Bank Liquidity Creation, Monetary Policy, and Financial Crises

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Bank Liquidity Creation, Monetary Policy, and Financial Crises"

Transcription

1 Bank Liquidity Creation, Monetary Policy, and Financial Crises Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina, Wharton Financial Institutions Center, and CentER Tilburg University Christa H.S. Bouwman MIT Sloan School of Management (visiting), Wharton Financial Institutions Center, and Case Western Reserve University July 2009 We study the relationship between aggregate bank liquidity creation and monetary policy in the U.S. from 1984:Q1 to 2008:Q4 by first examining the effectiveness of monetary policy during normal times and financial crises, and by then analyzing the behavior of both monetary policy and liquidity creation around financial crises. Our main findings are as follows. First, liquidity creation has increased substantially over the sample period, from $1.398 trillion to $5.304 trillion (in real 2008:Q4 dollars). The share of large banks (assets over $3 billion) in aggregate liquidity creation has also gone up over this time period, as has the fraction of liquidity created off the balance sheet. Second, the effect of monetary policy on bank liquidity creation is significant only for small banks, and additional interesting size-dependent differences appear after splitting liquidity creation into on- and offbalance sheet components. There appears to be no significant difference between the effects of monetary policy on liquidity creation during normal times and financial crises. If the Federal Reserve had used the Taylor rule, liquidity creation would have been similar during normal times, but higher during financial crises, and would have resulted in a 3.3% increase in liquidity creation over the sample period. Third, detrended liquidity creation is relatively high prior to financial crises, tends to drop significantly during financial crises and stays low afterwards. The data suggest that the level of detrended liquidity creation is a better indicator of a crisis occurring than detrended GDP, the federal funds rate, or the return on the stock market. The predicted probability of a crisis striking was only 0.02% when detrended liquidity creation was at its lowest point over the sample period, and 79.5% when detrended liquidity creation was at its highest point. Fourth, we find that the subprime lending crisis has made monetary policy more effective for small banks, less effective for medium banks, and equally effective for large banks, and left undisturbed the result that monetary policy has no different effect during normal times and crises. In addition, the high level of detrended liquidity creation before the crisis was far more pronounced than that before other financial crises, and it was driven by a high level of off-balance sheet illiquid guarantees (primarily loan commitments). When the crisis hit, illiquid assets (primarily business loans) increased for several quarters before declining. During the crisis, the drop in illiquid guarantees was far more pronounced than the drop in illiquid assets, and contributed significantly to the decline in detrended liquidity creation. Contact details: Moore School of Business, University of South Carolina, 1705 College Street, Columbia, SC Tel: Fax: aberger@moore.sc.edu. On leave from Case Western Reserve University. Contact details: MIT Sloan School of Management, 77 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge MA Tel: Fax: cbouwman@mit.edu. Keywords: Financial Crises, Liquidity Creation, and Banking. JEL Classification: G28, and G21. This is a significantly expanded version of the first part of an earlier paper, Financial Crises and Bank Liquidity Creation. The authors thank Bob DeYoung, John Driscoll, Bill English, Paolo Fulghieri, Thomas Kick, Loretta Mester, Steven Ongena, Bruno Parigi, Peter Ritchken, David Romer, Asani Sarkar, Klaus Schaeck, Greg Udell, Todd Vermilyea, Egon Zakrajsek, and participants at presentations at the CREI / JFI / CEPR Conference on Financial Crises at Pompeu Fabra, the Philadelphia Federal Reserve, the San Francisco Federal Reserve, the Cleveland Federal Reserve, the International Monetary Fund, the Summer Research Conference in Finance at the ISB in Hyderabad, the Unicredit Conference on Banking and Finance, the University of Kansas Southwind Finance Conference, Erasmus University, and Tilburg University for useful comments. We are indebted to Christopher Crowe for providing us with monetary policy shock data.

2 Bank Liquidity Creation, Monetary Policy, and Financial Crises 1. Introduction Over the past quarter century, the U.S. has experienced a number of financial crises. At the heart of these financial crises are often issues surrounding liquidity provision by the banking sector (e.g., Acharya, Shin, and Yorulmazer 2009). For example, in the current subprime lending crisis, liquidity seemed to have dried up for an extended time period. The practical importance of liquidity during financial crises is buttressed by financial intermediation theory, which indicates that the creation of liquidity is an important reason why banks exist. 1 Early contributions argue that banks create liquidity by financing relatively illiquid assets such as business loans with relatively liquid liabilities such as transactions deposits (e.g., Bryant 1980, Diamond and Dybvig 1983). More recent contributions suggest that banks also create liquidity off the balance sheet through loan commitments and similar claims to liquid funds (e.g., Holmstrom and Tirole 1998, Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein 2002). 2 The creation of liquidity makes banks fragile and susceptible to runs (e.g., Diamond and Dybvig 1983, Chari and Jagannathan 1988), and such runs can lead to financial crises via contagion effects. Such crises can affect the real economy if they rupture the creation of liquidity (e.g., Dell Ariccia, Detragiache, and Rajan 2008). 3 Because of the importance of liquidity provision by banks to the real economy, the central bank s monetary policy seeks to counter the effects of negative liquidity shocks. According to the bank lending channel literature, monetary policy may affect bank lending and deposits (for survey papers on this, see Bernanke and Gertler 1995, Kashyap and Stein 1997). Moreover, it may also affect off-balance sheet activities like loan commitments (e.g., Woodford 1996, Morgan 1998). It is plausible that the conduct of monetary policy varies across normal and financial crisis periods and that monetary policy affects and possibly interacts with aggregate liquidity creation by banks. Yet, we know little about the relationship 1 According to the theory, another central role of banks in the economy is to transform credit risk (e.g., Diamond 1984, Ramakrishnan and Thakor 1984, Boyd and Prescott 1986). Recently, Coval and Thakor (2005) theorize that banks may also arise in response to the behavior of irrational agents in financial markets. See Bhattacharya and Thakor (1993) and Freixas and Rochet (2008) for a summary of financial intermediary existence theories. 2 James (1981) and Boot, Thakor, and Udell (1991) endogenize the loan commitment contract due to informational frictions. The loan commitment contract is subsequently used in Holmstrom and Tirole (1998) and Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2002) to show how banks can provide liquidity to borrowers. 3 Acharya and Pedersen (2005) show that liquidity risk also affects the expected returns on stocks. 1

3 between monetary policy and bank liquidity creation, and particularly about how this relationship changes during and around financial crises. This paper seeks to fill this void in the literature. Since monetary policy potentially influences both sides of the bank s balance sheet as well as off-balance sheet activities, we use a comprehensive measure of bank liquidity creation that includes all on- and off-balance-sheet activities. Specifically, we address four broad questions. First, what has been the magnitude of liquidity creation (and some key components) by US banks of different size classes and how has this changed over time? Second, what has been the effect of monetary policy on aggregate bank liquidity creation, and does this effect differ in financial crises from normal times? Third, how have bank liquidity creation and monetary policy behaved during financial crises and in the periods immediately preceding and following those crises? Fourth, from the perspective of bank liquidity creation, how is the current subprime lending crisis different from other financial crises? To address these questions, our analyses use data on virtually all banks in the U.S. from 1984:Q1 2008:Q4. The sample period includes five financial crises: the 1987 stock market crash, the credit crunch of the early 1990s, the Russian debt crisis plus the Long-Term Capital Management meltdown in 1998, the bursting of the dot.com bubble plus the September 11 terrorist attack of the early 2000s, and the subprime lending crisis of 2007?. For our first question, we calculate the amount of liquidity created by the banking sector using Berger and Bouwman s (forthcoming) preferred liquidity creation measure. 4 This measure takes into account the fact that banks create liquidity both on and off the balance sheet and is constructed using a three-step procedure. In the first step, all bank assets, liabilities, equity, and off-balance sheet activities are classified as liquid, semi-liquid, or illiquid. This is done based on the ease, cost, and time for customers to obtain liquid funds from the bank, and the ease, cost, and time for banks to dispose of their obligations in order to meet these liquidity demands. In the second step, weights are assigned to these activities. The weights are consistent with the theory in that maximum liquidity is created when illiquid assets (e.g., business loans) are transformed into liquid liabilities (e.g., transactions deposits) and maximum liquidity is 4 While the preferred measure treats the securitizability of assets as fixed over time, we also construct an alternative liquidity creation measure (as in Berger and Bouwman forthcoming) that recognizes the fact that the ability to securitize assets has changed over time (see Section 4.2). 2

