We model an isolated portion of a competitive supply chain as a M/M/1 make-tostock

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "We model an isolated portion of a competitive supply chain as a M/M/1 make-tostock"

Transcription

1 Analysis of a Decentralized Production-Inventory System René Caldentey Lawrence M. Wein Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, New York Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, California rcaldent@stern.nyu.edu lwein@stanford.edu We model an isolated portion of a competitive supply chain as a M/M/1 make-tostock queue. The retailer carries finished goods inventory to service a Poisson demand process, and specifies a policy for replenishing his inventory from an upstream supplier. The supplier chooses the service rate, i.e., the capacity of his manufacturing facility, which behaves as a single-server queue with exponential service times. Demand is backlogged and both agents share the backorder cost. In addition, a linear inventory holding cost is charged to the retailer, and a linear cost for building production capacity is incurred by the supplier. The inventory level, demand rate, and cost parameters are common knowledge to both agents. Under the continuous-state approximation where the M/M/1 queue has an exponential rather than geometric steady-state distribution, we characterize the optimal centralized and Nash solutions, and show that a contract with linear transfer payments replicates a cost-sharing agreement and coordinates the system. We also compare the total system costs, the agents decision variables, and the customer service levels of the centralized versus Nash versus Stackelberg solutions. (Make-to-Stock Queue; Game Theory) 1. Introduction Within many supply chains, a devoted upstream agent, referred to here as the supplier, produces goods for a downstream agent, called the retailer, in a maketo-stock manner. Broadly speaking, the performance (e.g., service levels, cost to produce and hold items) of this isolated portion of the supply chain is dictated by three factors: (i) retailer demand, which is largely exogenous but can in some cases be manipulated via pricing and advertising, (ii) the effectiveness of the supplier s production process and the subsequent transportation of goods, and (iii) the inventory replenishment policy, by which retailer demand is mapped into orders placed with the supplier. If the supplier and retailer are under different ownership or are independent entities within the same firm, then their competing objectives can lead to severe coordination problems: The supplier typically wants the retailer to hold as much inventory as possible, while the retailer prefers to hold very little inventory and desires rapid response from the supplier. These tensions may deteriorate overall system performance. The recent explosion in the academic supply chain management literature is aimed at this type of multiagent problem. Almost without exception, the papers that incorporate stochastic demand employ variants of one of two prototypical operations management models: the newsvendor model, or the Clark-Scarf (1960) multiechelon inventory model. One-period and two-period versions of newsvendor supply chain models have been studied intensively to address the three factors above; see Agrawal et al. (1999), Cachon (1999), and Lariviere (1999), for recent reviews. Although many valuable insights have been generated by this work, these models are primarily useful for style goods and products with very short /03/0501/0001$ electronic ISSN Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 2003 INFORMS Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003 pp. 1 17

2 life cycles. More complex (multiperiod, and possibly multiechelon and positive lead time) supply chain models have been used to analyze the case where a product experiences ongoing production and demand. Of the three factors in the last paragraph, these multiperiod supply chain models successfully capture the replenishment policy and have addressed some aspects of retailer demand, for example, information lead times in the Clark-Scarf model (Chen 1999), pricing in multiechelon models with deterministic demand and ordering costs (Chen et al. 2001), and forecast updates (Anupindi and Bassok (1999) in a multiperiod newsvendor model, and Tsay and Lovejoy (1999) in a multistage model). However, the Clark- Scarf model simplifies the supplier s production process by assuming that lead times are independent of the ordering process, or equivalently, that the production process is an infinite-server queue. In this paper, we use an alternative prototypical model, an M/M/1 make-to-stock queue, to analyze a supply chain. Here, the supplier is modeled as a single-server queue, rather than an infiniteserver queue, and the retailer s optimal inventory replenishment strategy is a base-stock policy. Because the production system is explicitly incorporated, these make-to-stock queues are also referred to as production-inventory systems. The M/M/1 make-tostock queue was introduced by Morse (1958), but lay mysteriously dormant for the next three decades, perhaps because the multiechelon version of it lacked the attractive decomposition property of the Clark-Scarf model and traditional (i.e., make-to-order) queueing networks, except under some restrictive inventory policies (Rubio and Wein 1996). Make-to-stock queueing systems have experienced a revival in the 1990s, including multiproduct queues with (e.g., Federgruen and Katalan 1996, Markowitz et al. 2000) and without (e.g., Zheng and Zipkin 1990, Wein 1992) setups, and single-product, multistage systems in continuous time (e.g., Buzacott et al. 1992, Lee and Zipkin 1992) and discrete time (e.g., Glasserman and Tayur 1995 and Gavirneni et al. 1996, building on earlier work by Federgruen and Zipkin 1986). Although these papers either undertake a performance analysis or consider a centralized decision maker (Gaverneni et al. (1996) analyze their system under various informational structures, but not in a game-theoretic setting), the make-to-stock queue is amenable to a competitive analysis because it explicitly captures the trade-off between the supplier s capacity choice and the retailer s choice of base-stock level. However, the model treats the third key factor in a naive way, by assuming that retailer demand is an exogenous Poisson process. Moreover, we assume that the system state, the demand rate and the cost parameters are known by each agent. While this assumption is admittedly crude, we believe it is an appropriate starting point for exploring competitive make-to-stock queues. In the only other contemporaneous multiagent production-inventory study that we are aware of, Plambeck and Zenios (1999) take a significant step forward by analyzing a dynamic system with information asymmetry. Subsequent work includes Cachon (1999b), where both agents choose base-stock levels in a single-stage lost sales model, and Duenyas and Tsai (2001), where two profit-maximizing agents manage each stage of a tandem system that incurs demand for intermediate and end products. In an attempt to isolate and hence understand the impact of incorporating capacity into a supply chain model, we intentionally mimic Cachon and Zipkin (1999). Their two-stage Clark-Scarf model is quite similar to our M/M/1 make-to-stock queue: Both models have two players, assume linear backorder and holding costs for retailer inventory (where the backorder costs are shared by both agents), employ steady-state analysis, and ignore fixed ordering costs. The key distinction between the two models is that the production stage is an infinite-server queue and the supplier controls his (local or echelon) inventory level in Cachon and Zipkin (1999), whereas in our paper, the production stage is modeled as a single-server queue and the supplier controls the capacity level, which in turn dictates a steady-state lead-time distribution. While Cachon and Zipkin s supplier incurs a linear inventory holding cost, our supplier is subjected to a linear capacity cost. A minor difference is that our queueing model is in continuous time, while Cachon and Zipkin s inventory model is in discrete time. In fact, to make our results more transparent and to maintain a closer match of the 2 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003

