that would impair a market-maker s capital position and make it more difficult for an intermediary to finance its trading positions. However, specification (2) in the same table reveals that when gross trading revenues are partitioned into revenues associated with overnight inventory (RevInv m,t-1 ) and revenues associated with intraday round-trips (RevTr m,t-1 ), inventory revenues have a large negative effect on spreads, while the coefficient on round-trip revenues is indistinguishable from zero. [ Insert Table 2 Here ] Throughout the paper, we focus on inventory revenues because there are confounding effects between intraday trading revenues and future spreads. RevTr is essentially the total dollar 11

14 amount of effective spread earned on intraday round-trips by specialists less the associated losses to informed traders. Thus, it is a realized or net spread for specialists. If these realized spread changes are persistent for whatever reason (say, for example, that the specialist has market power or the amount of intraday specialist trading is persistent), then the relationship between today s RevTr and tomorrow s spread could be fairly mechanical. If RevTr and spreads both increase today, they are likely to both remain high tomorrow, and a higher RevTr today ends up predicting a higher effective spread tomorrow. In contrast, inventory-related revenues are not tied up with spreads in this way and are much easier to interpret. When specialists make money on their inventories, market-wide spreads tend to narrow the next period. The statistical evidence is compelling, as revenues alone explain about 23% of the daily variance in the proportional effective spread measure. In terms of economic magnitude, Panel A of Table 2 shows that a one standard deviation increase in inventory-related revenues (equal to $7.7 million from Table 1) narrows our aggregate proportional effective spread measure by 7.7 * / 1000 = 0.3 basis points on average the next day, about half of the daily standard deviation of basis points from Table 1 for the spread measure itself. Financial constraints are generally non-linear, so we look next at whether these sensitivities are greater following extreme specialist losses. In specification (3) we add a kink to both RevInv m,t-1 and RevTr m,t-1 at the lowest quartile (25 th percentile). Consistent with theory, the biggest losses are associated with bigger spread widenings, and the non-linearity is fairly pronounced. Based on the numbers in Panel A, the slope coefficient on RevInv m,t-1 is about 22 for 75% of days and 50 in the left tail of the inventory revenues distribution. We also obtain similar results when the kink is located at zero or one standard deviation below zero. To differentiate between traditional inventory models and models in which liquidity providers have limited risk-bearing capacity, we next test the spread-inventory relationship. Specification (4) includes a constant and the absolute value of aggregate specialist inventories (in hundreds of millions of dollars) on the right-hand side. We find that larger inventories yesterday lead to higher spreads today. Panel A shows that an additional $100 million in inventory, which is slightly less than a one-standard deviation change, corresponds to an increase of 0.17 basis points in our proportional effective spread measure; results are of similar magnitude when we examine dollar spreads. In specification (5), we add a kink to the linear 12

15 relationship between inventories and future liquidity, located at the upper quartile (75 th percentile) of the absolute inventory distribution. The idea is that when inventories are particularly large in either direction, market makers may be more constrained and require more compensation to provide liquidity. The data reveal strong evidence of this kind of non-linearity. On typical days, a $100 million increase in aggregate inventories increases the market-wide effective spread by basis points. But when inventories are beyond the 75 th percentile, the sensitivity of spreads to inventories more than doubles. In addition to our market-maker state variables, there are other variables that have been associated with changes in liquidity, both theoretically and empirically. For example, classic microstructure models, such as Kyle (1985) and Glosten and Milgrom (1985), say that liquidity should be decreasing in the variance of fundamental value. On the empirical side, Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2000, 2001) show that when markets fall, liquidity dries up. Perhaps our revenue and inventory variables are simply co-linear with these other, previously identified effects. For example, since specialists are net long over 94% of the time, we know that profits on overnight inventory positions will be quite correlated with market returns (Table 1 shows that the correlation between the two is 0.61). Similarly, the specialist s obligation to buffer order flow suggests that inventories are likely to grow large following a sharp market decline (the Table 1 correlation between absolute inventories and returns is -0.52). While financing constraints plus average net long intermediary positions together imply a correlation between market returns and next period s average liquidity, a financing constraint explanation is even more plausible if markets become illiquid when specialists lose money or take on large positions without a big market move. To investigate this, we estimate specification (6) of Table 2, which combines specialist revenue variables, absolute inventories, market returns, and the conditional return variance: Spr m, t = t α + β1revinvm, t 1 + β2revtrm, t 1 + β3invm, t 1 + β4retm, t 1 + β5varretm, t + ε m,. (7) As noted above, there is a fair bit of collinearity between the various explanatory variables, so not all of the right-hand side variables remain significant. Regardless of whether we use proportional effective spreads in Panel A or dollar effective spreads in Panel B, we find that the 13

16 coefficient on overnight inventory revenues RevInv m,t-1 remains negative and strongly statistically significant. When specialists lose money overall, both dollar and proportional spreads widen, even if the market is not falling at the same time. Inventory levels are also significant in Panel A. Note that the main reason we examine both dollar spreads and proportional spreads is that if spreads are limited by a discrete price grid, there will be a mechanical relationship between proportional spreads and the stock price level, and this may account for the relationship between market returns and future liquidity. Note that the R 2 measures for the dollar effective spread regressions in Panel B tend to be lower for the same reason. In fact, when we eliminate this denominator effect by using dollar spreads in Panel B, our revenue and inventory variables drive the effect of lagged market returns to virtually zero. In our final specification of Table 2, we allow a non-linear effect for both revenues and inventories. While this asks a lot of the data, given the collinearity between most of the explanatory variables, we continue to find evidence in specification (7) that the effects are biggest when specialists take on large positions and when they suffer the biggest losses on these overnight inventory positions. For robustness, we have also estimated (but do not report) a number of other variants of these specifications. The reported results are not driven by any particular subsample: the results are present during each of the tick-size periods in our sample, and the results are present in generally rising and generally falling markets. The results hold for quoted spreads as well as effective spreads. Including trading volume and the variance of trading volume has no effect on the coefficients of interest. 14 Finally, our quasi-differencing is not driving the results. When we estimate a vector autoregression on spreads, market returns, absolute market returns, intraday and overnight specialist revenues, and specialist inventories, taking a piecewise linear time trend out of the spreads for each tick regime, we get similar results on the importance of specialist inventories and revenues; these results are available from the authors upon request. The aggregate evidence strongly supports a role for financial constraints in shaping stock market liquidity. However, financial constraints should operate at the level of the financial intermediary, so we turn next to more disaggregated evidence to see if it too supports a capital constraint story. 14 See Lee, Mucklow, and Ready (1993) for intraday evidence that higher volume leads to higher subsequent spreads. 14