4 destroyed when liquid assets (e.g., treasuries) are transformed into illiquid liabilities (e.g., subordinated debt) or equity. In the third step, we combine the activities as classified in the first step and as weighted in the second step to construct a liquidity creation measure. We apply this measure to quarterly data on virtually all U.S. commercial and credit card banks from 1984:Q1 to 2008:Q4. The dollar amount of liquidity creation by these individual banks is added up to obtain aggregate liquidity creation by the banking sector. We find that liquidity creation has increased substantially over the sample period, from $1.398 trillion to $5.304 trillion (in real 2008:Q4 dollars), and that this growth has outpaced GDP growth in percentage terms over the same time period. The share of large banks in aggregate liquidity creation has also gone up over time, as has the fraction of liquidity created off the balance sheet. Turning to the second question, we examine the effect of monetary policy on aggregate bank liquidity creation during normal times and crisis periods by regressing the change in liquidity creation on the change in monetary policy, alternatively proxied by the change in the federal funds rate and Romer and Romer s (2004) monetary policy shocks, using several specifications. 5 We also address how the effect of monetary policy would have changed if the Federal Reserve had used the Taylor rule in setting the federal funds rate. Our main findings on this issue are that monetary policy seems to significantly affect liquidity creation only for small banks. Liquidity creation by large and medium banks (which create roughly 90% of aggregate bank liquidity) is mostly unaffected by monetary policy. There appears to be no significant difference between the effects of monetary policy on liquidity creation during normal times and financial crises. To the extent that monetary policy affects liquidity creation, the channel through which this effect occurs varies depending on bank size. Monetary policy seems to mostly affect on-balance sheet liquidity creation by small and medium banks, and off-balance sheet liquidity creation by large banks. However, the large-bank effect is positive, suggesting that increased demand for off-balance sheet guarantees outweighs any drop in supply caused by tightening monetary policy. Finally, we find that if the Federal Reserve had used the Taylor rule in conducting monetary policy, liquidity creation would have been similar during normal times, but higher during financial crises, and would have resulted in a 3.3% increase in liquidity 5 While Romer and Romer s (2004) monetary policy shock data ends in 1996:Q4, we use monetary policy shock data provided by Christopher Crowe (used in Barakchian and Crowe 2009) that covers our entire sample period. 3

5 creation over the sample period. To address the third question, we analyze the behavior of bank liquidity creation and monetary policy around financial crises. Since liquidity creation has grown considerably over time and also contains cyclical components, we do not focus on the actual dollar amount of liquidity creation for these analyses but follow an approach commonly used in the macroeconomics literature (e.g. Barro, 1997). Specifically, we first deseasonalize the data using the U.S. Census Bureau s X11 procedure, and then detrend it using the Hodrick Prescott (HP) filter. Henceforth, we call deseasonalized, detrended liquidity creation detrended liquidity creation for short. Our main results on this issue are that detrended liquidity creation is relatively high prior to financial crises, but tends to drop significantly during these crises and stays low afterwards. The federal funds rate is also often high prior to financial crises, but tends to fall as monetary policy generally loosens during the crises. Thus, detrended liquidity creation generally drops during financial crises despite loosened monetary policy. The high level of detrended liquidity creation that tends to precede financial crises suggests a possible dark side of bank liquidity creation. While financial fragility may be needed to induce banks to create liquidity (e.g., Diamond and Rajan 2000, 2001), our analysis raises the intriguing possibility that the causality may also be reversed in the sense that too much liquidity creation may lead to financial fragility. Results from logit regressions suggest that the level of detrended liquidity creation is significantly related to the probability of a crisis occurring one to four quarters hence. The predicted probability of a crisis striking is 0.02% when detrended liquidity creation is at its lowest point over the sample period, and it rises to 79.5% when detrended liquidity creation is at its highest point. In fact, our results show that detrended liquidity creation is a better indicator of a financial crisis than detrended GDP, the federal funds rate (monetary policy), or the return on the stock market. Finally, on the fourth question, we find that the subprime lending crisis has made monetary policy more effective for small banks, less effective for medium banks, and equally effective for large banks, and left undisturbed the result that monetary policy has no different effect during normal times and crises. Further differences, however, exist when we split liquidity creation into on- and off-balance sheet components. The behavior of detrended liquidity creation around the subprime lending crisis also differs in some important respects from previous financial crises. The high level of detrended liquidity creation 4

6 before the subprime lending crisis was driven by a high level of off-balance sheet illiquid guarantees (primarily loan commitments). When the crisis hit, illiquid assets (primarily business loans) increased for several quarters before declining. During the crisis, the drop in illiquid guarantees was far more pronounced than the drop in illiquid assets, and contributed significantly to the decline in detrended liquidity creation. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses some related literature. Section 3 describes the five financial crises. Section 4 explains the monetary policy and liquidity creation measures, discusses our sample, and presents summary statistics. Section 5 examines the relationship between monetary policy and bank liquidity creation during normal times and financial crises. Section 6 describes the behavior of aggregate bank liquidity creation and monetary policy before, during, and after financial crises, and draws some general conclusions. Section 7 concludes. 2. Related literature This paper is primarily related to two literatures. The first is the literature on financial crises. 6 One strand of this literature focuses on financial crises and fragility. Some papers analyze contagion, showing that a small liquidity shock in one area may have a contagious effect throughout the economy (e.g., Allen and Gale 1998, 2000). Other papers focus on the determinants of financial crises and their policy implications (e.g., Bordo, Eichengreen, Klingebiel, and Martinez-Peria 2001, Demirguc-Kunt, Detragiache, and Gupta 2006, Lorenzoni 2008, Claessens, Klingebiel, and Laeven forthcoming). A second strand examines the effect of financial crises on the real sector (e.g., Friedman and Schwarz 1963, Bernanke 1983, Bernanke and Gertler 1989, Dell Ariccia, Detragiache, and Rajan 2008, Shin forthcoming). These papers find that financial crises increase the cost of financing and reduce credit, which adversely affects investment and may lead to reduced growth and recessions. That is, financial crises have independent real effects (see Dell Ariccia, Detragiache, and Rajan 2008). In contrast to these papers, we examine how the amount of liquidity created by the banking sector behaved around financial crises in the U.S. The second literature to which this paper is related focuses on the effect of monetary policy on bank behavior. The credit channel literature hypothesizes two distinct mechanisms through which 6 Allen and Gale (2007) provide a detailed overview of the causes and consequences of financial crises. 5

7 monetary policy may affect real economic activity, of which the bank lending channel is most relevant for our paper. 7 According to the bank lending channel, a tightening of monetary policy may cause a decline in bank deposits, which lessens the amount of loanable funds available. The reason is that the decline in deposits may not be offset by increases in other sources of funds such as federal funds or large CDs, or deposits may have to be replaced by funds with higher marginal costs (e.g., Bernanke and Blinder 1992, Stein 1998). In this way, a monetary contraction may result in a reduced supply of bank credit. Additionally, an increase in market interest rates caused by a tightening of monetary policy reduces the present value of fixed-rate loans in a bank s portfolio, which causes a decline in the bank s net worth, thereby resulting in a reduction in bank credit supply, particularly for banks that are constrained by relatively low capital ratios. 8 Although the bank lending channel literature generally does not discuss offbalance sheet activities, it may be argued that a monetary policy tightening would also reduce the supply of loan commitments, letters of credit, and similar off-balance sheet guarantees, given that these are present commitments to lend in the future. Thus, it seems appropriate to use a bank liquidity creation measure that incorporates both sides of the balance sheet as well as off-balance sheet activities, like the Berger and Bouwman (forthcoming) measure used here. 3. Five financial crises This section describes five financial crises that occurred between 1984:Q1 and 2008:Q4. The crises include the 1987 stock market crash, the credit crunch of the early 1990s, the Russian debt crisis plus Long- Term Capital Management (LTCM) bailout of 1998, the bursting of the dot.com bubble and the September 11 terrorist attacks of the early 2000s, and the current subprime lending crisis. Financial crisis #1: Stock market crash (1987:Q4) On Monday, October 19, 1987, the stock market crashed, with the S&P500 index falling about 20%. During the years before the crash, the level of the stock market had increased dramatically, causing some 7 The second mechanism is the balance sheet channel, which argues that monetary tightening affects real activity because the associated higher interest rates impair collateral values or otherwise reduce the net worth of certain borrowers, thereby making them less creditworthy and diminishing their ability to obtain funds. For more details on both mechanisms, see the survey paper by Bernanke and Gertler (1995). 8 See also the survey paper by Kashyap and Stein (1997). 6

8 concern that the market had become overvalued. 9 A few days before the crash, two events occurred that may have helped precipitate the crash: 1) legislation was enacted to eliminate certain tax benefits associated with financing mergers; and 2) information was released that the trade deficit was above expectations. Both events seemed to have added to the selling pressure and a record trading volume on Oct. 19, in part caused by program trading, overwhelmed many systems. Financial crisis #2: Credit crunch (1990:Q1 1992:Q4) During the first three years of the 1990s, bank commercial and industrial lending declined in real terms, particularly for small banks and for small loans (see Berger, Kashyap, and Scalise 1995, Table 8, for details). The ascribed causes of the credit crunch include a fall in bank capital from the loan loss experiences of the late 1980s (e.g., Peek and Rosengren 1995), the increases in bank leverage requirements and implementation of Basel I risk-based capital standards during this time period (e.g., Berger and Udell 1994, Hancock, Laing, and Wilcox 1995, Thakor 1996), an increase in supervisory toughness evidenced in worse examination ratings for a given bank condition (e.g., Berger, Kyle, and Scalise 2001), and reduced loan demand because of macroeconomic and regional recessions (e.g., Bernanke and Lown 1991). The existing research provides some support for each of these hypotheses. Financial crisis #3: Russian debt crisis / LTCM bailout (1998:Q3 1998:Q4) Since its inception in March 1994, hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management ( LTCM ) followed an arbitrage strategy that was avowedly market neutral, designed to make money regardless of whether prices were rising or falling. When Russia defaulted on its sovereign debt on August 17, 1998, investors fled from other government paper to the safe haven of U.S. treasuries. This flight to liquidity caused an unexpected widening of spreads on supposedly low-risk portfolios. By the end of August 1998, LTCM s capital had dropped to $2.3 billion, less than 50% of its December 1997 value, with assets standing at $126 billion. In the first three weeks of September, LTCM s capital dropped further to $600 million without shrinking the portfolio. Banks began to doubt its ability to meet margin calls. To prevent a potential systemic meltdown triggered by the collapse of the world s largest hedge fund, the Federal Reserve Bank 9 E.g., Raging bull, stock market s surge is puzzling investors: When will it end? on page 1 of the Wall Street Journal, Jan. 19,