3 two models, we use a continuous-state approximation, essentially replacing the geometric steady-state distribution of the M/M/1 queue by an exponential distribution with the same mean. After defining the model in 2, we derive the centralized solution in 3, where a single decision maker optimizes system performance, and the unique Nash equilibrium in 4, where the supplier and retailer minimize their own cost. The two solutions are compared in 5. We show that the Nash solution is always inefficient and that the magnitude of the inefficiency tends to be minimized when backorder costs are evenly split between the supplier and the retailer. We also analyze the Nash equilibrium in terms of service performance that is measured by the fraction of customers that are backlogged. The Nash solution provides a poorer service than the centralized one and the difference is minimized when the retailer absorbs most of the backorder costs. In this respect, we conclude that customers prefer that the penalty for shortages be absorbed primarily by the agent in direct contact with them. In 6, we describe a family of contracts based on transfer payments between the two players that coordinate the system; for example, it allows the decentralized system to achieve the same cost as the centralized system. The payments are selected in such a way that each player transfers a fixed fraction of its own cost to the other player. The resulting cost structure mimics a cost-sharing agreement and thus coordinates the system. In 7, we analyze the Stackelberg games, where one agent has all the bargaining power. In terms of efficiency, the retailer s Stackelberg game dominates the supplier s Stackelberg game. However, from a customer service perspective, the supplier s Stackelberg game is preferable. Concluding remarks, including a comparison of our results to those of Cachon and Zipkin (1999), are presented in The Model Our idealized supply chain consists of a supplier providing a single product to a retailer. Retailer demand is modeled as a homogeneous Poisson process with rate. The retailer carries inventory to service this demand, and unsatisfied demand is backordered. Because we assume that there are no fixed ordering costs, the retailer s optimal replenishment policy (given the supplier s irreversible capacity decision, described below) is characterized by a (s 1s) base-stock policy. That is, the inventory initially contains s units, and the retailer places an order for one unit with the supplier at each epoch of the Poisson demand process. The supplier s production facility is modeled as a single-server queue with service times that are exponentially distributed with rate. The supplier is responsible for choosing the parameter, which will also be referred to as the capacity. The server is only busy when retailer orders are present in the queue. The supplier s facility behaves as a M/M/1 queue because the demand process is Poisson and a basestock policy is used. This setting, in which the supplier does not store finished goods, often holds when both agents are within the same company, or the supplier s sole customer is the retailer. In our model, the selling price that the retailer charges the customer, the wholesale price that the retailer pays to the supplier, and the supplier s variable production cost, are assumed to be given and constant. These conditions hold, for example, if we assume that the retailer and supplier operate in competitive markets. Because demand is exogenous, unsatisfied demand is backordered, and we use a long-run average cost criterion, it follows that the agents revenues are independent of their actions, as long as their utilities are nonnegative. Hence, profit maximization and cost minimization lead to the same solution, and we employ a cost-minimization framework. Each backordered unit generates a cost b per unit of time for the production-inventory system. As in Cachon and Zipkin (1999), this backorder cost is split between the two agents, with a fraction 0 1 incurred by the retailer. The parameter, which we refer to as the retailer s backorder share, is exogenously specified in our model. Because much of the academic literature assumes = 1, this assumption requires some discussion. The value of depends on a variety of factors, such as the structures of the market and distribution channel, and the customers expectations Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter

4 (e.g., Stern et al. 1996). At one extreme, if the supplier has a monopolistic (or well established) position in the market and uses an intensive distribution strategy with many competing retailers, then customers facing an inventory shortage at one retailer may buy the product from a different retailer. In this case, will be near 1 and the retailer will bear the brunt of the backorder costs. At the other extreme, suppose the supplier is in a competitive market and either the retailer has a monopoly at the distribution level or the supplier uses an exclusive distribution strategy with a single retailer. In this situation, poor customer service at the retailer level will mostly harm the supplier; for example, will be near 0. Of course, various intermediate situations generate less extreme values of. In addition, the retailer incurs a cost for holding units in inventory. The retailer s holding cost includes both physical and financial components, and is, in general, not the same in the centralized and decentralized systems. More specifically, the financial holding cost is proportional to the retailer s purchase cost, which is the supplier s production cost in the centralized system and the sum of the production cost and the supplier s profit margin in the decentralized system. Therefore, we expect the holding cost to be larger in the decentralized case, which is a source of inefficiency with respect to the centralized chain (e.g., Gallego and Boyaci 2002). For simplicity, however, we do not make this distinction here. That is, we assume that there is single holding cost h per unit of inventory per unit of time paid by the retailer independent of the supply chain configuration. This assumption is reasonable if the supplier s margin is small, which may hold if the supplier and retailer belong to the same company or are in industries in which physical holding costs dominate financial holding costs and/or there is a competitive market of low-margin suppliers. On the other hand, the supplier pays the fixed cost of building production capacity. The capacity cost parameter c is per unit of product, so that c represents the amortized cost per unit of time that the supplier incurs for having the capacity ; this fixed cost rate is independent of the demand level. To make our results more transparent, we normalize the expected variable cost per unit time by dividing it by the holding cost rate h. Toward this end, we normalize the cost parameters as follows: h = h h = 1 b b = h c c = h (1) To ease the notation, we hereafter omit the tildes from these cost parameters. Let N be the steady-state number of orders at the supplier s manufacturing facility. If we assume for now that > (this point is revisited later), then N is geometrically distributed with mean 1, where = (2) This parameter, which represents the normalized excess capacity, is the supplier s decision variable in our analysis, and we often refer to it simply as capacity. To simplify our analysis, we assume that N is a continuous random variable, and replace the geometric distribution by an exponential distribution with parameter. This continuous-state approximation can be justified by a heavy traffic approximation (e.g., 10 of Harrison 1988), and generates mean queue lengths that coincide with M/M/1 results for all server utilization levels. The heavy traffic approximation allows the incorporation of general interarrival time and service time distributions; in the nonexponential case, in Equation (2) would be divided by one-half of the sum of the squared coefficients of variation of the interarrival and service time distributions, ca 2 + c2 s /2, but we do not pursue this avenue here. Although this continuous-state approximation leads to slightly different quantitative results (the approximation tends to underestimate the optimal discrete base-stock level), it has no effect on the qualitative system behavior, which is the object of our study. The steady-state expected normalized variable cost per unit time for the risk-neutral retailer (C R ) and supplier C S ) in terms of the two decision variables are given by C R s = Es N + + b EN s + and = s 1 e s + b e s (3) C S s = 1 b EN s + + c = 1 b e s + c (4) 4 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003

5 3. The Centralized Solution As a reference point for the efficiency of the two-agent system, we start by finding the optimal solution to the centralized version of the problem, where there is a single decision maker that simultaneously optimizes the base-stock level s and the normalized excess capacity. The steady-state expected normalized cost per unit time C for this decision maker is Cs = C R s + C S s 1 b + 1e s = c + s (5) The centralized solution is given in Proposition 1; see the Appendix for the proof. Proposition 1. The optimal centralized solution is the unique solution to the first-order conditions Cs = 0 s = ln1 + b (6) s Cs = 0 b + 1s + 1 e s c 2 = 0 (7) and is given by ln1 + b = c The resulting cost is and s = c ln1 + b (8) Cs = 2 c ln1 + b (9) By relation (6), the ratio of the base-stock level, s, to the supplier s mean queue length, 1, satisfies s = ln1 + b at optimality. (The corresponding firstorder conditions for the discrete inventory problem is ln + 1s = ln1 + b, and so our continuous approximation can be viewed as using the Taylor series approximation ln + 1.) Although this ratio is independent of the capacity cost c, the optimal solution depends on c via s = c according to Equation (8). As expected, the optimal capacity level decreases with the capacity cost and increases with the backorder-to-holding cost ratio b. Similarly, because capacity and safety stock provide alternative means to avoid backorders, the optimal base-stock level increases with the capacity cost and with the normalized backorder cost b. Finally, as expected, plays no role in this single-agent optimization, because transfer payments between the retailer and the supplier do not affect the centralized cost. 4. The Nash Solution Under the Nash equilibrium concept, the retailer chooses s to minimize C R s, assuming that the supplier chooses to minimize C S s ; likewise, the supplier simultaneously chooses to minimize C S s, assuming the retailer chooses s to minimize C R s. Because each agent s strategy is a best response to the other s, neither agent is motivated to depart from this equilibrium. In anticipation of subsequent analysis, we express the Nash equilibrium in terms of the retailer s backorder share. Let us also define the auxiliary function f b = 1 bln1 + b + 1 (10) 1 + b ln1 + b which plays a prominent role in our analysis. Proposition 2. The unique Nash equilibrium is = f b (11) ( ) ln1 + b s = s (12) ln1 + bf b The resulting costs, CR and C S, are C R = C Rs = s ( ) (13) ln1 + b + 2 C S = C Ss = c ln1 + b + 1 (14) Proof. Let s be the retailer s reaction curve, for example, the optimal base-stock level given a capacity installed by the supplier. Because Equation (3) is concave in s, s is characterized by the first-order condition s = ln1 + b (15) Using a similar argument, we find that the supplier s reaction curve s satisfies ( ) e ss ss + 1 c = ss 2 1 bs (16) 2 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter

6 The unique solution to Equations (15) (16) is Equations (11) (12), and substituting this solution into Equations (3) (4) yields Equations (13) (14). Because f b is decreasing in and ln1 + b is increasing in for b>0, it follows that as increases, the retailer becomes more concerned with backorders and increases his base-stock level, while the supplier cares less about backorders and builds less excess capacity. The supplier s variable cost CS is a monotonically decreasing function of that satisfies CS 0 = 2 bc and CS 1 = 0 and C R is a monotonically increasing function of that satisfies C R0 = 0 lim 1 C R + (17) as shown in Figure 1. (Many of the limits taken in this paper, for example, 1, are implicitly taken to be one-sided.) To understand the unbounded retailer losses in Equation (17), note that for the extreme case = 1, the supplier does not face any backorder cost and consequently has no incentive to build excess capacity, for instance, 1 = 0. This corresponds to the null recurrent case of a queueing system with an arrival rate equal to its service rate. Consequently, the retailer is unable to maintain finite inventory (backorder plus holding) costs, and the supply chain is not operational in the Nash equilibrium. Figure 1 2 bc 5 The Retailer s C R and Supplier s C S Costs in the Nash Equilibrium as a Function of the Retailer s Backorder Share C S *(α) C R *(α) Comparison of Solutions In this section, we compare the centralized solution and the Nash equilibrium with respect to the total system cost, the agents decisions, and the customer service level. The Nash Equilibrium Is Inefficient. The centralized solution is not achievable as a Nash equilibrium. By Equations (6) and (15), the first-order conditions are s = ln1 + b in the centralized solution and s = ln1 + b in the Nash solution. Hence, the two solutions are not equal when <1, and the Nash equilibrium in the = 1 case is an unstable system, as discussed earlier. The source of this inefficiency is the inability of the agents to fully replicate the centralized cost structure. The magnitude of the inefficiency of a Nash equilibrium is typically quantified by comparing the costs under the centralized and Nash solutions. We follow Cachon and Zipkin (1999) and compute the competition penalty, which is defined as the percentage increase in variable cost of the Nash equilibrium over the centralized solution. By Equations (5) and (8), the variable cost for the centralized solution is Cs = (s 1 ) s s e + b e + c = 2 c ln1 + b and the variable cost C associated with the Nash equilibrium is, by Equations (3) (4) and Proposition 2, C = C Ss + C Rs [ = f b ( ln1 + b + 2 ln1 + b + 1 ) + Hence, the competition penalty is where C Cs Cs 100% P b = C Cs Cs = 1 [ ( ) ln1 + b + 2 f 2 b ln1 + b ] ln1 + b s ln1 + bf b ln1 + b ln1 + bf b ] 1 (18) 6 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003

7 Surprisingly, the competition penalty in Equation (18) is independent of the supplier s cost of capacity. This occurs because the centralized variable cost and the Nash variable cost are both proportional to c at optimality, which is a consequence of the particular functional form arising from the make-to-stock formulation. This penalty is a function of and b, and we can simplify Equation (18) for the limiting values of these two parameters. The function f b is decreasing in and f 1 b = 0. Hence, the competition penalty goes to as 1. This inefficiency occurs because, as the retailer bears more of the backorder cost, the supplier builds less excess capacity, and in the limit the lack of excess capacity causes instability of the queueing system. At the other extreme, f b b/ln1 + b as 0, and the competition penalty in this case is given by b 1 for b>0 (19) ln1 + b This function is increasing in b, approaches zero as b 0 and grows to as b. Hence, when the supplier incurs most of the backorder cost, the retailer holds very little inventory and the competition penalty depends primarily on the backorder cost; if this cost is low then the supplier has little incentive to build excess capacity, which leads to a small competition penalty because the centralized planner holds neither safety stock nor excess capacity in this case. In contrast, if the backorder cost is very high, the supplier cannot overcome the retailer s lack of safety stock, and his backorders get out of control, leading to high inefficiency. Turning to the backorder cost asymptotics, f b 1 / as b, and the competition penalty approaches (20) 1 This quantity vanishes at = 05, is symmetric about = 05, and approaches as 0 and 1. Thus, when backorders are very expensive, this cost component dominates both agents objective functions when they care equally about backorders ( = 05), and their cost functions and hence decisions coincide with the centralized solution. However, when there is a severe imbalance in the backorder allocation ( is near 0 or 1), one of the agents does not build enough of his buffer resource, and the other agent cannot prevent many costly backorders, which is highly inefficient from the viewpoint of the entire supply chain. Finally, for the case b 0, the competition penalty is given by (21) 1 which is an increasing function of. Consistent with the previous analysis, this penalty function vanishes as 0 and approaches as 1. In summary, there are two regimes, ( = 05b ) and 0b 0), where the Nash equilibrium is asymptotically efficient, and two regimes, 1 and ( 0b ), where the inefficiency of the Nash solution is arbitrarily large. However, because Equation (18) does not consider the agents participation constraints, some of the large inefficiencies in the latter regimes may not be attainable by the supply chain (see Caldentey and Wein 1999). To complement these asymptotic results, we plot in Figure 2 the competition penalty in Equation (18) for various values of b as a function of. A new insight emerges from Figure 2. The competition penalty is minimized by near 0.5 (i.e., the backorder cost is split evenly) when the backorder-to-holding cost ratio b 1. Comparison of Decision Variables. Figure 3 depicts the optimal Nash production capacity and the optimal Nash base-stock level s as a function of, and allows us to compare these functions to the centralized solutions, and s. Excess capacity and the base-stock level are alternative ways for the supplier and retailer, respectively, to buffer against demand uncertainty, and Figure 3 shows that the inefficiency of the Nash solution does not necessarily imply that these agents have less buffer resources in the Nash solution than in the centralized solution. For both decision variables, there exist thresholds on the value of, denoted by s and in Figure 3, that divide the regions where the agents have more or less buffer resources than the optimal centralized solution. However, as shown in the next proposition, at least one Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter

8 Figure 2 The Competition Penalty in Equation (18) in the Absence of Participation Constraints for Different Values of the Backorder-to-Holding Cost Ratio b as a Function of Competition Penalty b=10 b= b=1 0.1 b= α agent in the Nash equilibrium possesses less of his buffer resource than the central planner. Proposition 3. For s and defined in Figure 3, we have s >. Proof. By Figure 3, if s then there exists ˆ s such that ˆ s ˆ s However, this inequality together with Equations (6) and (15) implies that f ˆ b = ln1 + b, for example, ˆ = 1. But for = 1 the supply chain is unstable and does not operate. Hence, s < s for 0 1, and consequently s >. The parameters s and can be used in the following way. Let be the value of the retailer s backorder share that minimizes the competition penalty in Equation (18). Then computational experiments show that for b 1, the approximation s + /2 has an absolute error bounded by Thus, in the case where the backorder cost is well quantified (e.g., a price discount for waiting, or the financial cost of delayed payments), knowledge of s and can be used to negotiate a contract that shifts the retailer s backorder share towards. For instance, if < then the contract should include a fee of b that the retailer pays to the supplier per unit of backorder per unit time, which would change the retailer s backorder share to. Similarly, if > then the supplier Figure 3 ν The Optimal Nash Production Capacity and the Optimal Nash Base-Stock Level s as a Function of the Retailer s Backorder Share The Centralized Solutions Are and s. (a) ν α 0 α ν 1 0 α s 1 s (b) s α 8 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003

9 should pay the retailer a fee of b per unit of backorder per unit time. This contract, while suboptimal, is conceptually simpler than the linear transfer payment in 6. We cannot solve for s and in closed form, except when b takes on a limiting value. By Equation (12), s satisfies ln1 + b = 1 (22) ln1 + bf b As b 0, we have f b 1 and ln1 + b/ ln1 + b. Therefore, as b 0, s satisfies / 1 = 1 or s = 5 1/2 0618, which is the inverse of the golden-section number that arises in a variety of disciplines (e.g., Vajda 1989). As b, we have f b 1 /, and ln1 + b/ ln1 + b. In this case, s satisfies /1 = 1, or s = 05. Numerical computations reveal that s is unimodal in b, achieving a maximum of at b = 148, and is rather insensitive to moderate values of the backorder-to-holding cost ratio b (e.g., s 061 for b 1 10). In other words, for moderate values of the normalized backorder cost, the Nash retailer holds more inventory than optimal when his share of the backorder cost is more than about 61%. By Equation (11), solves f b = 1; for example, when the normalized backorder cost is small, the Nash supplier holds a less-than-optimal level of capacity. As b 0, this condition becomes 1 = 1, which gives = 0. As b, the condition becomes 1 / = 1, which is solved by = 05. Note that s = = 05 asb is consistent with our previous claim that the Nash equilibrium is asymptotically efficient in the regime ( = 05b ). A numerical study reveals that is more sensitive than s to the value of b. As the backorder-to-holding cost ratio b varies from 1 to 10, ranges from 028 to 049. Customer Service Level. The exponential distribution of the queue length implies that the steady-state probability that a customer is forced to wait because of retailer shortages is equal to PrN s = e s ; consequently, we refer to 1 e s 100% as the service level. By Equations (6) and (15), the stockout probability e s equals 1 + b 1 in the centralized solution and 1+b 1 in the Nash solution. Hence, customers receive better service in the centralized solution than in the Nash equilibrium. This is because (see Figure 3) the product of the two buffer resources (normalized excess capacity and base-stock level) is always smaller in the Nash equilibrium than in the centralized solution, and the customers suffer from this lessthan-optimal level of collective buffer resource; this degradation in customer service in decentralized systems also occurs in the traditional bilateral monopoly model (e.g., Tirole 1997), where double marginalization leads to a higher price charged to the customer and less goods sold. Finally, even though the system is not stable for = 1, customers generally desire a larger value of ; for example, they prefer that the penalty for shortages be absorbed primarily by the agent in direct contact with them. 6. Contracts We showed in 5 that the Nash equilibrium is always inefficient when the supply chain operates. In this section, we analyze a coordinating mechanism based on static transfer payments between the agents. Specifically, we assume that the supplier (or the retailer) agrees to transfer a fixed amount per unit time to the retailer (supplier) in order to improve his operations and eventually the operation of the whole chain. In its most general form, this transfer depends on both s and. As in our earlier analysis, this information is assumed to be common knowledge. Cachon and Zipkin (1999) also use a linear transfer payment based on inventory levels to coordinate their supply chain, and readers are referred to 1.5 of Cachon (1999a) for a survey of alternative types of contracts in the multiechelon inventory setting. We do not impose an explicit constraint that forces either agent to build a predefined level of its buffer resource. Using Cachon and Lariviere s (2001) terminology, we assume a voluntary compliance regime, where both the retailer and the supplier choose their buffer resource levels to maximize their own profits. The transfer payment s modifies the cost functions in Equations (3) and (4) for the retailer and supplier, respectively, to C R s = C R s s and C S s = C S s + s (23) Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter

10 The choice of s that coordinates the system is not unique. One possibility is to define the transfer in such a way that the modified cost functions replicate a cost-sharing situation. That is, we can set s such that C S s = Cs and C R s = 1 Cs, where 0 1 is a splitting factor and Cs is the centralized cost function defined in Equation (5). This cost sharing forces the transfer payment to satisfy s = C R s 1 C S s (24) In this situation, both agents have an objective that is a scaled version of the centralized one. Therefore, supplier and retailer have aligned objectives and the centralized solution s is the unique Nash equilibrium. We notice that the transfer payment has two components. First, C R s is a payment made by the supplier to the retailer proportional to the retailer s cost. Similarly, 1 C S s corresponds to a payment made by the retailer to the supplier proportional to the supplier s cost. In other words, each agent transfers a fraction of its own cost to the other player. Although we appear to have a degree of freedom in splitting the costs via, both agents must be better off under the Nash equilibrium with the transfer payments than under the Nash equilibrium without the transfer payments, for example, C R s 1 Cs C S s Cs (25) This condition can be rewritten as b b, where ln1 + b b = 1 2ln1 + bf b b = f b 2 ( ln1 + b + 2 ln1 + b + 1 and ) (26) In addition, has to be in the 0 1 range. If not, one of the players would have a negative cost function. In such a situation, the optimal strategy for this player is to increase as much as possible the absolute value of its cost. For example, if <0 then the supplier has a negative cost function and his/her best strategy is to pick as large as possible independently of the value of s. To summarize, the centralized solution can be achieved using the transfer payment (Equation 24) if and only if b b 0 1. It is not hard to show that b b, b < 1, and b 0; hence, coordination is always possible using this type of contract. This conclusion stems from the fact that the Nash equilibrium is inefficient and the cost reduction obtained using the centralized solution can be split, making both agents better off. After some algebra we get b = C Ss Cs P b and b = C Ss Cs where P b is the competition penalty defined in Equation (18). Notice that the range of admissible (those that effectively coordinate the system), and hence the ease of negotiation, increases with the magnitude of the competition penalty. Two extreme cases deserve particular attention: b < 0 and b > 1. In these situations, there exists a coordinating contract having one of the agents fully subsidizing the other agent s operation, for example, = 0 or = 1. When b < 0 it is profitable for the retailer to absorb the supplier s variable cost (the reverse is true when b > 1) 1. This type of behavior, where large manufacturers pay for their supplier s capital equipment, has been observed in the automobile industry (e.g., Dyer and Ouchi 1993, Dyer et al. 1998), although for reasons related to maintaining long-term supplier relationships and bearing the risk of low future demand. As b goes to infinity the lower and upper bounds converge to lim b b= and lim b= 1 b 2 1 Hence as b the conditions b = 0 and b = 1 hold for = 08 and = 02, respectively. At the other extreme, as b goes to zero the bounds are lim b 0 b = and lim b 0 b = 1 1 If an agent is fully subsidized then any strategy is optimal and so it is not necessarily true that he/she will pick the optimal centralized solution. To avoid this technicality, it suffices that the player that absorbs all the cost offers a small fee to the subsidized player if he/she picks the optimal centralized solution. 10 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003