17 5. Liquidity and Market Maker Inventories and Revenues at the Specialist-firm Level If specialists are marginal liquidity suppliers, then a stock s liquidity should suffer if its specialist firm faces financing constraints. If financing constraints bind for all specialist firms at the same time, then we should indeed see all the effects at the aggregate level. However, if specialist firm revenues are imperfectly correlated, different specialist firms may face financing constraints at different times, and we might be able to find even better empirical support for the constraints hypothesis by identifying a relationship between specialist firm revenues and liquidity in that firm s assigned stocks. At the end of our sample, there are only seven specialist firms, each with a broadly diversified list of assigned stocks. Facing little idiosyncratic risk, these specialist firms are likely to generate revenues and take on inventories that are highly correlated with each other. However, at the beginning of the sample, there are 41 specialist firms, resulting in considerable cross-sectional dispersion in revenues and inventories, and thereby aiding identification. To proceed, we aggregate now only up to the specialist firm level and create an unbalanced panel with one observation for each specialist firm for each day. We quasi-difference and demean all variables as discussed in Section 3. In particular, we calculate gross trading revenues for each specialist firm f ending on day t (RevGr f,t ), which is then decomposed into overnight inventory-related revenues (RevInv f,t ) and intraday round-trip revenues (RevTr f,t ). We calculate the absolute dollar inventory position for each specialist firm based on its assigned stocks each day. A value-weighted effective spread measure is calculated each day for all the stocks assigned to a given specialist firm. We also calculate value-weighted returns (Ret f,t ) on this portfolio of assigned stocks in excess of the aggregate market return, along with the associated conditional volatility (VarRet f,t ) using an asymmetric GARCH model. Table 3 shows the correlations and standard deviations for the variables in the specialist-firm panel. The general patterns from the market-wide analysis carry over to the specialist-firm level, but magnitudes naturally are smaller. Specialist-firm gross trading revenues (RevGr f,t-1 ) have a standard deviation of $2.1 million around the regime means. Again, weekly revenues from intraday round-trips (RevTr f,t-1 ) are substantially more volatile (σ = $1.9 million) than revenues from overnight inventory (RevInv f,t-1 ), with a standard deviation of only $0.8 million. Compared to the market-wide correlations, the two components of specialist-firm revenue are somewhat 15

18 more positively correlated with each other (ρ = 0.012), while the correlation between RevInv f,t-1 and contemporaneous stock market returns Ret f,t-1 is more modest (ρ = 0.24). Note that these are pooled correlations, so cross-sectional differences in scale between the specialist firms may account for some of the differences from the market-wide correlations. For the specialist-firm panel, pooled regressions are estimated, and inference is conducted using double-clustered Thompson (2006) standard errors, which are robust to both crosssectional correlation and idiosyncratic time-series persistence. [ Insert Table 4 Here ] The results are in Table 4. Panel A examines proportional effective spreads, while Panel B displays results for dollar effective spreads. Specification (1) shows that, in contrast to earlier regressions at the aggregate level, specialist firm gross trading revenues are significant predictors of next day liquidity in that firm s assigned stocks, though the economic magnitude remains small. As discussed earlier, there could be confounding effects between intraday revenues (RevTr f,t-1 ) and future spreads, so we again decompose the specialist firm s daily revenues and focus on revenues that arise from overnight inventory (RevInv f,t-1 ). Specification (2) shows that these inventory-related revenues continue to predict liquidity at the specialist-firm level, with t- statistics in the neighborhood of 4 for both proportional and dollar effective spreads. In economic terms, if a specialist firm experiences a one standard deviation inventory revenue shortfall of $0.78 million, the spread on that firm s stocks the next day widens by an average of 0.16 basis points. We look next at non-linearities following extreme specialist losses. In specification (3) we add a kink to both RevInv and RevTr at the lower quartile point (25 th percentile). As in the market-level results, the biggest losses are associated with significantly bigger spread widenings. Based on the numbers in Panel B, the slope coefficient on RevInv is about 133 on a typical day and about 254 in the left tail of the inventory revenues distribution. Again, we find that larger inventories yesterday lead to higher spreads today. The kink in the spread-inventory relationship is particularly pronounced. Specification (5) shows that when specialist-firm absolute inventories are above their 75 th percentile value, market makers require more compensation to provide liquidity. For example, based on the results in Panel A, there is 16

19 virtually no relationship between inventories and spreads for typical inventory levels. However, when inventories are beyond the 75 th percentile, the sensitivity of spreads to inventories of is strongly significant and means that a one-standard deviation inventory shock of about $19.8 million in the tail of the distribution predicts a spread narrowing of about * = 0.1 basis point. Specification (6) is the kitchen-sink version, which predicts tomorrow s effective spreads on the value-weighted portfolio of assigned stocks using specialist-firm level RevInv f,t-1 and RevTr f,t- 1, returns on the portfolio of assigned stocks, and conditional volatility on the assigned stocks: Spr f, t = t α + β1revinv f, t 1 + β 2RevTrf, t 1 + β 3Inv f, t 1 + β 4Ret f, t 1 + β5varret f, t + ε f,. (8) Recall that all of these explanatory variables exhibit considerable covariation, so we expect some of them to become insignificant when all are included together. Revenues related to overnight inventory survive in the Panel B dollar spread regressions, but inventory does not fare well in either Panel A or Panel B. When we add kinks to the revenue and inventory variables in specification (7), we find that the significant coefficient on RevInv is driven by the left tail of the distribution, again consistent with financial constraints binding more severely following relatively large revenue losses. Overall at the specialist firm level, there is evidence that specialist-firm trading revenues and inventories affect next period s spreads. We suspect that there is considerable heterogeneity across specialist firms and over time, and in the next section we identify and examine specialist firms that are a priori most likely to be constrained. 6. Evidence from Specialist Firm Ownership Early in our sample period, there is considerable variation in the size and ownership structure of specialist firms. If some specialist firms have less access to capital, we would expect to see cross-sectional differences in the sensitivity of spreads to inventories and trading losses. While we do not have access to specialist firm balance sheets or income statements per se, Coughenour and Deli (2002) have identified three specialist firms that are owned by the specialists themselves, along with three specialist firms in which the specialists are employees. The 17