9 of New York organized a $3.5 billion bail-out by LTCM s major creditors on September 23, In 1998:Q4, several large banks had to take substantial write-offs as a result of losses on their investments. Financial crisis #4: Bursting of the dot.com bubble and Sept. 11 terrorist attack (2000:Q2 2002:Q3) The dot.com bubble was a speculative stock price bubble that was built up during the mid- to late-1990s. During this period, many internet-based companies, commonly referred to as dot.coms, were founded. Rapidly increasing stock prices and widely available venture capital created an environment in which many of these companies seemed to focus largely on increasing market share. At the height of the boom, many dot.com s were able to go public and raise substantial amounts of money even if they had never earned any profits, and in some cases had not even earned any revenues. On March 10, 2000, the Nasdaq composite index peaked at more than double its value just a year before. After the bursting of the bubble, many dot.com s ran out of capital and were acquired or filed for bankruptcy (examples of the latter include WorldCom and Pets.com). The U.S. economy started to slow down and business investments began falling. The September 11, 2001 terrorist attacks may have exacerbated the stock market downturn by adversely affecting investor sentiment. By 2002:Q3, the Nasdaq index had fallen by 78%, wiping out $5 trillion in market value of mostly technology firms. Financial crisis #5: Subprime lending crisis (2007:Q3?) The subprime lending crisis has been characterized by turmoil in financial markets as banks have experienced difficulty in selling loans in the syndicated loan market and in securitizing loans. According to press reports, banks also seem to be reluctant to provide credit: they appear to have cut back their lending to firms and individuals, and have also been reticent to lend to each other. Some banks have experienced substantial losses in capital. Massive losses at Countrywide resulted in a takeover by Bank of America. Bear Stearns suffered a fatal loss in confidence and was sold at a fire-sale price to J.P. Morgan Chase with the Federal Reserve guaranteeing $29 billion in potential losses. Washington Mutual, the sixth-largest bank, became the biggest bank failure in the U.S. financial history. J.P. Morgan Chase purchased the banking business while the rest of the organization filed for bankruptcy. IndyMac Bank was seized by the FDIC after it suffered substantive losses and depositors had started to run on the bank. The FDIC sold all 8

10 deposits and most of the assets to OneWest Bank, FSB. The Federal Reserve also intervened in some unprecedented ways in the market. It extended its safety-net privileges to investment banks and one insurance company (AIG) and began holding mortgage-backed securities and lending directly to investment banks. The Treasury set aside $250 billion out of its $700-billion bailout package (TARP program) to enhance capital ratios of selected banks. 4. Monetary policy measures, bank liquidity creation, and the sample This section first describes the two monetary policy measures, the change in the federal funds rate and Romer and Romer s monetary policy shocks, and provides summary statistics. It then explains Berger and Bouwman s (forthcoming) preferred and an alternative liquidity creation measure. Finally, it describes the sample and provides summary statistics Two monetary policy measures To examine the relationship between monetary policy and liquidity creation, we select two monetary policy measures. The first measure is the federal funds rate. Since the Federal Reserve explicitly targeted the federal funds rate over our entire sample period (see Romer and Romer 2004), the change in the federal funds rate measures the change in monetary policy. 10 A drawback of this measure, however, is that it may contain anticipatory movements. That is, movements in the federal funds rate may respond to information about future developments in the economy, making it harder to isolate the effect of monetary policy on bank output. The second measure takes into account such endogeneity. Our second (change in) monetary policy measure is a monetary policy shock measure developed by Romer and Romer (2004). As a first step to construct this measure, the intended federal funds rate changes around meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the institution responsible for setting monetary policy in the U.S., are obtained by examining narrative accounts of each FOMC meeting. Next, anticipatory movements are removed by regressing the intended federal funds rate on the Federal Reserve s internal forecasts of inflation and real activity. The residuals from this regression are the monetary policy shocks, i.e., the changes in the intended federal funds rate that are not made in response to forecasts of 10 We use the actual federal funds rate (as in Romer and Romer 2004) rather than the target federal funds rate since bank behavior will be affected most by the actual rate. 9

11 future economic conditions. While Romer and Romer s (2004) monetary policy shock data ends in 1996:Q4, Barakchian and Crowe (2009) extend this data through 2008:Q2, and Crowe provides a further extension to 2008:Q4. 11 Figure 1 shows the change in the federal funds rate (Panel A) and the Romer and Romer monetary policy shocks (Panel B) over time. The broad movements in the two series tend to be similar, but differences do exist. For example, if the Federal Reserve lowers interest rates by less than it normally would based on its internal forecasts of low inflation and sluggish growth, monetary loosening based on the change in the federal funds rate coincides with monetary tightening based on the monetary policy shock data Bank liquidity creation: preferred and alternative measure To construct a measure of liquidity creation, we follow Berger and Bouwman s (forthcoming) three-step procedure (see Table 1). Below, we briefly discuss these three steps. In Step 1, we classify all bank activities (assets, liabilities, equity, and off-balance sheet activities) as liquid, semi-liquid, or illiquid. For assets, this is based on the ease, cost, and time for banks to dispose of their obligations in order to meet these liquidity demands. For liabilities and equity, this is based on the ease, cost, and time for customers to obtain liquid funds from the bank. We follow a similar approach for off-balance sheet activities, classifying them based on functionally similar on-balance sheet activities. For all activities other than loans, this classification process uses information on both product category and maturity. Due to data restrictions, we classify loans entirely by category. In Step 2, we assign weights to all the bank activities classified in Step 1. The weights are consistent with liquidity creation theory, which argues that banks create liquidity on the balance sheet when they transform illiquid assets into liquid liabilities. We therefore apply positive weights to illiquid assets and liquid liabilities. Following similar logic, we apply negative weights to liquid assets and illiquid liabilities and equity, since banks destroy liquidity when they use illiquid liabilities to finance liquid assets. We use weights of ½ and -½, because only half of the total amount of liquidity created is attributable to the source or use of funds alone. For example, when $1 of liquid liabilities is used to finance $1 in illiquid 11 We are grateful to Christopher Crowe for making this data available to us. 10

12 assets, liquidity creation equals ½ * $1 + ½ * $1 = $1. In this case, maximum liquidity is created. However, when $1 of liquid liabilities is used to finance $1 in liquid assets, liquidity creation equals ½ * $1 + -½ * $1 = $0. In this case, no liquidity is created as the bank holds items of approximately the same liquidity as those it gives to the nonbank public. Maximum liquidity is destroyed when $1 of illiquid liabilities or equity is used to finance $1 of liquid assets. In this case, liquidity creation equals -½ * $1 + -½ * $1 = -$1. An intermediate weight of 0 is applied to semi-liquid assets and liabilities. Weights for off-balance sheet activities are assigned using the same principles. In Step 3, we combine the activities as classified in Step 1 and as weighted in Step 2 to construct Berger and Bouwman s (forthcoming) preferred liquidity creation measure. This measure classifies loans by category, while all activities other than loans are classified using information on product category and maturity, and includes off-balance sheet activities. 12 To obtain the dollar amount of liquidity creation at a particular bank, we multiply the weights of ½, -½, or 0, respectively, times the dollar amounts of the corresponding bank activities and add the weighted dollar amounts. Since the ability to securitize assets has changed greatly over time, we also construct an alternative liquidity creation measure as in Berger and Bouwman (forthcoming). This measure is identical to the preferred measure, except for the way we classify loans. For each loan category, we use U.S. Flow of Funds data on the total amount of loans outstanding and the total amount of loans securitized to calculate the fraction of loans that has been securitized in the market at each point in time. Following Loutskina (2006), we then assume that each bank can securitize that fraction of its own loans. To give an example, in 1993:Q4, $3.1 trillion in residential real estate loans were outstanding in the market, and 48.4% of these loans were securitized. If a bank has $10 million in residential real estate loans in that quarter, we assume that 48.4% thereof can be securitized. Hence, we classify $4.84 million of these loans as semi-liquid and the remainder as illiquid. Note that this alternative measure faces a significant drawback. While the theories suggest that the ability to securitize matters for liquidity creation, this measure uses the actual amount of securitization. Thus, while the vast majority of these residential real estate loans may be securitizable, this alternative measure treats only about half of them as such. 12 Berger and Bouwman (forthcoming) construct four liquidity creation measures by alternatively classifying loans by category or maturity, and by alternatively including or excluding off-balance sheet activities. However, they argue that the measure we use here is the preferred measure since for liquidity creation, banks ability to securitize or sell loans is more important than loan maturity, and banks do create liquidity both on and off the balance sheet. 11