11 Figure 4 Solution to b = 0 and b = 1 Backorder allocation fraction ( ) Retailer is willing to pay the supplier's cost Supplier is willing to pay the retailer's cost Backorder-to-holding cost ratio (b) In this case, the roots for 0 = 0 and 0 = 1 are = and = 0, respectively. Figure 4 plots the solution to b = 0 (upper curve) and b = 1 (lower curve). Roughly speaking, we can show that for 08 the retailer is willing to pay the supplier s cost in order to achieve coordination and the opposite holds for 02. As we pointed out, the transfer payment in (24) replicates a cost-sharing situation in which both agents agree upfront to split the total cost of the supply chain. From a practical perspective, however, a direct cost-sharing negotiation based on total cost probably dominates the transfer-payment approach because it does not require any special accounting of cost (in terms of capacity and backordering costs) and it is more familiar, transparent, robust (with respect to model misspecifications), and easier to implement. 7. The Stackelberg Games We conclude our study of this two-stage supply chain by considering the case where one agent dominates. Supplier s Stackelberg Game. When the supplier is the Stackelberg leader, he chooses to optimize C S s in Equation (4), given the retailer s best response, s in Equation (15). This straightforward computation leads to the following proposition. Proposition 4. In the absence ofparticipation constraints, the equilibrium in the supplier s Stackelberg game is s = s 1 + ln1 + b = 1 + ln1 + b (27) The agents costs are 1 bc C S s = b C R s = s (28) Equation (27) implies that s = s, and hence the customer service level is the same under the Stackelberg and Nash equilibria. Because the first-order conditions of the centralized problem dictate the service level, it also follows that the Stackelberg equilibrium is inefficient relative to the centralized solution. Not surprisingly, the supplier builds less capacity and the retailer holds more safety stock in Equation (27) than in the Nash equilibrium. The discrepancy between the Stackelberg and Nash solutions increases as and b increase. Now we compare the variable cost of each agent and the entire system under the Nash and Stackelberg equilibria. By Equation (14), the supplier s cost in the Nash equilibrium can be written as ( ) C S s = 2 1 bc ln1 + b b 2 ln1 + b + 1 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter

12 The function x + 2/2 x + 1 is strictly increasing in 0, and is equal to 1 when x = 0. Thus, it is always the case that C S s C S s ; this is to be expected, because the supplier incorporates the retailer s best response when selecting his level of capacity. However, C S s = C S s when = 0, = 1orb = 0, and so the supplier does not benefit from being the leader in these extreme cases. When = 1orb = 0, the supplier does not face any backorder costs and builds no excess capacity ( = 0). On the other hand, when = 0 the retailer incurring no backorder costs holds no safety stock (s = 0). Because these choices ( = 0 and s = 0) are independent of the bargaining power of the supplier in these cases, the Stackelberg and Nash equilibria provide the same cost to the supplier. By Equations (13) and (27), the difference in the retailer s cost between the Stackelberg equilibrium and the Nash equilibrium is ( ) C R s C R s = s 1 + ln1 + b 1 (29) As expected, the retailer is worse off in the supplier s Stackelberg equilibrium than in the Nash equilibrium. By Equations (8), (10), (12), and (29), the increase in the retailer s cost from being the follower vanishes as 0 and b 0 (similar to the reasons given in the previous paragraph), and grows with and b. As gets larger, the supplier cares less about backorders and builds less capacity, leaving the retailer in a vulnerable situation. A comparison of the total system cost shows that C R s + C Ss C R s + C S s if and only if 1 + b ln1 + b 1 + ln1 + b (30) 1 b Condition (30) holds for large values of, but is not true in general. Because the left side of condition (30) equals zero when = 0, is increasing in 0 if it is increasing in at 0, and has a derivative with respect to equal to 1 b/2 when = 0, we conclude that for a backorder-to-holding cost ratio b 2 the Nash solution achieves a lower system cost than the Stackelberg equilibrium for any value of. Ifb>2, the Nash solution is more efficient if and only if >, where is the unique positive value of that solves condition (30) with equality. Hence, overall system performance suffers when the retailer incurs most of the expensive backorder costs, and as the follower has less power than in the Nash equilibrium to control these costs. Retailer s Stackelberg Game. The Stackelberg problem is less tractable when the retailer is the leader. The following proposition (see the Appendix for a proof) characterizes the solution. Proposition 5. Let ˆ ŝ be the equilibrium when the retailer is the Stackelberg leader in the absence ofparticipation constraints. Define ˆ 0 to be the unique nonnegative solution of ( 1 e s ) = 0 (31) Then the Stackelberg solution is 1 b ˆ + 1e ˆ = ˆ ŝ c = ˆ (32) ˆ Although we do not have a closed-form solution to the retailer s Stackelberg game, the next proposition (see the Appendix for a proof) provides a comparison between this equilibrium and the Nash equilibrium. Proposition 6. The following five inequalities hold: ˆ ŝ s (33) ˆ (34) ŝ s (35) C R ŝ ˆ C R s (36) C S ŝ ˆ C S s (37) While inequalities (34) (37) mirror our results for the supplier Stackelberg game, inequality (33) states that the customer service level, 1 e s 100%, is lower in the retailer s Stackelberg equilibrium than in the supplier s Stackelberg equilibrium (and the Nash equilibrium). Inequality (33) also implies that the retailer Stackelberg equilibrium is inefficient relative to the centralized solution. Analytical approximations (using e x 1 x in Equation 31) and numerical com- 12 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003