20 difference in ownership structure suggests that specialist-owned firms may have less access to capital than corporate-owned specialist firms. In this section, we investigate whether there is a cross-sectional difference in how these two kinds of specialist firms react to trading losses and inventory shocks. To do this, we construct a daily panel for these six specialist firms, beginning on January 1, Each specialist firm remains in the sample until it is acquired or March 1, 2002, when the last specialist-owned firm is acquired, whichever is earlier. The format is similar to the pooled regressions in the previous section, aggregating to the specialist-firm level, except that we define a dummy variable Dum f,t which is equal to 1 for specialist-owned firms and zero otherwise, and we interact this dummy with all of the right-hand side variables. For example, the specification with inventories alone on the right-hand side becomes: Spr f, t = t α 1 + α 2Dum f, t 1 + β1 Inv f, t 1 + β 2 Inv f, t 1 Dum f, t 1 + ε f,. (9) In this case, we are interested in the null hypothesis that β 2 = 0; more generally, we look to all of the interaction terms for evidence that spreads in stocks assigned to specialist-owned firms are more sensitive to inventory and revenue shocks. Standard errors are based on Thompson (2006). Table 5 presents the results. In each specification, we reject the null in favor of the alternative that spreads are more sensitive for specialist-owned firms. For example, specification (1) reveals that a $1 million shock to inventory revenues causes a basis point change in spreads for corporate-owned specialist firms. The effect is more than quadrupled for specialistowned firms. Specification (2) in the table corresponds to equation (9) above, with inventories as explanatory variables, and the effect of firm type is similarly strong, with a t-statistic of 2.35 on the interacted inventory variable. When we throw revenues, inventories, past stock returns, and conditional return variances into the regression together, the specialist revenue variables become insignificant, but the coefficient on the interacted inventory variable remains at 10.29, with a t-statistic of This means that an additional $1 million of inventory is associated with an additional basis points of spread for the specialist-owned firm relative to other specialist firms. 18

21 Thus, we have strong evidence that access to capital can affect the sensitivity of spreads to market-maker revenue and inventory shocks. However, it is possible that the stocks assigned to specialist-owned firms are somehow different from the stocks assigned to corporate-owned specialist firms, and that this somehow accounts for our results. To address this possibility, we look next at a time-series analysis of the same stocks following a relaxation of financial constraints. 7. Evidence from Specialist-Firm Mergers What should happen if financing constraints are suddenly relaxed? Specialists should become less sensitive to losses and less constrained by large inventory positions. In this section, we investigate whether deep pockets help specialists provide liquidity by looking at the mergers of the three specialist-owned firms from Section 6. The first merger took place on March 20, 2001 when Benjamin Jacobson & Sons was acquired by Spear Leeds Kellogg. On October 19, 2001, Bocklet & Company was acquired by LaBranche & Co. The final of the three mergers took place on March 1, 2004, with Van Der Moolen acquiring Lyden, Dolan, Nick & Company. The empirical strategy is straightforward. We first identify the set of stocks assigned to each specialist firm just prior to the merger. The same stocks are studied post-merger to see if there is a change in the sensitivity of spreads. Specifically, we define a dummy variable Post f,t for each date and specialist firm that is equal to one after a firm is merged and zero otherwise. We interact this dummy with each of the included revenue and inventory measures to see if there is an identifiable difference in sensitivities post-merger. For example, the specification with inventories alone on the right-hand side is: Spr f, t = t α 1 + α 2Post f, t 1 + β1 Inv f, t 1 + β 2 Inv f, t 1 Post f, t 1 + ε f,. (10) and the relevant null hypothesis is that β 2 = 0. The pre-merger period covers event days [-70, - 11], about three calendar months, and the post-merger period is defined symmetrically as event 19

Time Variation in Liquidity: The Role of Market Maker Inventories and Revenues

Time Variation in Liquidity: The Role of Market Maker Inventories and Revenues Journal of Finance forthcoming Time Variation in Liquidity: The Role of Market Maker Inventories and Revenues Carole Comerton-Forde Terrence Hendershott Charles M. Jones Pamela C. Moulton Mark S. Seasholes

More information

Market Maker Inventories and Stock Prices

Market Maker Inventories and Stock Prices Capital Market Frictions Market Maker Inventories and Stock Prices By Terrence Hendershott and Mark S. Seasholes* Empirical studies linking liquidity provision to asset prices follow naturally from inventory

More information

Decimalization and market liquidity

Decimalization and market liquidity Decimalization and market liquidity Craig H. Furfine On January 29, 21, the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) implemented decimalization. Beginning on that Monday, stocks began to be priced in dollars and

More information

Commonality in liquidity: A demand-side explanation

Commonality in liquidity: A demand-side explanation Commonality in liquidity: A demand-side explanation Andrew Koch, Stefan Ruenzi, and Laura Starks *, ** Abstract We hypothesize that a source of commonality in a stock s liquidity arises from correlated

More information

Participation Strategy of the NYSE Specialists to the Trades

Participation Strategy of the NYSE Specialists to the Trades Journal of Economic and Social Research 10(1) 2008, 73-113 Participation Strategy of the NYSE Bülent Köksal Abstract. Using 2001 NYSE system order data in the decimal pricing environment, we analyze how

More information

FINANCIAL MARKETS GROUP AN ESRC RESEARCH CENTRE

FINANCIAL MARKETS GROUP AN ESRC RESEARCH CENTRE Daily Closing Inside Spreads and Trading Volumes Around Earning Announcements By Daniella Acker Matthew Stalker and Ian Tonks DISCUSSION PAPER 404 February 2002 FINANCIAL MARKETS GROUP AN ESRC RESEARCH