13 We provide descriptive statistics on the preferred and the alternative liquidity creation measures in Section 4.4. Since we obtain qualitatively similar regression results based on the alternative measure, all reported regression results are based on the preferred measure for brevity Sample description We include virtually all commercial and credit card banks in the U.S. in our study. 13 For each bank, we obtain quarterly Call Report data from 1984:Q1 to 2008:Q4. We keep a bank in the sample if it: 1) has commercial real estate or commercial and industrial loans outstanding; 2) has deposits; 3) has gross total assets or GTA exceeding $25 million; 4) has an equity capital to GTA ratio of at least 1%. 14 For each bank, we calculate the dollar amount of liquidity creation in each quarter (933,209 bankquarter observations from 18,294 distinct banks) using the process described in Section 4.2. We aggregate these amounts to obtain the dollar amount of liquidity creation by the banking sector, and put these (and all other financial values) into real 2008:Q4 dollars using the implicit GDP price deflator. We thus end up with a final sample that contains 100 inflation-adjusted, quarterly liquidity creation amounts. Given documented differences between banks of different sizes in terms of portfolio composition (e.g., Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein 2002, Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein 2005), we also split the sample by bank size into large, medium, and small banks, and perform our analyses separately for three sets of banks. Large banks have gross total assets (GTA) exceeding $3 billion, medium banks have GTA exceeding $1 billion and up to $3 billion, and small banks have GTA up to $1 billion Bank liquidity creation summary statistics Figure 2 Panel A shows the dollar amount of liquidity created by the banking sector, calculated using the preferred liquidity creation measure over our sample period. It also shows the breakout into on- and offbalance sheet liquidity creation. As shown, liquidity creation increased substantially over time: it almost 13 Berger and Bouwman (forthcoming) include only commercial banks. We also include credit card banks to avoid an artificial $0.19 trillion drop in bank liquidity creation in the fourth quarter of 2006 when Citibank N.A. moved its credit-card lines to Citibank South Dakota N.A., a credit card bank. 14 GTA equals total assets plus the allowance for loan and lease losses and the allocated transfer risk reserve (a reserve for certain foreign loans). Total assets on Call Reports deduct these two reserves, which are held to cover potential credit losses. We add these reserves back to measure the full value of the loans financed and the liquidity created by the bank on the asset side. 12

14 quadrupled from $1.398 trillion in 1984:Q1 to $5.304 trillion in 2008:Q4 (in real 2008:Q4 dollars). Using the alternative liquidity creation measure (see Section 4.2), liquidity creation grew from $1.715 trillion to $5.797 trillion over this period. Since the mid-1990s, off-balance sheet liquidity creation has exceeded and grown faster than on-balance sheet liquidity creation. Figure 2 Panel B shows that most of the liquidity in the banking sector is created by large banks and that their share of liquidity creation has increased from 76% in 1984 to 86% in Using the alternative measure, it increased from 70% to 87%. Over this same time frame, the shares of medium and small banks dropped from 8% to 5% and from 16% to 9%, respectively. Using the alternative measure, their shares dropped from 9% to 4% and from 21% to 8%, respectively. Figure 2 Panel C shows per capita liquidity creation over time. The picture reveals that per capita liquidity creation more than tripled from $5.9K in 1984:Q1 to $17.4K in 2008:Q4. Using the alternative measure, it almost tripled from $7.3K to $19.0K over this time period. Interestingly, the picture looks very similar to the one shown in Panel A, because the annual U.S. population growth rate is low relative to the growth in liquidity creation. Figure 2 Panel D shows the dollar amount of liquidity creation divided by GDP. The picture reveals that bank liquidity creation has increased from 19.9% of GDP in 1984:Q1 to 37.3% of GDP in 2008:Q4. Using the alternative liquidity creation measure, it increased from 24.4% to 40.8% of GDP over this time period. This picture also resembles the one shown in Panel A, but the increase over time is less pronounced. While liquidity creation more than quadrupled over the sample period, GDP doubled. 5. The effect of monetary policy on bank liquidity creation during normal times and financial crises The goals of monetary policy are to promote maximum sustainable output and employment and to promote stable prices. The FOMC sets the federal funds rate at a level it believes will foster conditions consistent with achieving these goals. Given the potential impact of monetary policy on both sides of the bank s balance sheet and on off-balance sheet guarantees via the bank lending channel, monetary policy can be expected to affect liquidity creation by banks. This section focuses on the second goal of the paper and examines the effect of monetary policy on liquidity creation during normal times and financial crises. We also analyze how the impact of monetary 13

15 policy would have been affected if the Federal Reserve had used the Taylor rule in setting monetary policy. We use regression analysis (in the spirit of Romer and Romer 2004) for this purpose, but acknowledge that our results, while indicative of causation, may merely reflect association Monetary policy and bank liquidity creation We start with the simplest possible regression. We regress the percentage change in aggregate liquidity creation (%ΔLC) on the (lagged) change in monetary policy and quarterly dummies (D SEASON) to control for seasonal effects. The change in monetary policy is alternatively defined as the change in the federal funds rate (ΔFEDFUNDS) and Romer and Romer s monetary policy shocks (POLICYSHOCKS). The specification based on ΔFEDFUNDS is: % (1) Inference is based on robust standard errors. Since tighter monetary policy (i.e. an increase in the federal funds rate or a positive monetary policy shock) is expected to be associated with a decrease in liquidity creation, we expect to find a negative coefficient on the change in monetary policy. Table 2 shows the results based on the change in the federal funds rate (Panel A) and the Romer and Romer monetary policy shocks (Panel B). 15 As can be seen in column (i), the coefficient on the change in monetary policy is positive for the all-bank sample, suggesting that tighter monetary policy is associated with an increase in liquidity creation (significant using the change in the federal funds rate). This result is puzzling and seems to be driven by large banks. For medium banks, the coefficient on monetary policy is not significant. For small banks, the coefficient is negative (significant based on the change in the federal funds rate), suggesting that for these banks, monetary policy works as expected, a finding consistent with Kashyap and Stein (2000). One reason why we find a positive effect of monetary policy on liquidity creation by large banks may be that large banks engage in far more off-balance sheet liquidity creation relative to on-balance sheet liquidity creation than small banks. While tighter monetary policy reduces the supply of on- and offbalance-sheet liquidity creation by for example restricting the supply of loans and loan commitments, the 15 Since Panel A regresses the percentage change in liquidity creation on the lagged change in the federal funds rate, these regressions have 98 (rather than 100) observations. Since Panel B regresses the percentage change in liquidity creation on lagged monetary policy shocks (available for every quarter), these regressions have 99 observations. 14

16 increase in the demand for loan commitments by borrowers may outweigh the supply effect. This is consistent with Thakor (2005), who shows that the value of the guarantee provided by loan commitments increases during periods of rationing. In Section 5.2 we provide evidence consistent with this. To examine whether the impact of monetary policy on liquidity creation varies across normal times and financial crises, we add a crisis dummy (D CRIS), and the (lagged) change in monetary policy interacted with the crisis dummy (alternatively defined as ΔFEDFUNDS * D CRIS or POLICYSHOCKS * D CRIS) to our specification. The crisis dummy equals one if there was a crisis in that quarter and is zero otherwise. The specification based on the change in the federal funds rate is: % (2) In these regressions, the coefficient on the change in monetary policy picks up the effect of monetary policy during normal times, while the coefficient on the interaction term shows whether monetary policy has a differential effect during financial crises. For example, if monetary policy is more effective during financial crises than during normal times, the coefficient on the interaction term will be negative and significant. Also, if liquidity creation is negatively affected during financial crises as one might expect, the coefficient on the crisis dummy will be negative. Table 2 column (ii) contains the results. As expected, the coefficient on the crisis dummy is negative and significant (in most cases), suggesting that liquidity creation indeed declines during financial crises. The coefficient on the change in monetary policy for the all-bank sample is now negative, but not significant. As before, this coefficient is significant only for small banks (based on the change in the federal funds rate). This suggests that monetary policy does not affect liquidity creation by large and medium banks, but provides some evidence that it does affect liquidity creation by small banks during normal times. The coefficients on the interaction terms are not significant, suggesting that the effect of monetary policy on liquidity creation is not different across crisis and non-crisis periods. It is intriguing that monetary policy does not seem to affect large and medium banks. We offer two possible reasons for this result. First, large and medium banks have better access to capital markets, which means that their cost and availability of funds are likely to be less affected by changes in monetary policy than those of small banks. Second, while the bank lending channel argues that tighter monetary policy 15

17 leads to a drop in lending, deposits, and off-balance sheet guarantees, the associated drop in liquidity creation may be offset by increased customer demand for off-balance sheet guarantees. It is possible that our results suffer from an omitted variables bias. One could argue, for example, that we need to control for demand for banking services in our regressions. 16 If this demand increased in the previous period, liquidity creation is expected to increase this period. We now address this issue by including the percentage change in GDP (%ΔGDP) in the regressions. Henceforth, we call this the complete specification. The specification based on the change in the federal funds rate is: % % (3) If changes in monetary policy affect liquidity creation, the coefficients on the change in monetary policy should be significant after controlling for changes in demand. Table 2 column (iii) contains the results. The coefficient on the change in GDP is positive and significant in the all-bank and large-bank regressions, suggesting that higher demand indeed fuels liquidity creation for these banks. However, controlling for demand does not materially affect the monetary policy results. To gauge the economic significance of the small-bank results, we focus on the coefficient on the change in the federal funds rate of (column (iii) in Panel A). This result suggests that if the federal funds rate increases by one percentage point, liquidity creation by small banks decreases by 1.3%. Evaluated at the average dollar amount of liquidity created by small banks of $333 billion, this translates into a drop in liquidity creation of $4.33 billion Monetary policy and on- versus off-balance sheet liquidity creation According to the bank lending channel, monetary tightening induces a drop in deposits and lending, and may have a negative effect on the supply of off-balance sheet guarantees such as loan commitments and letters of credit as well. While this suggests a decrease in on-balance sheet liquidity creation, off-balance sheet liquidity creation does not necessarily decline. Faced with rationing by banks in the spot credit 16 Regression specifications that also include the lagged percentage change in liquidity creation as a regressor or include the annual (rather than quarterly) change in monetary policy yield qualitatively similar results as the ones that are reported. Details are available on request. 16