More information

UNIVERSITÀ DELLA SVIZZERA ITALIANA MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE AND ITS APPLICATIONS

UNIVERSITÀ DELLA SVIZZERA ITALIANA MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE AND ITS APPLICATIONS UNIVERSITÀ DELLA SVIZZERA ITALIANA MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE AND ITS APPLICATIONS Course goals This course introduces you to market microstructure research. The focus is empirical, though theoretical work

More information

Limited Attention and the Allocation of Effort in Securities Trading

Limited Attention and the Allocation of Effort in Securities Trading Limited Attention and the Allocation of Effort in Securities Trading SHANE A. CORWIN and JAY F. COUGHENOUR * ABSTRACT While limited attention has been analyzed in a variety of economic and psychological

More information

Affirmative obligations and market making with inventory $

Affirmative obligations and market making with inventory $ Journal of Financial Economics 86 (2007) 513 542 www.elsevier.com/locate/jfec Affirmative obligations and market making with inventory $ Marios A. Panayides David Eccles School of Business, University

More information

Exchange Entrances, Mergers and the Evolution of Trading of NASDAQ Listed Securities 1993-2010

Exchange Entrances, Mergers and the Evolution of Trading of NASDAQ Listed Securities 1993-2010 Exchange Entrances, Mergers and the Evolution of Trading of NASDAQ Listed Securities 199321 Jared F. Egginton Louisiana Tech University Bonnie F. Van Ness University of Mississippi Robert A. Van Ness University

More information

Internet Appendix to. Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson.

Internet Appendix to. Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson. Internet Appendix to Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson August 9, 2015 This Internet Appendix provides additional empirical results

More information

René Garcia Professor of finance

René Garcia Professor of finance Liquidity Risk: What is it? How to Measure it? René Garcia Professor of finance EDHEC Business School, CIRANO Cirano, Montreal, January 7, 2009 The financial and economic environment We are living through

More information

Market Microstructure & Trading Universidade Federal de Santa Catarina Syllabus. Email: rgencay@sfu.ca, Web: www.sfu.ca/ rgencay

Market Microstructure & Trading Universidade Federal de Santa Catarina Syllabus. Email: rgencay@sfu.ca, Web: www.sfu.ca/ rgencay Market Microstructure & Trading Universidade Federal de Santa Catarina Syllabus Dr. Ramo Gençay, Objectives: Email: rgencay@sfu.ca, Web: www.sfu.ca/ rgencay This is a course on financial instruments, financial

More information

Measures of implicit trading costs and buy sell asymmetry

Measures of implicit trading costs and buy sell asymmetry Journal of Financial s 12 (2009) 418 437 www.elsevier.com/locate/finmar Measures of implicit trading costs and buy sell asymmetry Gang Hu Babson College, 121 Tomasso Hall, Babson Park, MA 02457, USA Available

More information

Tick Size, Spreads, and Liquidity: An Analysis of Nasdaq Securities Trading near Ten Dollars 1

Tick Size, Spreads, and Liquidity: An Analysis of Nasdaq Securities Trading near Ten Dollars 1 Journal of Financial Intermediation 9, 213 239 (2000) doi:10.1006/jfin.2000.0288, available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on Tick Size, Spreads, and Liquidity: An Analysis of Nasdaq Securities Trading

More information

Trading for News: an Examination of Intraday Trading Behaviour of Australian Treasury-Bond Futures Markets

Trading for News: an Examination of Intraday Trading Behaviour of Australian Treasury-Bond Futures Markets Trading for News: an Examination of Intraday Trading Behaviour of Australian Treasury-Bond Futures Markets Liping Zou 1 and Ying Zhang Massey University at Albany, Private Bag 102904, Auckland, New Zealand

More information

Asymmetric Information (2)

Asymmetric Information (2) Asymmetric nformation (2) John Y. Campbell Ec2723 November 2013 John Y. Campbell (Ec2723) Asymmetric nformation (2) November 2013 1 / 24 Outline Market microstructure The study of trading costs Bid-ask

More information

Tick Size and Trading Costs on the Korea Stock Exchange #

Tick Size and Trading Costs on the Korea Stock Exchange # Tick Size and Trading Costs on the Korea Stock Exchange # Kee H. Chung * and Jung S. Shin State University of New York at Buffalo Abstract The Korea Stock Exchange (KSE) imposes larger mandatory tick sizes

More information

Liquidity Supply and Volatility: Futures Market Evidence *

Liquidity Supply and Volatility: Futures Market Evidence * Liquidity Supply and Volatility: Futures Market Evidence * Peter R. Locke Commodity Futures Trading Commission George Washington University Asani Sarkar Federal Reserve Bank of New York 33 Liberty Street

More information

Dark trading and price discovery

Dark trading and price discovery Dark trading and price discovery Carole Comerton-Forde University of Melbourne and Tālis Putniņš University of Technology, Sydney Market Microstructure Confronting Many Viewpoints 11 December 2014 What

More information

Dealing with Negative Values in the High-Low Spread Estimator

Dealing with Negative Values in the High-Low Spread Estimator Dealing with Negative Values in the High-Low Spread Estimator A Comment On Pricing of Liquidity Risks: Evidence from Multiple Liquidity Measures by Soon-Ho Kim and Kuan-Hui Lee, Journal of Empirical Finance

More information

Commonality in Liquidity of UK Equity Markets: Evidence from the Recent Financial Crisis

Commonality in Liquidity of UK Equity Markets: Evidence from the Recent Financial Crisis Commonality in Liquidity of UK Equity Markets: Evidence from the Recent Financial Crisis Andros Gregoriou Bournemouth Business School University of Bournemouth BH12 5BB Christos Ioannidis * Economics Department

More information

CFDs and Liquidity Provision

CFDs and Liquidity Provision 2011 International Conference on Financial Management and Economics IPEDR vol.11 (2011) (2011) IACSIT Press, Singapore CFDs and Liquidity Provision Andrew Lepone and Jin Young Yang Discipline of Finance,

More information

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? International Review of Economics and Finance 9 (2000) 387 415 Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? Mathias Binswanger* Institute for Economics and the Environment, University