18 market, customers may try to insure themselves against future rationing. The associated increase in demand for off-balance sheet guarantees may offset any decline in supply, and could lead to an increase off-balance sheet liquidity creation (Thakor 2005). Since large banks create far more liquidity off the balance sheet than small banks (see Berger and Bouwman forthcoming), the impact on off-balance sheet liquidity creation is expected to be strongest for these banks. We now investigate how monetary policy affects on- and off-balance sheet liquidity creation by re-running regressions (1) (3) from the previous section, with the percentage change in on- and off-balance sheet liquidity creation as dependent variables. Table 3 shows the regression results for on-balance sheet liquidity creation (Panel I) and offbalance sheet liquidity creation (Panel II). Subpanels A and B use the change in the federal funds rate and monetary policy shocks to measure the change in monetary policy, respectively. Results are shown in a similar way as in Table 2. Our discussion focuses on the complete specification in column (iii), which regresses the percentage change in (on- or off-balance sheet) liquidity creation on the change in monetary policy, the crisis dummy, the change in monetary policy interacted with the crisis dummy, the percentage change in GDP, and seasonal dummies. The results shown before (Table 2) suggested that monetary policy is effective only for small banks. The results in Table 3 Panel I provide evidence that monetary tightening reduces on-balance sheet liquidity creation of small banks (based on both monetary policy measures) and that of medium banks (significant based on the change in the federal funds rate). The small-bank effect on on-balance sheet liquidity creation seems stronger than the effect on overall liquidity creation in Table 2 based on both the federal funds rate (coefficient of versus ) and the Romer and Romer monetary policy shocks (coefficient of versus ). While monetary policy does not seem to affect total liquidity creation by large banks (see Table 2), the results in Table 3 Panel II suggest that it does have a significant effect on off-balance sheet liquidity creation for these banks (based on the monetary policy shock measure). There is no such effect for medium and small banks. The positive coefficient for large banks supports the hypothesis that firms try to obtain more off-balance sheet loan commitments from banks during periods of monetary tightening, and that large banks are most affected by this. The coefficient of suggests that a one percentage point bigger monetary policy shock is associated with a 6.1% increase in off-balance sheet liquidity creation, which 17

19 evaluated at the sample average of $1.773 trillion translates into a gain in off-balance sheet liquidity creation of $108.2 billion The effect of monetary policy on liquidity creation excluding the current subprime lending crisis The previous two subsections examine how monetary policy affects liquidity creation over the sample period. Since the current subprime lending crisis has been called the most serious crisis since the Great Depression, one might wonder to what extent the results presented above are driven by this crisis. To examine this, we rerun the regressions from Tables 2 and 3 using data from 1984:Q1 2004:Q4, a period that excludes the current crisis and the tremendous growth of liquidity creation that preceded it. 17 We only discuss the results based on the complete specification in column (iii) here (not shown for brevity). As before, we first focus on the effect of monetary policy on total liquidity creation. Using this shorter sample period, we find that monetary policy was somewhat less effective for small banks than reported in Table 2 above: the coefficients on liquidity creation are smaller (less negative) while still significant (based on the federal funds rate). Monetary policy was more effective for medium banks: the coefficients on liquidity creation are bigger (more negative) and are now significant. Monetary policy was equally ineffective for large banks: the coefficients and t-statistics are similar to those reported in Table 2 above. As above, we find that monetary policy affects liquidity creation during normal times and crises in a similar way for all size classes (the interaction term was not significant). These results suggest that the subprime lending crisis made monetary policy more effective for small banks, less effective for medium banks, and equally ineffective for large banks. Next, we split liquidity creation into on- and off-balance sheet liquidity creation. We find that using this shorter sample period, monetary policy affects on-balance sheet liquidity creation by small and medium banks more than reported in Table 3 Panel A above: the coefficients on on-balance sheet liquidity creation are more negative than before, while the t-statistics are similar. Monetary policy again does not significantly affect on-balance sheet liquidity creation by large banks. As above, we find no differential effect of monetary policy between normal periods and crises. These findings suggest that the subprime lending crisis has made monetary policy less effective for small and medium banks and had no effect on 17 We thank Loretta Mester for suggesting this additional analysis. 18

20 large banks in terms of on-balance sheet liquidity creation. Turning to off-balance sheet liquidity creation, we find that based on the shorter sample period, monetary policy again does not significantly affect off-balance sheet liquidity creation by small and medium banks, although the small-bank coefficients are now positive (not significant) based on the federal funds rate. Monetary policy has a larger positive effect for large banks during normal times than reported in Table 3 Panel B above (based on the Romer and Romer monetary policy shocks): the coefficients on offbalance sheet liquidity creation are bigger (more positive) as are the t-statistics. However, in contrast to our earlier findings, monetary policy has no effect on large banks during crisis periods based on the Romer and Romer monetary policy shocks (the sum of the coefficients on monetary policy and the interaction term is approximately zero). These results suggest that in terms of off-balance sheet liquidity creation, the subprime lending crisis has (insignificantly) enhanced the effectiveness of monetary policy for small banks; has not affected medium banks; has reduced the positive effect of monetary policy for large banks during normal times; and has increased the positive effect of monetary policy for these banks during crises Monetary policy and bank liquidity creation: the Taylor rule Taylor-type rules are widely used to explain how monetary policy has been set in the past and how it should be set in the future (e.g., Judd and Rudebusch 1998, Carlstrom and Fuerst 2003). This raises an interesting question: would aggregate liquidity creation have been significantly different if the Federal Reserve had used a Taylor rule? As a first step, in each quarter we estimate the Taylor rule federal funds rate, i.e., the federal funds rate that would have obtained if the Federal Reserve had used a Taylor rule. Taylor (1993) argues that the federal funds rate should be set as follows: where Infl is the four-quarter rate of inflation; NatFedFunds is the natural real federal funds rate (a rate that is consistent with full employment), which Taylor assumed to be 2%; TargetInfl is the target inflation rate, which also equals 2% by assumption; and OutputGap is the percent deviation of potential GDP from 19

Bank Liquidity Creation, Monetary Policy, and Financial Crises

Bank Liquidity Creation, Monetary Policy, and Financial Crises Bank Liquidity Creation, Monetary Policy, and Financial Crises Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina, Wharton Financial Institutions Center, and CentER Tilburg University Christa H.S. Bouwman MIT

More information

Financial Crises and Bank Liquidity Creation

Financial Crises and Bank Liquidity Creation Financial Crises and Bank Liquidity Creation Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina, Wharton Financial Institutions Center, and CentER Tilburg University Christa H.S. Bouwman Case Western Reserve

More information

Bank Capital, Survival, and Performance around Financial Crises

Bank Capital, Survival, and Performance around Financial Crises Bank Capital, Survival, and Performance around Financial Crises Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina, Wharton Financial Institutions Center, and CentER Tilburg University Christa H.S. Bouwman MIT

More information

Bank risk taking and liquidity creation following regulatory interventions and capital support

Bank risk taking and liquidity creation following regulatory interventions and capital support following regulatory interventions and capital support ALLEN N. BERGER U N I V E R S I T Y O F S O U T H C A R O L I N A W H A R T O N F I N A N C I A L I N S T I T U T I O N S C E N T E R C e n t E R

More information

Small Bank Comparative Advantages in Alleviating Financial Constraints and Providing Liquidity Insurance over Time

Small Bank Comparative Advantages in Alleviating Financial Constraints and Providing Liquidity Insurance over Time Small Bank Comparative Advantages in Alleviating Financial Constraints and Providing Liquidity Insurance over Time Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina Wharton Financial Institutions Center European

More information

René Garcia Professor of finance

René Garcia Professor of finance Liquidity Risk: What is it? How to Measure it? René Garcia Professor of finance EDHEC Business School, CIRANO Cirano, Montreal, January 7, 2009 The financial and economic environment We are living through

More information

While there is widespread agreement that

While there is widespread agreement that Bank Lending and Monetary Policy: Evidence on a Credit Channel By Charles S. Morris and Gordon H. Sellon, Jr. While there is widespread agreement that banks play a key part in the transmission of monetary

More information

Do Mortgage Loans Respond Perversely to Monetary Policy?

Do Mortgage Loans Respond Perversely to Monetary Policy? Do Mortgage Loans Respond Perversely to Monetary Policy? 11 November, 2014 Ali Termos American University of Beirut Olayan School of Business Finance Department Email: at36@aub.edu.lb Mohsen Saad American

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 2011-22 July 18, 2011 Securitization and Small Business BY JAMES A. WILCOX Small businesses have relied considerably on securitized markets for credit. The recent financial crisis

More information

Lecture 16: Financial Crisis

Lecture 16: Financial Crisis Lecture 16: Financial Crisis What is a Financial Crisis? A financial crisis occurs when there is a particularly large disruption to information flows in financial markets, with the result that financial

More information

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector by Wensheng Peng, Kitty Lai, Frank Leung and Chang Shu of the Research Department A rise in the Hong Kong dollar risk premium,

More information

Recent Developments in Small Business Finance

Recent Developments in Small Business Finance Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin February Recent Developments in Small Business Finance This article focuses on recent trends in small business financing, including the interest rates and fees and charges

More information

Licensed by the California Department of Corporations as an Investment Advisor

Licensed by the California Department of Corporations as an Investment Advisor Licensed by the California Department of Corporations as an Investment Advisor The Impact of the Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT) on Leverage Benefits My associate Matthias Schoener has pointed out to me

More information

Recent Developments in Small Business Finance

Recent Developments in Small Business Finance April 1 Recent Developments in Small Business Finance Introduction In 1, a Small Business Panel was formed by the Reserve Bank to advise it on the availability of finance to small business. At about the

More information

Discussion of The Effects of Bank Capital on Lending: What Do We Know, and What Does It Mean?

Discussion of The Effects of Bank Capital on Lending: What Do We Know, and What Does It Mean? Discussion of The Effects of Bank Capital on Lending: What Do We Know, and What Does It Mean? José-Luis Peydró European Central Bank 1. Introduction The events of the last few years suggest that the financial

More information

IW Monetary Outlook December 2015

IW Monetary Outlook December 2015 IW policy paper 37/2015 Contributions to the political debate by the Cologne Institute for Economic Research IW Monetary Outlook December 2015 Weak Credit Growth Hinders Eurozone Inflation to Increase

More information

Large and Small Companies Exhibit Diverging Bankruptcy Trends

Large and Small Companies Exhibit Diverging Bankruptcy Trends JANUARY, 22 NUMBER 2-1 D I V I S I O N O F I N S U R A N C E Bank Trends Analysis of Emerging Risks In Banking WASHINGTON, D.C. ALAN DEATON (22) 898-738 adeaton@fdic.gov Large and Small Companies Exhibit

More information

Credit Supply versus Demand: Bank and Firm Balance-Sheet Channels in Good and Crisis Times

Credit Supply versus Demand: Bank and Firm Balance-Sheet Channels in Good and Crisis Times Credit Supply versus Demand: Bank and Firm Balance-Sheet Channels in Good and Crisis Times Gabriel Jiménez Banco de España PO Box 28014, Alcalá 48, Madrid, Spain Telephone: +34 91 3385710, Fax: +34 91

More information

Are Banks Still Important for Financing Large Businesses?

Are Banks Still Important for Financing Large Businesses? FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE August 1999 Volume 5 Number 12 Are Banks Still Important for Financing Large Businesses? Marc R. Saidenberg and Philip E. Strahan As more corporations

More information

Conceptual Framework: What Does the Financial System Do? 1. Financial contracting: Get funds from savers to investors

Conceptual Framework: What Does the Financial System Do? 1. Financial contracting: Get funds from savers to investors Conceptual Framework: What Does the Financial System Do? 1. Financial contracting: Get funds from savers to investors Transactions costs Contracting costs (from asymmetric information) Adverse Selection

More information

Federal Reserve Monetary Policy

Federal Reserve Monetary Policy Federal Reserve Monetary Policy To prevent recession, earlier this decade the Federal Reserve s monetary policy pushed down the short-term interest rate to just 1%, the lowest level for many decades. Long-term

More information

Diane Delelis 21.10.2011. Securitization. Finance (Basics) Luděk Benada

Diane Delelis 21.10.2011. Securitization. Finance (Basics) Luděk Benada Diane Delelis 21.10.2011 Securitization Finance (Basics) Luděk Benada Index Introduction... 3 I. Detailed presentation...3 II. Vocabulary of securitization...4 III. An example...5 IV. Advantages...6 1.

More information

THE PROPERTY MARKET AND THE MACRO-ECONOMY

THE PROPERTY MARKET AND THE MACRO-ECONOMY THE PROPERTY MARKET AND THE MACRO-ECONOMY In the wake of the Asian financial crisis, property prices in Hong Kong dropped sharply relative to prices of other goods and services by close to 50% between

More information

Debt, Delinquencies, and Consumer Spending Jonathan McCarthy

Debt, Delinquencies, and Consumer Spending Jonathan McCarthy February 1997 Volume 3 Number 3 Debt, Delinquencies, and Consumer Spending Jonathan McCarthy The sharp rise in household debt and delinquency rates over the last year has led to speculation that consumers

More information

Chapter 13 Money and Banking

Chapter 13 Money and Banking Chapter 13 Money and Banking Multiple Choice Questions Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1. The most important function of money is (a) as a store of

More information

CREDIT UNION TRENDS REPORT

CREDIT UNION TRENDS REPORT CREDIT UNION TRENDS REPORT CUNA Mutual Group Economics June 2 (April 2 data) Highlights During April, credit unions picked up 3, new memberships, credit union loan balances grew at an annualized 1.7% pace,

More information

Lecture 4: The Aftermath of the Crisis

Lecture 4: The Aftermath of the Crisis Lecture 4: The Aftermath of the Crisis 2 The Fed s Efforts to Restore Financial Stability A financial panic in fall 2008 threatened the stability of the global financial system. In its lender-of-last-resort

More information

All in All it was not much of a Maturity Wall BY JASON M. THOMAS AND LINDA PACE

All in All it was not much of a Maturity Wall BY JASON M. THOMAS AND LINDA PACE Market Commentary August 27, 2012 All in All it was not much of a Maturity Wall BY JASON M. THOMAS AND LINDA PACE By virtually any measure, the speculative grade corporate credit market in the United States

More information

A VERY DIFFERENT NASDAQ

A VERY DIFFERENT NASDAQ LPL RESEARCH WEEKLY MARKET COMMENTARY KEY TAKEAWAYS The Nasdaq Composite just hit 5000 today as this report was going to press and is nearing its all-time record closing high of 5048. Even with the Nasdaq

More information

Chapter 11 Money and Monetary Policy Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Chapter 11 Money and Monetary Policy Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.) Chapter 11 Money and Monetary Policy Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.) Chapter Overview In this chapter, you will be introduced to a standard treatment of the banking system and monetary policy.

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 2009-27 August 31, 2009 Credit Market Conditions and the Use of Bank Lines of Credit BY CHRISTOPHER M. JAMES Many credit line agreements contain restrictive covenants and other contingencies

More information

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds International Department Working Paper Series 00-E-3 Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds Yoshihito SAITO yoshihito.saitou@boj.or.jp Yoko TAKEDA youko.takeda@boj.or.jp

More information

Banks Exposure to Interest Rate Risk and The Transmission of Monetary Policy:

Banks Exposure to Interest Rate Risk and The Transmission of Monetary Policy: Banks Exposure to Interest Rate Risk and The Transmission of Monetary Policy: Augustin Landier David Sraer David Thesmar May 22, 2012 Abstract This paper offers a new test of the lending channel view,

More information

MACROECONOMIC AND INDUSTRY ANALYSIS VALUATION PROCESS

MACROECONOMIC AND INDUSTRY ANALYSIS VALUATION PROCESS MACROECONOMIC AND INDUSTRY ANALYSIS VALUATION PROCESS BUSINESS ANALYSIS INTRODUCTION To determine a proper price for a firm s stock, security analyst must forecast the dividend & earnings that can be expected

More information

A Model of Housing Prices and Residential Investment

A Model of Housing Prices and Residential Investment A Model of Prices and Residential Investment Chapter 9 Appendix In this appendix, we develop a more complete model of the housing market that explains how housing prices are determined and how they interact

More information

THE POTENTIAL MACROECONOMIC EFFECT OF DEBT CEILING BRINKMANSHIP

THE POTENTIAL MACROECONOMIC EFFECT OF DEBT CEILING BRINKMANSHIP OCTOBER 2013 THE POTENTIAL MACROECONOMIC EFFECT OF DEBT CEILING BRINKMANSHIP Introduction The United States has never defaulted on its obligations, and the U. S. dollar and Treasury securities are at the

More information

Managing Bank Liquidity Risk

Managing Bank Liquidity Risk MANAGING BANK LIQUIDITY RISK: HOW DEPOSIT-LOAN SYNERGIES VARY WITH MARKET CONDITIONS Preliminary Findings: Please do not Quote without Permission Evan Gatev Boston College Til Schuermann Federal Reserve

More information

FINANCIAL CRISES AND ITS IMPACT ON THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM. Lecturer Oleg Deev oleg@mail.muni.cz

FINANCIAL CRISES AND ITS IMPACT ON THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM. Lecturer Oleg Deev oleg@mail.muni.cz FINANCIAL CRISES AND ITS IMPACT ON THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM Lecturer Oleg Deev oleg@mail.muni.cz Essential readings 1. Geisst, C.R. (2009). Globalization and the US Financial System. US Department of State

More information

Comment On: Reducing Foreclosures by Christopher Foote, Kristopher Gerardi, Lorenz Goette and Paul Willen

Comment On: Reducing Foreclosures by Christopher Foote, Kristopher Gerardi, Lorenz Goette and Paul Willen Comment On: Reducing Foreclosures by Christopher Foote, Kristopher Gerardi, Lorenz Goette and Paul Willen Atif Mian 1 University of Chicago Booth School of Business and NBER The current global recession

More information

China s Economic Reforms and Growth Prospects. Nicholas Lardy. Anthony M Solomon Senior Fellow. Peterson Institute for International Economics

China s Economic Reforms and Growth Prospects. Nicholas Lardy. Anthony M Solomon Senior Fellow. Peterson Institute for International Economics China s Economic Reforms and Growth Prospects Nicholas Lardy Anthony M Solomon Senior Fellow Peterson Institute for International Economics Paper Prepared for the CF-40 PIIE 2014 Conference Beijing May

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 214-23 August 4, 214 Long Road to Normal for Bank Business Lending BY SIMON KWAN Following the 27 9 financial crisis, bank lending to plummeted. Five years later, the dollar amount

More information

PERSONAL RETIREMENT SAVINGS ACCOUNT INVESTMENT REPORT

PERSONAL RETIREMENT SAVINGS ACCOUNT INVESTMENT REPORT PENSIONS INVESTMENTS LIFE INSURANCE PERSONAL RETIREMENT SAVINGS ACCOUNT INVESTMENT REPORT FOR PERSONAL RETIREMENT SAVINGS ACCOUNT () PRODUCTS WITH AN ANNUAL FUND MANAGEMENT CHARGE OF 1% - JULY 201 Thank