More information

Liquidity Externalities and Adverse Selection: Evidence from Trading after Hours

Liquidity Externalities and Adverse Selection: Evidence from Trading after Hours THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LIX, NO. 2 APRIL 2004 Liquidity Externalities and Adverse Selection: Evidence from Trading after Hours MICHAEL J. BARCLAY and TERRENCE HENDERSHOTT ABSTRACT This paper examines

More information

Liquidity in the Foreign Exchange Market: Measurement, Commonality, and Risk Premiums

Liquidity in the Foreign Exchange Market: Measurement, Commonality, and Risk Premiums Liquidity in the Foreign Exchange Market: Measurement, Commonality, and Risk Premiums Loriano Mancini Swiss Finance Institute and EPFL Angelo Ranaldo University of St. Gallen Jan Wrampelmeyer University

More information

Liquidity Determinants in an Order-Driven Market : Using High Frequency Data from the Saudi Market

Liquidity Determinants in an Order-Driven Market : Using High Frequency Data from the Saudi Market 2011 International Conference on Economics, Trade and Development IPEDR vol.7 (2011) (2011) IACSIT Press, Singapore Liquidity Determinants in an Order-Driven Market : Using High Frequency Data from the

More information

THE IMPACT OF LIQUIDITY PROVIDERS ON THE BALTIC STOCK EXCHANGE

THE IMPACT OF LIQUIDITY PROVIDERS ON THE BALTIC STOCK EXCHANGE RĪGAS EKONOMIKAS AUGSTSKOLA STOCKHOLM SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS IN RIGA Bachelor Thesis THE IMPACT OF LIQUIDITY PROVIDERS ON THE BALTIC STOCK EXCHANGE Authors: Kristīne Grečuhina Marija Timofejeva Supervisor:

More information

Limited attention and the allocation of effort in securities trading

Limited attention and the allocation of effort in securities trading Limited attention and the allocation of effort in securities trading Shane A. Corwin a, *, Jay F. Coughenour b a Mendoza College of Business, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556 b Lerner College

More information

Specialist Profits and the Minimum Price Increment

Specialist Profits and the Minimum Price Increment Specialist Profits and the Minimum Price Increment Jay F. Coughenour Lawrence E. Harris * September 30, 2003 * Jay Coughenour is from the University of Delaware. Larry Harris is the Chief Economist of

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996 Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996 THE USE OF FINANCIAL RATIOS AS MEASURES OF RISK IN THE DETERMINATION OF THE BID-ASK SPREAD Huldah A. Ryan * Abstract The effect

More information

Trade Size and the Adverse Selection Component of. the Spread: Which Trades Are "Big"?

Trade Size and the Adverse Selection Component of. the Spread: Which Trades Are Big? Trade Size and the Adverse Selection Component of the Spread: Which Trades Are "Big"? Frank Heflin Krannert Graduate School of Management Purdue University West Lafayette, IN 47907-1310 USA 765-494-3297

More information

THE INTRADAY PATTERN OF INFORMATION ASYMMETRY: EVIDENCE FROM THE NYSE

THE INTRADAY PATTERN OF INFORMATION ASYMMETRY: EVIDENCE FROM THE NYSE THE INTRADAY PATTERN OF INFORMATION ASYMMETRY: EVIDENCE FROM THE NYSE A Thesis Submitted to The College of Graduate Studies and Research in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master

More information

Informed Trading and Option Spreads

Informed Trading and Option Spreads Informed Trading and Option Spreads Gautam Kaul Michigan Business School Ann Arbor, MI 48109 Email: kaul@umich.edu PH. (734) 764-9594. M. Nimalendran Warrington College of Business University of Florida

More information

Short sales constraints and stock price behavior: evidence from the Taiwan Stock Exchange

Short sales constraints and stock price behavior: evidence from the Taiwan Stock Exchange Feng-Yu Lin (Taiwan), Cheng-Yi Chien (Taiwan), Day-Yang Liu (Taiwan), Yen-Sheng Huang (Taiwan) Short sales constraints and stock price behavior: evidence from the Taiwan Stock Exchange Abstract This paper

More information

Liquidity and Autocorrelations in Individual Stock Returns

Liquidity and Autocorrelations in Individual Stock Returns THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXI, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2006 Liquidity and Autocorrelations in Individual Stock Returns DORON AVRAMOV, TARUN CHORDIA, and AMIT GOYAL ABSTRACT This paper documents a strong relationship

More information

THE NUMBER OF TRADES AND STOCK RETURNS

THE NUMBER OF TRADES AND STOCK RETURNS THE NUMBER OF TRADES AND STOCK RETURNS Yi Tang * and An Yan Current version: March 2013 Abstract In the paper, we study the predictive power of number of weekly trades on ex-post stock returns. A higher

More information

Yao Zheng University of New Orleans. Eric Osmer University of New Orleans

Yao Zheng University of New Orleans. Eric Osmer University of New Orleans ABSTRACT The pricing of China Region ETFs - an empirical analysis Yao Zheng University of New Orleans Eric Osmer University of New Orleans Using a sample of exchange-traded funds (ETFs) that focus on investing

More information

The Shrinking New York Stock Exchange Floor. and the Hybrid Market

The Shrinking New York Stock Exchange Floor. and the Hybrid Market The Shrinking New York Stock Exchange Floor and the Hybrid Market Terrence Hendershott Pamela C. Moulton * April 11, 2008 * Hendershott is at Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley

More information

Volatility in the Overnight Money-Market Rate

Volatility in the Overnight Money-Market Rate 5 Volatility in the Overnight Money-Market Rate Allan Bødskov Andersen, Economics INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY This article analyses the day-to-day fluctuations in the Danish overnight money-market rate during

More information

Should Exchanges impose Market Maker obligations? Amber Anand. Kumar Venkataraman. Abstract

Should Exchanges impose Market Maker obligations? Amber Anand. Kumar Venkataraman. Abstract Should Exchanges impose Market Maker obligations? Amber Anand Kumar Venkataraman Abstract We study the trades of two important classes of market makers, Designated Market Makers (DMMs) and Endogenous Liquidity