More information

Notation. Entrepreneurs Undertake the project if. Total deposits. Sum of all deposits except bank i. Sum of all loans except bank i

Notation. Entrepreneurs Undertake the project if. Total deposits. Sum of all deposits except bank i. Sum of all loans except bank i Banking Crises and Crisis Dating: Theory and Evidence John Boyd University of Minnesota, Department of Finance Gianni De Nicolò IMF, Research Department Elena Loukoianova EBRD, Evaluation Department http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.cfm?sk=23052.0

More information

What s behind the liquidity spread? On-the-run and off-the-run US Treasuries in autumn 1998 1

What s behind the liquidity spread? On-the-run and off-the-run US Treasuries in autumn 1998 1 Craig H Furfine +4 6 28 923 craig.furfine@bis.org Eli M Remolona +4 6 28 844 eli.remolona@bis.org What s behind the liquidity spread? On-the-run and off-the-run US Treasuries in autumn 998 Autumn 998 witnessed

More information

Proposal to Allow Treasury to Buy Mortgage- Related Assets to Address Financial Instability

Proposal to Allow Treasury to Buy Mortgage- Related Assets to Address Financial Instability Order Code RS22957 September 22, 2008 Proposal to Allow Treasury to Buy Mortgage- Related Assets to Address Financial Instability Summary Edward V. Murphy Analyst in Financial Economics Government and

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. ECON 4110: Sample Exam Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) Economists define risk as A) the difference between the return on common

More information

Narrow Banking

Narrow Banking Can Narrow Banking Provide a Substitute for Depository Intermediaries? Preliminary. Comments very welcome. William Miles Department of Economics Wichita State University Wichita, KS 67260-0078 Phone: 316-978-7085

More information

RESIDENTIAL MORTGAGE-BACKED SECURITIES (RMBS)

RESIDENTIAL MORTGAGE-BACKED SECURITIES (RMBS) Market Review & Outlook RESIDENTIAL MORTGAGE-BACKED SECURITIES (RMBS) July 2008 Metropolitan West Asset Management 11766 Wilshire Boulevard, Suite 1500 Los Angeles, California 90025 TEL 310.966.8900 FAX

More information

Quarterly NEWS. Is Inflation Around the Corner?

Quarterly NEWS. Is Inflation Around the Corner? Quarterly GHP Investment Advisors, Inc. NEWS Second Quarter 2009 by Brian J. Friedman, CFA Is Inflation Around the Corner? Those of you who took an economics class in college probably remember your professor

More information

1. State and explain two reasons why short-maturity loans are safer (meaning lower credit risk) to the lender than long-maturity loans (10 points).

1. State and explain two reasons why short-maturity loans are safer (meaning lower credit risk) to the lender than long-maturity loans (10 points). Boston College, MF 820 Professor Strahan Midterm Exam, Fall 2010 1. State and explain two reasons why short-maturity loans are safer (meaning lower credit risk) to the lender than long-maturity loans (10

More information

Current account deficit -10. Private sector Other public* Official reserve assets

Current account deficit -10. Private sector Other public* Official reserve assets Australian Capital Flows and the financial Crisis Introduction For many years, Australia s high level of investment relative to savings has been supported by net foreign capital inflow. This net capital

More information

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Karl Walentin Sveriges Riksbank 1. Background This paper is part of the large literature that takes as its starting point the

More information

Transformation Risk and its Determinants: A New Approach based on the Basel III Liquidity Management Framework

Transformation Risk and its Determinants: A New Approach based on the Basel III Liquidity Management Framework Transformation Risk and its Determinants: A New Approach based on the Basel III Liquidity Management Framework Alain Angora, Caroline Roulet Université de Limoges, LAPE, 5 rue Félix Eboué, 87031 Limoges

More information

A Beginner s Guide to the Stock Market

A Beginner s Guide to the Stock Market A beginner s guide to the stock market 1 A Beginner s Guide to the Stock Market An organized market in which stocks or bonds are bought and sold is called a securities market. Securities markets that deal

More information

Fixed Income Liquidity in a Rising Rate Environment

Fixed Income Liquidity in a Rising Rate Environment Fixed Income Liquidity in a Rising Rate Environment 2 Executive Summary Ò Fixed income market liquidity has declined, causing greater concern about prospective liquidity in a potential broad market sell-off

More information

Trends in residential mortgage loan originations and their impact on community banks. Introduction

Trends in residential mortgage loan originations and their impact on community banks. Introduction December 2009 Trends in residential mortgage loan originations and their impact on community banks James Harvey James Harvey is a policy economist in the Division of Supervision and Risk Management of

More information

Senior Floating Rate Loans

Senior Floating Rate Loans Senior floating rate loans have become a staple of the U.S. debt market and have grown from a market value of $126 billion in 2001 to $607 billion as of year-end 2011. 1 For over 20 years, managed senior

More information

Effectiveness of Increasing Liquidity as a Response to Increased Repayment Risk: A Case Study

Effectiveness of Increasing Liquidity as a Response to Increased Repayment Risk: A Case Study Effectiveness of Increasing Liquidity as a Response to Increased Repayment Risk: A Case Study ABSTRACT Volatile net farm incomes and potential for higher interest rates has strengthened the importance

More information

Chapter Two FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC INDICATORS

Chapter Two FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC INDICATORS Chapter Two FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC INDICATORS 1. Introduction In Chapter One we discussed the concept of risk and the importance of protecting a portfolio from losses. Managing your investment risk should

More information

THE GREAT DEPRESSION OF FINLAND 1990-1993: causes and consequences. Jaakko Kiander Labour Institute for Economic Research

THE GREAT DEPRESSION OF FINLAND 1990-1993: causes and consequences. Jaakko Kiander Labour Institute for Economic Research THE GREAT DEPRESSION OF FINLAND 1990-1993: causes and consequences Jaakko Kiander Labour Institute for Economic Research CONTENTS Causes background The crisis Consequences Role of economic policy Banking

More information

Loan Portfolio Performance and Selection of Lending Practices

Loan Portfolio Performance and Selection of Lending Practices The Effects of Underwriting Practices on Loan Losses: Evidence from the FDIC Survey of Bank Lending Practices* John O Keefe Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation 550 17 th Street, NW Washington, DC 20429

More information

Improving Our Ability to Monitor Bank Lending

Improving Our Ability to Monitor Bank Lending Improving Our Ability to Monitor Bank Lending William F. Bassett Simon Gilchrist Gretchen C. Weinbach Egon Zakrajšek August 2, 211 Bank lending to households and businesses over the past several years

More information

Factors Determining Bank Debt vs Bond Debt of Canadian Corporations

Factors Determining Bank Debt vs Bond Debt of Canadian Corporations Factors Determining Bank Debt vs Bond Debt of Canadian Corporations May 2012 Preliminary; do not quote George J. Georgopoulos Department of Economics York University, Toronto, Canada Abstract This paper

More information

The Return of Saving

The Return of Saving Martin Feldstein the u.s. savings rate and the global economy The savings rate of American households has been declining for more than a decade and recently turned negative. This decrease has dramatically

More information

The global financial crisis which began in the

The global financial crisis which began in the What is responsible for the easing of credit standards before the crisis: monetary policy or the savings glut? Adrian Penalver Monetary and Financial Analysis Directorate This letter presents the findings

More information

The Business Credit Index

The Business Credit Index The Business Credit Index April 8 Published by the Credit Management Research Centre, Leeds University Business School April 8 1 April 8 THE BUSINESS CREDIT INDEX During the last ten years the Credit Management

More information

Assessing the Risks of Mortgage REITs. By Sabrina R. Pellerin, David A. Price, Steven J. Sabol, and John R. Walter

Assessing the Risks of Mortgage REITs. By Sabrina R. Pellerin, David A. Price, Steven J. Sabol, and John R. Walter Economic Brief November 2013, EB13-11 Assessing the Risks of Mortgage REITs By Sabrina R. Pellerin, David A. Price, Steven J. Sabol, and John R. Walter Regulators have expressed concern about the growth

More information

Project LINK Meeting New York, 20-22 October 2010. Country Report: Australia

Project LINK Meeting New York, 20-22 October 2010. Country Report: Australia Project LINK Meeting New York, - October 1 Country Report: Australia Prepared by Peter Brain: National Institute of Economic and Industry Research, and Duncan Ironmonger: Department of Economics, University

More information

Re-Assessing Multi-Strategy Hedge Funds Aaron Mirandon, Associate Portfolio Manager

Re-Assessing Multi-Strategy Hedge Funds Aaron Mirandon, Associate Portfolio Manager Re-Assessing Multi-Strategy Hedge Funds Aaron Mirandon, Associate Portfolio Manager { Overview } The market returns from September 2008 through mid-2010 have introduced some extraordinary market movements

More information

MACROECONOMICS. The Monetary System: What It Is and How It Works. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

MACROECONOMICS. The Monetary System: What It Is and How It Works. N. Gregory Mankiw. PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich 4 : What It Is and How It Works MACROECONOMICS N. Gregory Mankiw Modified for EC 204 by Bob Murphy PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL

More information

HOW DID THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECT SMALL-BUSINESS LENDING IN THE U.S.?

HOW DID THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECT SMALL-BUSINESS LENDING IN THE U.S.? HOW DID THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECT SMALL-BUSINESS LENDING IN THE U.S.? Rebel A. Cole Driehaus College of Business DePaul University Email: rcole@depaul.edu Presentation for the 2013 AIDEA Bicentenniel

More information

EC 341 Monetary and Banking Institutions, Boston University Summer 2, 2012 Homework 3 Due date: Tuesday, July 31, 6:00 PM.

EC 341 Monetary and Banking Institutions, Boston University Summer 2, 2012 Homework 3 Due date: Tuesday, July 31, 6:00 PM. EC 341 Monetary and Banking Institutions, Boston University Summer 2, 2012 Homework 3 Due date: Tuesday, July 31, 6:00 PM. Problem 1 Questions 1, 4, 6, 8, 12, 13, 16, 18, 22, and 23 from Chapter 8. Solutions:

More information

A Proposal to Resolve the Distress of Large and Complex Financial Institutions

A Proposal to Resolve the Distress of Large and Complex Financial Institutions A Proposal to Resolve the Distress of Large and Complex Financial Institutions Viral V Acharya, Barry Adler and Matthew Richardson 1 Due to the difficulty in resolving bankruptcies of large multinational

More information

Fixed Income: The Hidden Risk of Indexing

Fixed Income: The Hidden Risk of Indexing MANNING & NAPIER ADVISORS, INC. Fixed Income: The Hidden Risk of Indexing Unless otherwise noted, all figures are based in USD. Fixed income markets in the U.S. are vast. At roughly twice the size of domestic

More information

Does Market Size Structure Affect Competition? The Case of Small Business Lending

Does Market Size Structure Affect Competition? The Case of Small Business Lending Does Market Size Structure Affect Competition? The Case of Small Business Lending Allen N. Berger Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 20551 U.S.A. Wharton Financial Institutions

More information

How To Find Out How Effective Stimulus Is

How To Find Out How Effective Stimulus Is Do Tax Cuts Boost the Economy? David Rosnick and Dean Baker September 2011 Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Suite 400 Washington, D.C. 20009 202-293-5380 www.cepr.net

More information

Arbeitsbereich Ökonomie. IOS Working Papers. Bank Capital and Liquidity Creation: Granger Causality Evidence

Arbeitsbereich Ökonomie. IOS Working Papers. Bank Capital and Liquidity Creation: Granger Causality Evidence Arbeitsbereich Ökonomie IOS Working Papers No. 318 July 2012 Bank Capital and Liquidity Creation: Granger Causality Evidence Roman Horváth *, Jakub Seidler **, and Laurent Weill *** * Charles University,

More information

The Effects of Funding Costs and Risk on Banks Lending Rates

The Effects of Funding Costs and Risk on Banks Lending Rates The Effects of Funding Costs and Risk on Banks Lending Rates Daniel Fabbro and Mark Hack* After falling for over a decade, the major banks net interest margins appear to have stabilised in a relatively

More information

4. The minimum amount of owners' equity in a bank mandated by regulators is called a requirement. A) reserve B) margin C) liquidity D) capital

4. The minimum amount of owners' equity in a bank mandated by regulators is called a requirement. A) reserve B) margin C) liquidity D) capital Chapter 4 - Sample Questions 1. Quantitative easing is most closely akin to: A) discount lending. B) open-market operations. C) fractional-reserve banking. D) capital requirements. 2. Money market mutual

More information

How Do Small Businesses Finance their Growth Opportunities? The Case of Recovery from the Lost Decade in Japan

How Do Small Businesses Finance their Growth Opportunities? The Case of Recovery from the Lost Decade in Japan How Do Small Businesses Finance their Growth Opportunities? The Case of Recovery from the Lost Decade in Japan Daisuke Tsuruta National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies and CRD Association January

More information

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS PROBLEM SETS 1. There is little hedging or speculative demand for cement futures, since cement prices are fairly stable and predictable. The trading activity necessary to support

More information

Bank Lending and Credit Supply Shocks

Bank Lending and Credit Supply Shocks Bank Lending and Credit Supply Shocks Simon Gilchrist Egon Zakrajšek October 7, 211 Abstract This paper analyzes the linkages between credit supply conditions and bank lending. Building on the recent work

More information

Outsourcing Accounts Receivable to Increase Cash Flow

Outsourcing Accounts Receivable to Increase Cash Flow Outsourcing Accounts Receivable to Increase Cash Flow Outsourcing Accounts Receivable to Increase Cash Flow In the current economic environment, small and medium-size businesses are facing unprecedented

More information

SPDR S&P 400 Mid Cap Value ETF

SPDR S&P 400 Mid Cap Value ETF SPDR S&P 400 Mid Cap Value ETF Summary Prospectus-October 31, 2015 Before you invest in the SPDR S&P 400 Mid Cap Value ETF (the Fund ), you may want to review the Fund's prospectus and statement of additional

More information

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER 211-32 October 17, 211 Recent Trends in Small Business Lending BY LIZ LADERMAN AND JAMES GILLAN Although bank small business loan portfolios continue to shrink, there are hints of

More information

Bank Lending. -Doing due diligence before making loans in order to separate the wheat from the chaff; -Work-out/foreclose when loans go bad.

Bank Lending. -Doing due diligence before making loans in order to separate the wheat from the chaff; -Work-out/foreclose when loans go bad. Bank Lending A. Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection in Financial Contracting As we saw in the first week, a key role of intermediaries is to transform illiquid loans into liquid deposits. Loans are illiquid

More information

Measuring Credit 1. Introduction. What Is Credit?

Measuring Credit 1. Introduction. What Is Credit? Measuring Credit 1 Introduction Central banks put significant emphasis on credit aggregates for understanding financial conditions in the economy. Measuring credit outstanding, however, is not straightforward,

More information

OneWest Bank N. A. Dodd-Frank Act Stress Test Disclosure

OneWest Bank N. A. Dodd-Frank Act Stress Test Disclosure OneWest Bank N. A. Dodd-Frank Act Stress Test Disclosure Capital Stress Testing Results Covering the Time Period October 1, through December 31, for OneWest Bank N.A. under a Hypothetical Severely Adverse

More information

Small Business Lending During the Recession

Small Business Lending During the Recession Economic Brief February 211, EB11-2 Small Business Lending During the Recession By Betty Joyce Nash and Kimberly Zeuli Access to credit enables businesses to smooth income streams and take advantage of

More information

The New FDIC Insurance Premium Assessments: A Better Way Scott Hein and Timothy Koch April 6, 2009

The New FDIC Insurance Premium Assessments: A Better Way Scott Hein and Timothy Koch April 6, 2009 The New FDIC Insurance Premium Assessments: A Better Way Scott Hein and Timothy Koch April 6, 2009 Effective January 1, 2009 the FDIC increased the annual insurance assessment rate by 7 basis points applied

More information

chapter: Solution Money, Banking, and the Federal Reserve System

chapter: Solution Money, Banking, and the Federal Reserve System Money, Banking, and the Federal Reserve System 1. For each of the following transactions, what is the initial effect (increase or decrease) on M1? On M2? a. You sell a few shares of stock and put the proceeds

More information

During the last couple of years, concern

During the last couple of years, concern Does Faster Loan Growth Lead to Higher Loan Losses? By William R. Keeton During the last couple of years, concern has increased that the exceptionally rapid growth in business loans at commercial banks

More information

TARGETING OF KEY INTEREST RATE AS A SOURCE OF CRISIS

TARGETING OF KEY INTEREST RATE AS A SOURCE OF CRISIS vol. 2, 2012 67 TARGETING OF KEY INTEREST RATE AS A SOURCE OF CRISIS YANA SOKOLOVA St. Petersburg State University, Faculty of Economics, Russia Abstract In response to the world economic crisis of 2008

More information

Stock Markets Correlation: before and during the Crisis Analysis *

Stock Markets Correlation: before and during the Crisis Analysis * Theoretical and Applied Economics Volume XVIII (2011), No. 8(561), pp. 111-122 Stock Markets Correlation: before and during the Crisis Analysis * Ioana MOLDOVAN Bucharest Academy of Economic Studies ioana.moldovan@economie.ase.ro

More information

HSBC North America Holdings Inc. 2015 Comprehensive Capital Analysis and Review and Annual Company-Run Dodd-Frank Act Stress Test Results

HSBC North America Holdings Inc. 2015 Comprehensive Capital Analysis and Review and Annual Company-Run Dodd-Frank Act Stress Test Results 2015 Comprehensive Capital Analysis and Review and Annual Company-Run Dodd-Frank Act Stress Test Results Date: March 5, 2015 TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE 1. Overview of the Comprehensive Capital Analysis and

More information

Quarterly NEWS GHP. Investment Advisors, Inc. GHP Investment Advisors, Inc. is a member of The GHP Financial Group. Fourth Quarter 2009

Quarterly NEWS GHP. Investment Advisors, Inc. GHP Investment Advisors, Inc. is a member of The GHP Financial Group. Fourth Quarter 2009 Quarterly GHP Investment Advisors, Inc. NEWS Fourth Quarter 2009 by Brian J. Friedman, CFA Will Deteriorating Commercial Real Estate Cause Financial Crisis Aftershocks? Some investors are jittery because

More information

The Search for Yield Continues: A Re-introduction to Bank Loans

The Search for Yield Continues: A Re-introduction to Bank Loans INSIGHTS The Search for Yield Continues: A Re-introduction to Bank Loans 203.621.1700 2013, Rocaton Investment Advisors, LLC Executive Summary With the Federal Reserve pledging to stick to its zero interest-rate

More information