More information

Liquidity in U.S. Treasury spot and futures markets

Liquidity in U.S. Treasury spot and futures markets Liquidity in U.S. Treasury spot and futures markets Michael Fleming and Asani Sarkar* Federal Reserve Bank of New York 33 Liberty Street New York, NY 10045 (212) 720-6372 (Fleming) (212) 720-8943 (Sarkar)

More information

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange

LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING. Evidence for the London Stock Exchange LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICING Evidence for the London Stock Exchange Timo Hubers (358022) Bachelor thesis Bachelor Bedrijfseconomie Tilburg University May 2012 Supervisor: M. Nie MSc Table of Contents Chapter

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

Market Predictability and Non-Informational Trading

Market Predictability and Non-Informational Trading Market Predictability and Non-Informational Trading Terrence Hendershott U.C. Berkeley Mark S. Seasholes HKUST This Version: 11-Mar-2009 Abstract This paper studies the ability of non-informational order

More information

Are Market Center Trading Cost Measures Reliable? *

Are Market Center Trading Cost Measures Reliable? * JEL Classification: G19 Keywords: equities, trading costs, liquidity Are Market Center Trading Cost Measures Reliable? * Ryan GARVEY Duquesne University, Pittsburgh (Garvey@duq.edu) Fei WU International

More information

The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us?

The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us? The (implicit) cost of equity trading at the Oslo Stock Exchange. What does the data tell us? Bernt Arne Ødegaard Sep 2008 Abstract We empirically investigate the costs of trading equity at the Oslo Stock

More information

Forgery, market liquidity, and demat trading: Evidence from the National Stock Exchange in India

Forgery, market liquidity, and demat trading: Evidence from the National Stock Exchange in India Forgery, market liquidity, and demat trading: Evidence from the National Stock Exchange in India Madhav S. Aney and Sanjay Banerji October 30, 2015 Abstract We analyse the impact of the establishment of

More information

Market Crashes and Institutional Trading

Market Crashes and Institutional Trading Market Crashes and Institutional Trading Amber Anand Syracuse University Paul Irvine University of Georgia Andy Puckett University of Tennessee Kumar Venkataraman Southern Methodist University Abstract

More information

Market Microstructure. Hans R. Stoll. Owen Graduate School of Management Vanderbilt University Nashville, TN 37203 Hans.Stoll@Owen.Vanderbilt.

Market Microstructure. Hans R. Stoll. Owen Graduate School of Management Vanderbilt University Nashville, TN 37203 Hans.Stoll@Owen.Vanderbilt. Market Microstructure Hans R. Stoll Owen Graduate School of Management Vanderbilt University Nashville, TN 37203 Hans.Stoll@Owen.Vanderbilt.edu Financial Markets Research Center Working paper Nr. 01-16

More information

Autocorrelation in Daily Stock Returns

Autocorrelation in Daily Stock Returns Autocorrelation in Daily Stock Returns ANÓNIO CERQUEIRA ABSRAC his paper examines the roles of spread and gradual incorporation of common information in the explanation of the autocorrelation in daily

More information

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation

B.3. Robustness: alternative betas estimation Appendix B. Additional empirical results and robustness tests This Appendix contains additional empirical results and robustness tests. B.1. Sharpe ratios of beta-sorted portfolios Fig. B1 plots the Sharpe

More information

THE EFFECTS OF STOCK LENDING ON SECURITY PRICES: AN EXPERIMENT

THE EFFECTS OF STOCK LENDING ON SECURITY PRICES: AN EXPERIMENT THE EFFECTS OF STOCK LENDING ON SECURITY PRICES: AN EXPERIMENT Steve Kaplan Toby Moskowitz Berk Sensoy November, 2011 MOTIVATION: WHAT IS THE IMPACT OF SHORT SELLING ON SECURITY PRICES? Does shorting make

More information

Liquidity Commonality and Pricing in UK Equities

Liquidity Commonality and Pricing in UK Equities Liquidity Commonality and Pricing in UK Equities Jason Foran*, Mark C. Hutchinson** and Niall O Sullivan*** January 2015 Forthcoming in Research in International Business and Finance Abstract We investigate

More information

Financial Market Microstructure Theory

Financial Market Microstructure Theory The Microstructure of Financial Markets, de Jong and Rindi (2009) Financial Market Microstructure Theory Based on de Jong and Rindi, Chapters 2 5 Frank de Jong Tilburg University 1 Determinants of the

More information

A Simple Way to Estimate Bid-Ask Spreads from Daily High and Low Prices

A Simple Way to Estimate Bid-Ask Spreads from Daily High and Low Prices A Simple Way to Estimate Bid-Ask Spreads from Daily High and Low Prices Shane A. Corwin and Paul Schultz * * Both authors are from the Mendoza College of Business at the University of Notre Dame. We are

More information

An Empirical Analysis of the Relation Between Option Market Liquidity and Stock Market Activity

An Empirical Analysis of the Relation Between Option Market Liquidity and Stock Market Activity An Empirical Analysis of the Relation Between Option Market Liquidity and Stock Market Activity Iskra Kalodera Christian Schlag This version: November 25, 2003 Graduate Program Finance and Monetary Economics,

More information

The Effect of Short-selling Restrictions on Liquidity: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange

The Effect of Short-selling Restrictions on Liquidity: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange The Effect of Short-selling Restrictions on Liquidity: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange Matthew Clifton ab and Mark Snape ac a Capital Markets Cooperative Research Centre 1 b University of Technology,

More information

Liquidity of Corporate Bonds

Liquidity of Corporate Bonds Liquidity of Corporate Bonds Jack Bao, Jun Pan and Jiang Wang MIT October 21, 2008 The Q-Group Autumn Meeting Liquidity and Corporate Bonds In comparison, low levels of trading in corporate bond market

More information

Master Programme in Finance Master Essay I

Master Programme in Finance Master Essay I Master Programme in Finance Master Essay I Volume of Trading and Stock Volatility in the Swedish Market May 2012 Erla Maria Gudmundsdottir Supervisors: Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Abstract Recent

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending Lamont Black* Indiana University Federal Reserve Board of Governors November 2006 ABSTRACT: This paper analyzes empirically the

More information

Sell-Side Illiquidity and Expected Stock Returns

Sell-Side Illiquidity and Expected Stock Returns Sell-side Illiquidity and the Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns Michael J. Brennan Tarun Chordia Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Qing Tong March 14, 2009 Brennan is from the Anderson School at UCLA and the

More information

An Application of the High-Low Spread Estimator to Intraday Data

An Application of the High-Low Spread Estimator to Intraday Data An Application of the High-Low Spread Estimator to Intraday Data Shane A. Corwin and Paul Schultz February 2009 Corwin and Schultz (2009) derive an estimator for the bid-ask spread based on daily high

More information

Trading Game Invariance in the TAQ Dataset

Trading Game Invariance in the TAQ Dataset Trading Game Invariance in the TAQ Dataset Albert S. Kyle Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland akyle@rhsmith.umd.edu Anna A. Obizhaeva Robert H. Smith School of Business University

More information

Endogenous Tick Sizes, Bid-Ask Spreads, Depth, and Trading Volumes: The Evidence on the Stock Exchange of Thailand

Endogenous Tick Sizes, Bid-Ask Spreads, Depth, and Trading Volumes: The Evidence on the Stock Exchange of Thailand Endogenous Tick Sizes, Bid-Ask Spreads, Depth, and Trading Volumes: The Evidence on the Stock Exchange of Thailand Kulpatra Sirodom Department of Finance, Thammasat Business School, Thammasat University,

More information

Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity. Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds

Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity. Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds Online Appendix to Impatient Trading, Liquidity Provision, and Stock Selection by Mutual Funds Zhi Da, Pengjie Gao, and Ravi Jagannathan This Draft: April 10, 2010 Correspondence: Zhi Da, Finance Department,

More information

Competition Among Market Centers

Competition Among Market Centers Competition Among Market Centers Marc L. Lipson* University of Virginia November, 2004 * Contact information: Darden Graduate School of Business, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, VA 22901; 434-924-4837;

More information

Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings. Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden

Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings. Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden Stock Prices and Institutional Holdings Adri De Ridder Gotland University, SE-621 67 Visby, Sweden This version: May 2008 JEL Classification: G14, G32 Keywords: Stock Price Levels, Ownership structure,

More information

Nasdaq Trading and Trading Costs: 1993 2002

Nasdaq Trading and Trading Costs: 1993 2002 The Financial Review 40 (2005) 281--304 Nasdaq Trading and Trading Costs: 1993 2002 Bonnie F. Van Ness University of Mississippi Robert A. Van Ness University of Mississippi Richard S. Warr North Carolina

More information

Selection Biases and Cross-Market Trading Cost Comparisons*

Selection Biases and Cross-Market Trading Cost Comparisons* Selection Biases and Cross-Market Trading Cost Comparisons* Hendrik Bessembinder Blaine Huntsman Chair in Finance David Eccles School of Business University of Utah e-mail: finhb@business.utah.edu May

More information

The Foreign Exchange Market Not As Liquid As You May Think

The Foreign Exchange Market Not As Liquid As You May Think 06.09.2012 Seite 1 / 5 The Foreign Exchange Market Not As Liquid As You May Think September 6 2012 1 23 AM GMT By Loriano Mancini Angelo Ranaldo and Jan Wrampelmeyer The foreign exchange market facilitates

More information

Trading Activity and Stock Price Volatility: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange

Trading Activity and Stock Price Volatility: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange Trading Activity and Stock Price Volatility: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange Roger D. Huang Mendoza College of Business University of Notre Dame and Ronald W. Masulis* Owen Graduate School of Management

More information

Decimalization and competition among stock markets: Evidence from the Toronto Stock Exchange cross-listed securities

Decimalization and competition among stock markets: Evidence from the Toronto Stock Exchange cross-listed securities Journal of Financial Markets 1 (1998) 51 87 Decimalization and competition among stock markets: Evidence from the Toronto Stock Exchange cross-listed securities Hee-Joon Ahn, Charles Q. Cao *, Hyuk Choe

More information

A More Informed Picture of Market Liquidity In the U.S. Corporate Bond Market

A More Informed Picture of Market Liquidity In the U.S. Corporate Bond Market MARKETAXESS ON MARKETAXESS BID-ASK SPREAD INDEX (BASI) A More Informed Picture of Market Liquidity In the U.S. Corporate Bond Market MARKETAXESS ON MARKETAXESS ON is a forum for thought leadership and

More information

The Effects of Transaction Costs on Stock Prices and Trading Volume*

The Effects of Transaction Costs on Stock Prices and Trading Volume* JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION 7, 130 150 (1998) ARTICLE NO. JF980238 The Effects of Transaction Costs on Stock Prices and Trading Volume* Michael J. Barclay University of Rochester, Rochester, New

More information

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Joseph Chen University of Southern California Harrison Hong Stanford University Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) document individual stock momentum:

More information

Fixed odds bookmaking with stochastic betting demands

Fixed odds bookmaking with stochastic betting demands Fixed odds bookmaking with stochastic betting demands Stewart Hodges Hao Lin January 4, 2009 Abstract This paper provides a model of bookmaking in the market for bets in a British horse race. The bookmaker

More information

LIQUIDITY AND TRADING ACTIVITY OF EQUITY OPTIONS: TIME SERIES AND HEDGING COST EFFECTS

LIQUIDITY AND TRADING ACTIVITY OF EQUITY OPTIONS: TIME SERIES AND HEDGING COST EFFECTS LIQUIDITY AND TRADING ACTIVITY OF EQUITY OPTIONS: TIME SERIES AND HEDGING COST EFFECTS Thanos Verousis 1 and Owain ap Gwilym Bangor Business School, Bangor University, Bangor, LL57 2DG, UK. Abstract: This

More information

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in financial markets. For this purpose we examine the relationship between

More information

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle

Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Internet Appendix to Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Randi Næs, Johannes A. Skjeltorp and Bernt Arne Ødegaard This Internet appendix contains additional material to the paper Stock Market

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Market Fragmentation on U.S. Equities Markets

An Empirical Analysis of Market Fragmentation on U.S. Equities Markets An Empirical Analysis of Market Fragmentation on U.S. Equities Markets Frank Hatheway The NASDAQ OMX Group, Inc. Amy Kwan The University of Sydney Capital Markets Cooperative Research Center Hui Zheng*

More information

Program Trading and Intraday Volatility

Program Trading and Intraday Volatility Program Trading and Intraday Volatility Lawrence Harris University of Southern California George Sofianos James E. Shapiro New York Stock Exchange, Inc. Program trading and intraday changes in the S&P

More information

Symposium on market microstructure: Focus on Nasdaq

Symposium on market microstructure: Focus on Nasdaq Journal of Financial Economics 45 (1997) 3 8 Symposium on market microstructure: Focus on Nasdaq G. William Schwert William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Rochester,

More information

Order handling rules, tick size, and the intraday pattern of bid}ask spreads for Nasdaq stocks

Order handling rules, tick size, and the intraday pattern of bid}ask spreads for Nasdaq stocks Journal of Financial Markets 4 (2001) 143}161 Order handling rules, tick size, and the intraday pattern of bid}ask spreads for Nasdaq stocks Kee H. Chung*, Robert A. Van Ness School of Management, Department

More information

Conflict of Interest and Execution Quality of Futures Floor Traders

Conflict of Interest and Execution Quality of Futures Floor Traders Conflict of Interest and Execution Quality of Futures Floor Traders Asani Sarkar The Federal Reserve Bank of New York Research Department 33 Liberty Street New York, NY 10045 212-720-8943 Fax: 212-720-1582

More information

ARE TEENIES BETTER? ABSTRACT

ARE TEENIES BETTER? ABSTRACT NICOLAS P.B. BOLLEN * ROBERT E. WHALEY * ARE TEENIES BETTER? ABSTRACT On June 5 th, 1997, the NYSE voted to adopt a system of decimal price quoting, changing its longstanding practice of using 1/8 th s.

More information

Short Selling Bans around the World: Evidence from the 2007-09 Crisis

Short Selling Bans around the World: Evidence from the 2007-09 Crisis Short Selling Bans around the World: Evidence from the 2007-09 Crisis Alessandro Beber Cass Business School and CEPR Marco Pagano University of Naples Federico II, CSEF, EIEF and CEPR February, 2011 Motivation

More information

Discussion of The competitive effects of US decimalization: Evidence from the US-listed Canadian stocks by Oppenheimer and Sabherwal

Discussion of The competitive effects of US decimalization: Evidence from the US-listed Canadian stocks by Oppenheimer and Sabherwal Journal of Banking & Finance 27 (2003) 1911 1916 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Discussion Discussion of The competitive effects of US decimalization: Evidence from the US-listed Canadian stocks by Oppenheimer

More information

How Much Equity Does the Government Hold?

How Much Equity Does the Government Hold? How Much Equity Does the Government Hold? Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley and NBER January 2004 This paper was presented at the 2004 Meetings of the American Economic Association. I

More information

STOCK MARKET VOLATILITY AND REGIME SHIFTS IN RETURNS

STOCK MARKET VOLATILITY AND REGIME SHIFTS IN RETURNS STOCK MARKET VOLATILITY AND REGIME SHIFTS IN RETURNS Chia-Shang James Chu Department of Economics, MC 0253 University of Southern California Los Angles, CA 90089 Gary J. Santoni and Tung Liu Department

More information

Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle

Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle Stock Market Liquidity and the Business Cycle RANDI NÆS, JOHANNES A. SKJELTORP, and BERNT ARNE ØDEGAARD ABSTRACT In the recent financial crisis we saw liquidity in the stock market drying up as a precursor

More information

Does Market Structure Affect the Immediacy of Stock Price Responses to News?

Does Market Structure Affect the Immediacy of Stock Price Responses to News? Does Market Structure Affect the Immediacy of Stock Price Responses to News? Ronald W. Masulis Owen Graduate School of Management Vanderbilt University Nashville, TN 37203 (615) 322-3687 Lakshmanan Shivakumar

More information

Informed trading in options market and stock return predictability

Informed trading in options market and stock return predictability Informed trading in options market and stock return predictability Abstract Prior research has highlighted the importance of two distinct types of informed trading in options market: trading on price direction

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports How Do Treasury Dealers Manage Their Positions? Michael J. Fleming Joshua V. Rosenberg Staff Report no. 299 August 2007 Revised March 2008 This paper presents

More information

Crisis Alpha and Risk in Alternative Investment Strategies

Crisis Alpha and Risk in Alternative Investment Strategies Crisis Alpha and Risk in Alternative Investment Strategies KATHRYN M. KAMINSKI, PHD, RPM RISK & PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT AB ALEXANDER MENDE, PHD, RPM RISK & PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT AB INTRODUCTION The investment

More information

Trading Costs and Taxes!

Trading Costs and Taxes! Trading Costs and Taxes! Aswath Damodaran Aswath Damodaran! 1! The Components of Trading Costs! Brokerage Cost: This is the most explicit of the costs that any investor pays but it is usually the smallest

More information

Betting Against Beta

Betting Against Beta Betting Against Beta Andrea Frazzini AQR Capital Management LLC Lasse H. Pedersen NYU, CEPR, and NBER Preliminary Copyright 2010 by Andrea Frazzini and Lasse H. Pedersen Motivation Background: Security

More information

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS By Benjamin M. Blau 1, Abdullah Masud 2, and Ryan J. Whitby 3 Abstract: Xiong and Idzorek (2011) show that extremely

More information

Specialist Performance and New Listing Allocations on the NYSE: An Empirical Analysis

Specialist Performance and New Listing Allocations on the NYSE: An Empirical Analysis Specialist Performance and New Listing Allocations on the NYSE: An Empirical Analysis Shane A. Corwin * Department of Finance 240 Mendoza College of Business University of Notre Dame Notre Dame, IN 46556

More information

Noise trading and the price formation process

Noise trading and the price formation process Available online at www.sciencedirect.com Journal of Empirical Finance 15 (2008) 232 250 www.elsevier.com/locate/jempfin Noise trading and the price formation process Henk Berkman a,, Paul D. Koch b a

More information