13 putations reveal that when the service level is close to 0 or 100%, both Stackelberg games have asymptotically the same service level. The maximum difference is approximately 9.5%, and is achieved when the service level is 76.0% for the supplier s Stackelberg game and 66.5% for the retailer s Stackelberg game. In a more practical example, if the supplier s Stackelberg service level is 90.0% then the retailer s Stackelberg service level is approximately 82%. Hence, the deterioration in customer service is not trivial, and if there is a leader the customers prefer that it is the supplier. This is because the base-stock level is more effective than the capacity level at controlling the customer service level, and the retailer chooses a small base-stock level when he is the leader. Figure 5 shows the competition penalty P for the Nash and Stackelberg games. The left graph plots P as a function of the backorder cost b for = 05. Consistent with our discussion in 5, for = 05 the competition penalty decreases with b for the Nash game. In contrast, for both Stackelberg games the competition penalty increases with the backorder rate. The other plot in Figure 5 displays the competition penalty as a function of for b = 2. The inefficiency for the three games is U-shaped, and is minimized near = 05. Moreover, all three games have a similar level of inefficiency as 0 and 1. Finally, Figure 5 also suggests that the retailer s Stackelberg game achieves a lower total system cost than the supplier s Stackelberg game. Evidently, the supplier, by owning the cost-driving resource, wreaks more havoc on his opponent as the leader than does the retailer. He holds less capacity, leading the retailer to incur considerable holding costs. The retailer holds less inventory (which is the customer-service-driving resource) when he leads, and the supplier s increase in capacity is not enough to compensate for the retailer s lower base-stock level; consequently, customer service suffers. 8. Concluding Remarks The distinguishing feature of our simple supply chain model is that congestion at the supplier s manufacturing facility is explicitly captured via a single-server queue. Each agent has a resource at his disposal (the Figure 5 Competition Penalty for the Nash Game N, the Supplier s Stackelberg Game S, and the Retailer s Stackelberg Game R Competition penalty (%) S R N Competition penalty (%) S R N Backorder-to-holding cost ratio (b) Backorder allocation fraction ( ) 1.0 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter

14 Table 1 A Summary of the Asymptotic Results b 0 b 0 <b< 0if 0 if 0 U-shaped as ranges Competition Penalty 0 if = 05 from0to1 (Nash Inefficiency) if 1 if 1 Customer Service Level Centr. = Nash Centr. = Nash Centr. Nash if 0 1 exp s Centr. = Nash if 1 s s s = root of (22) = 0 05 = root of f b = 1 Contract: Supplier Pays Retailer s Cost If = 0 02 b see condition (30) Retailer Pays Supplier s Cost If b see condition (30) supplier chooses the capacity level and the retailer chooses the base-stock level) that buffers against backorders. When the inventory backorder cost is incurred entirely by the retailer (i.e., the retailer s backorder share = 1), the supplier has no incentive to build any excess capacity, which leads to system instability. When the supplier incurs some backorder cost ( 0 1), there is a unique Nash equilibrium that is always inefficient: The agents selfish behavior degrades overall system performance. However, the Nash equilibrium is asymptotically efficient (a summary of all our asymptotic results is provided in Table 1) in two cases: (i) The backorder cost goes to zero and the supplier incurs all of the backorder cost, and (ii) the backorder cost goes to infinity and is split evenly between the two agents. The Nash equilibrium has an arbitrarily high inefficiency in two cases: (i) The backorder cost goes to infinity and the supplier incurs all of the backorder cost, and (ii) the retailer incurs all of the backorder cost. For most practical cases (i.e., backorder-to-holding cost ratio is greater than 2), the inefficiency of the Nash solution is smallest when the backorder costs are split relatively evenly between the two agents. This is likely to occur, for example, if the propensity of customers to switch brands (suppliers) or switch retailers is similar. Relative to the centralized solution, the agents in the Nash equilibrium have more buffer resources when they care sufficiently about backorders: The supplier builds more capacity than optimal when < (and 028 if backorders are more expensive than holding inventory) and the retailer has a larger than optimal base-stock level when >063 (and, in some cases, an even smaller threshold). However, at least one of the agents in the Nash equilibrium holds a lowerthan-optimal level of his buffer resource. Finally, customers receive better service in the centralized solution than in the Nash equilibrium, and customer service improves in the Nash setting when the retailer incurs most but not all of the backorder cost. A linear transfer payment that induces cost sharing between the players coordinates the system. In the absence of participation constraints, coordination is always possible. A coordinating contract requires the parties to negotiate on the value of a single parameter () that defines the split of the total system cost. The range of admissible values for increases with the magnitude of the inefficiency of the Nash equilibrium. Hence, negotiations should be easier when the backorder costs are not split too evenly. However, if an agent absorbs 80% or more of the system backorder cost then this agent is willing to sign a contract that fully subsidizes the other agent s operation. Consequently, our model predicts that vertical integration would preclude the widespread prevalence of decentralized supply chains with extreme values of. Although we did not incorporate participation constraints in the model, a straightforward analysis (see Caldentey and Wein (1999)) in a profit-maximization framework shows that there are values of (in the proximity of 0 and 1) for which the contract will lead to the operation of an otherwise inoperative supply chain, for example, the extra system profit generated 14 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003

15 by the contract is sufficient to entice the nonparticipating agent into playing. Finally, when one of the agents is the Stackelberg leader, he builds less of his buffer resource and faces a lower cost than in the Nash equilibrium, and the other agent builds more of his buffer resource and pays a higher cost. The total system cost is less in the retailer Stackelberg game than in the supplier Stackelberg game. Because scarce capacity causes a nonlinear increase in delay, the supplier s leadership power causes more harm to the supply chain than the retailer s leadership power. Customer service is the same in the Nash equilibrium as when the supplier is the Stackelberg leader, but customers fare worse when the retailer is the leader. This latter effect is because the retailer holds less inventory when he is the leader, and the base-stock level has a more direct impact on customer service than the supplier s capacity. Taken together, these results provide operations managers with a comprehensive understanding of the competitive interactions in this system, and offer guidelines for when (i.e., for which sets of problem parameters) and how to negotiate contracts to induce participation and increase profits. Recall that our model is quite similar to the twostage inventory model of Cachon and Zipkin (1999): The main difference is the single-server vs. infiniteserver model (i.e., queueing vs. inventory model) for the manufacturing process. Indeed, these two models can be viewed as the simplest prototypes for singleproduct, steady-state supply chains with no fixed ordering costs. In the extreme case when the supplier does not care about backorders ( = 1), he builds no excess capacity in our queueing model, whereas he holds no inventory in Cachon and Zipkin s inventory model. The effect of the former is an unstable system, while the effect of the latter is to turn the supply chain into a stable albeit ineffective make-to-order system. In Cachon and Zipkin s echelon inventory game, the Nash solution is indeed highly inefficient when = 1, but in the local inventory game the median inefficiency in their computational study is only 1%. When = 1 in the local inventory game, the supplier s base-stock level offers him little control over the system s cost, whereas the capacity level in our model impacts the entire system in a more profound way. On the other hand, both models predict that the inefficiency is small when the backorder costs are shared equally. Another qualitative difference between the results in these two papers is that Cachon and Zipkin s agents typically hold less inventory (for the echelon inventory game) in the Nash equilibrium than in the centralized solution, whereas our agents build/hold a higher-than-optimal level of their buffer resource when their share of the backorder cost is large, as suggested in the management literature by Buzzell and Ortmeyer (1995) and others. In our view, the make-to-stock queue is an attractive operations management model to embed into a game-theoretic framework. The model complements the newsvendor model by considering products with long life cycles, and is about as complex as but considerably more tractable than a two-stage Clark- Scarf model. It also allows us to capture the nonlinear effect of capacity on the supplier s lead times. Of course, none of these models attempt to mimic the complexities of an actual supply chain. Nevertheless, to the extent that queueing effects are present in manufacturers production facilities, the make-tostock queue is a parsimonious and tractable model for deriving new insights into multiagent models for supply chain management. Acknowledgments The authors are grateful to Gérard Cachon for valuable discussions and to the Senior Editor and two referees for their extraordinary efforts, which significantly improved the paper s content and presentation. Appendix Proof of Proposition 1. The function Cs defined in Equation (5) is continuously differentiable and bounded below by 0 in X = s s 0 >0. Thus, a global minimum is either a local interior minimum that satisfies the first-order conditions or an element of the boundary of X; alternatively, there could be no global minimum if the function decreases as s or. However, we have checked that lim s Cs for >0, and lim Cs for s 0, which implies that a global minimum exists. From the first-order conditions (6) and (7), the only interior point that is a candidate for the global minimum is s. In addition, the Hessian of Cs at s is given by Hs = s s cln1 + b+ 2 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter

16 Because ln1 + b > 0 for b>0, the Hessian is positive definite and s is the unique local minimum in the interior of X. The resulting cost is Cs = 2 c ln1 + b. Finally, lim 0 Cs for s 0 and C0= b c 2 cb > Cs for >0b>0 Thus, s is the unique global minimum for s. Proof of Proposition 5. To derive the Stackelberg equilibrium, we find it convenient to define e ( = s (38) and rewrite the supplier s reaction curve (Equation 16) as ) = c 1 bs 2 (39) The one-to-one correspondence between the base-stock level s and the service level parameter (recall that the service level is e 100%) allows the retailer in this Stackelberg game to choose rather than s. By Equations (3) and (38), the retailer s cost is ( ) be C R = (40) Solving Equation (39) for s and using Equation (38) gives 1 b + 1e = (41) c Substituting Equation (41) into Equation (40) yields the retailer s cost as the following convex function of 0: c C R = 1 b Therefore, the first-order condition ( be + 1e ) (42) be = 0 (43) e 2 is sufficient for optimality. Because 1 + b = e s and the denominator of condition (43) is always positive, condition (43) is equivalent to Equation (31). Hence, by Equations (31), (38), and (41), the Stackelberg equilibrium is given by Equations (31) and (32). Proof of Proposition 6. To prove Equation (33), note that the left side of Equation (31) is positive if > s. Thus, the root ˆ of Equation (31) must satisfy ˆ s, for example, ˆ ŝ s. To show that ˆ and ŝ s, we first observe that s = arg min >0 C R s and 2 C R s /s = 1 bse s 0 Thus (e.g., Chapter 2 of Topkis 1998), C R s satisfies the decreasing difference property, ds 0 (44) ds In addition, the function e +1/ 2 is decreasing in >0. Hence, from Equation (39) and inequality (33), we conclude that ŝ s. Finally, Equation (44) and ŝ s implies that ˆ. The retailer s cost in Equation (42) is an increasing function of for ˆ. Hence, inequality (36) follows from inequality (33). To prove Equation (37), for example, C S C S ˆ ˆ, we first use Equation (4) to rewrite the supplier s cost as ( ) 1 be C S = c + The function C S is decreasing in for >0, and so inequality (33) implies that C S ˆ C S ˆ ˆ. Hence the proof of Equation (37) will follow if we can show that C S C S ˆ. For any fixed nonnegative, the function C S is convex in, achieves its only minimum at 1 be = c and is increasing for. In particular, we have 1 b = c1 + b 1 b c1 + b 1 + ln1 + b = This inequality and Equation (34) imply that C S C S ˆ, which completes the proof of Equation (37). References Agrawal, N., S. Nahmias, A. Tsay Modeling supply chain contracts: A review. S. Tayur, M. Magazine, R. Ganeshan, eds. Quantitative Models for Supply Chain Management. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, MA. Anupindi, R., Y. Bassok Supply contracts with quantity commitments and stochastic demand. S. Tayur, M. Magazine, R. Ganeshan, eds. Quantitative Models for Supply Chain Management. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, MA. Buzacott, J. A., S. Price, J. G. Shanthikumar Service levels in multistage MRP and base stock controlled production systems. G. Fandel, T. Gulledge, A. Jones, eds. New Directions for Operations Research in Manufacturing. Springer, Berlin, Germany. Buzzell, R., G. Ortmeyer Channel partnerships streamline distribution. Sloan Management Rev Cachon, G. 1999a. Competitive supply chain inventory management. S. Tayur, M. Magazine, R. Ganeshan, eds. Quantitative Models for Supply Chain Management. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, MA b. Competitive and cooperative inventory management in a two-echelon supply chain with lost sales. Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, Durham, NC., M. Lariviere Contracting to assure supply: How to share demand forecasts in a supply chain. Management Sci , P. Zipkin Competitive and cooperative inventory policies in a two-stage supply chain. Management Sci Caldentey, R., L. M. Wein Analysis of a decentralized production-inventory system. Working paper, Sloan School of Management, MIT, Cambridge, MA. 16 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 2003

17 Chen, F Decentralized supply chains subject to information delays. Management Sci , A. Federgruen, Y. Zheng Coordination mechanisms for a distribution system with one supplier and multiple retailers. Management Sci Clark, A., H. Scarf Optimal policies for a multi-echelon inventory problem. Management Sci Duenyas, I., C.-Y. Tsai Centralized and decentralized control of a two-stage tandem manufacturing system with demand for intermediate and end products. Working paper, Business School, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI. Dyer, J., W. Ouchi Japanese-style partnerships: Giving companies a competitive edge. Sloan Management Rev , D. S. Cho, W. Chu Strategic supplier segmentation: The next best practice in supply chain management. California Management Rev Federgruen, A., Z. Katalan The stochastic economic lot scheduling problem: Cyclical base stock policies with idle times. Management Sci , P. Zipkin An inventory model with limited production capacity and uncertain demands, I: The average-cost criterion. Math. Oper. Res Gavirneni, S., R. Kapuscinski, S. Tayur Value of information in capacitated supply chains. Management Sci Glasserman P., S. Tayur Sensitivity analysis for base stock levels in multi-echelon production-inventory systems. Management Sci Harrison, J. M Brownian models of queueing networks with heterogeneous customer populations. W. Fleming, P. L. Lions, eds. Stochastic Differential Systems, Stochastic Control Theory and Applications, IMA vol. 10. Springer-Verlag, New York. Lariviere, M Supply chain contracting and coordination with stochastic demand. S. Tayur, M. Magazine, R. Ganeshan, eds. Quantitative Models for Supply Chain Management. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, MA. Lee, Y. J., P. Zipkin Tandem queues with planned inventories. Oper. Res Markowitz, D. M., M. I. Reiman, L. M. Wein The stochastic economic lot scheduling problem: Heavy traffic analysis of dynamic cyclic policies. Oper. Res Morse, P Queues, Inventories and Maintenance. Wiley, New York. Plambeck, E. L., S. A. Zenios Incentive efficient control of a make-to-stock production system. Working paper, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. Rubio, R., L. M. Wein Setting base stock levels using productform queueing networks. Management Sci Stern, L. W., I. El-Ansary, A. T. Coughlan Marketing Channels. Prentice Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Tirole, J The Theory of Industrial Organization. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Topkis, D. M Supermodularity and Complementarity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Tsay, A. A., W. S. Lovejoy Quantity flexibility contracts and supply chain performance. Manufacturing and Service Oper. Management Vajda, S Fibonacci and Lucas Numbers, and the Golden Section: Theory and Applications. Ellis Horwood Limited, England. Wein, L. M Dynamic scheduling of a multiclass make-tostock queue. Oper. Res Zheng, Y., P. Zipkin A queueing model to analyze the value of centralized inventory information. Oper. Res The consulting Senior Editor for this manuscript was William Lovejoy. This manuscript was received on November 30, 1999, and was with the authors 710 days for 5 revisions. The average review cycle time was 71 days. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management/Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter

Information Sharing in Supply Chain Management: A Literature Review on Analytical Research

Information Sharing in Supply Chain Management: A Literature Review on Analytical Research Information Sharing in Supply Chain Management: A Literature Review on Analytical Research Hyun-cheol Paul Choi California State University, Fullerton, CA In this paper, we reviewed the area of upstream

More information

Competition and Cooperation in a Two-Stage Supply Chain with Demand Forecasts

Competition and Cooperation in a Two-Stage Supply Chain with Demand Forecasts OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 58, No. 5, September October 2010, pp. 1350 1363 issn 0030-364X eissn 1526-5463 10 5805 1350 informs doi 10.1287/opre.1100.0809 2010 INFORMS Competition and Cooperation in a Two-Stage

More information

Companies often face nonstationary demand due to product life cycles and seasonality, and nonstationary

Companies often face nonstationary demand due to product life cycles and seasonality, and nonstationary MANUFACTURING & SERVICE OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT Vol. 14, No. 3, Summer 2012, pp. 414 422 ISSN 1523-4614 (print) ISSN 1526-5498 (online) http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/msom.1110.0373 2012 INFORMS Single-Stage

More information

A QUEUEING-INVENTORY SYSTEM WITH DEFECTIVE ITEMS AND POISSON DEMAND. bhaji@usc.edu

A QUEUEING-INVENTORY SYSTEM WITH DEFECTIVE ITEMS AND POISSON DEMAND. bhaji@usc.edu A QUEUEING-INVENTORY SYSTEM WITH DEFECTIVE ITEMS AND POISSON DEMAND Rasoul Hai 1, Babak Hai 1 Industrial Engineering Department, Sharif University of Technology, +98-1-66165708, hai@sharif.edu Industrial

More information

DECENTRALIZED INVENTORY CONTROL IN A TWO-STAGE CAPACITATED SUPPLY CHAIN. and Fikri Karaesmen

DECENTRALIZED INVENTORY CONTROL IN A TWO-STAGE CAPACITATED SUPPLY CHAIN. and Fikri Karaesmen DECENTRALIZED INVENTORY CONTROL IN A TWO-STAGE CAPACITATED SUPPLY CHAIN Zied Jemaï and Fikri Karaesmen Laboratoire Génie Industriel Ecole Centrale Paris 92295, Chatenay-Malabry Cedex FRANCE Department

More information

Supplement to Call Centers with Delay Information: Models and Insights

Supplement to Call Centers with Delay Information: Models and Insights Supplement to Call Centers with Delay Information: Models and Insights Oualid Jouini 1 Zeynep Akşin 2 Yves Dallery 1 1 Laboratoire Genie Industriel, Ecole Centrale Paris, Grande Voie des Vignes, 92290

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Luís M. B. Cabral New York University and CEPR November 2005 1 Introduction Beginning with their seminal 2002 paper,

More information

SPARE PARTS INVENTORY SYSTEMS UNDER AN INCREASING FAILURE RATE DEMAND INTERVAL DISTRIBUTION

SPARE PARTS INVENTORY SYSTEMS UNDER AN INCREASING FAILURE RATE DEMAND INTERVAL DISTRIBUTION SPARE PARS INVENORY SYSEMS UNDER AN INCREASING FAILURE RAE DEMAND INERVAL DISRIBUION Safa Saidane 1, M. Zied Babai 2, M. Salah Aguir 3, Ouajdi Korbaa 4 1 National School of Computer Sciences (unisia),

More information

A Decomposition Approach for a Capacitated, Single Stage, Production-Inventory System

A Decomposition Approach for a Capacitated, Single Stage, Production-Inventory System A Decomposition Approach for a Capacitated, Single Stage, Production-Inventory System Ganesh Janakiraman 1 IOMS-OM Group Stern School of Business New York University 44 W. 4th Street, Room 8-160 New York,

More information

We consider a two-echelon inventory system with a capacitated centralized production facility and several

We consider a two-echelon inventory system with a capacitated centralized production facility and several MANUFACTURING & SERVICE OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT Vol. 16, No. 4, Fall 2014, pp. 561 577 ISSN 1523-4614 (print) ISSN 1526-5498 (online) http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/msom.2014.0494 2014 INFORMS Exact Analysis

More information

On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers

On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers Sam C.M. Lee John C.S. Lui + Abstract The current Internet architecture comprises of different privately owned Internet service providers

More information

How To Find The Optimal Base Stock Level In A Supply Chain

How To Find The Optimal Base Stock Level In A Supply Chain Optimizing Stochastic Supply Chains via Simulation: What is an Appropriate Simulation Run Length? Arreola-Risa A 1, Fortuny-Santos J 2, Vintró-Sánchez C 3 Abstract The most common solution strategy for

More information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation The Cournot and Bertrand models are the two basic templates for models of oligopoly; industry structures with a small number of firms. There are a number

More information

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality ROBERTO ROSON Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università Ca Foscari di Venezia, Venice, Italy. Abstract I review two papers, addressing the issue of

More information

Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity

Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity G. P. Kiesmüller, A.G. de Kok, S. Dabia Faculty of Technology Management, Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, P.O. Box 513,

More information

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output. Topic 8 Chapter 13 Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition Econ 203 Topic 8 page 1 Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry

More information

Control of a two-stage production/inventory system with products returns

Control of a two-stage production/inventory system with products returns Control of a two-stage production/inventory system with products returns S. VERCRAENE J.-P. GAYON Z. JEMAI G-SCOP, Grenoble-INP, 4 avenue Félix Viallet, 331 Grenoble Cedex 1, France, (e-mail : samuel.vercraene@g-scop.fr).

More information

In this paper we analyze the impact of supply-side externalities existing among downstream retailers on

In this paper we analyze the impact of supply-side externalities existing among downstream retailers on MANUFACTURING & SERVICE OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT Vol. 7, No. 1, Winter 2005, pp. 58 73 issn 1523-4614 eissn 1526-5498 05 0701 0058 informs doi 10.1287/msom.1040.0058 2005 INFORMS Positive vs. Negative Externalities

More information

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, 2003. Abstract

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, 2003. Abstract Interconnection Agreement between Internet Service Providers and the Optimal Policy Intervention: The Case of Cournot-type Competition under Network Externalities Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku

More information

Outsourcing vs. In-House Production: A Comparison of Supply Chain Contracts with Effort Dependent Demand

Outsourcing vs. In-House Production: A Comparison of Supply Chain Contracts with Effort Dependent Demand Outsourcing vs. In-House Production: A Comparison of Supply Chain Contracts with Effort Dependent Demand Onur Kaya 1 Department of Industrial Engineering, Koc University, Turkey okaya@ku.edu.tr Abstract

More information

Scheduling Policies, Batch Sizes, and Manufacturing Lead Times

Scheduling Policies, Batch Sizes, and Manufacturing Lead Times To appear in IIE Transactions Scheduling Policies, Batch Sizes, and Manufacturing Lead Times Saifallah Benjaafar and Mehdi Sheikhzadeh Department of Mechanical Engineering University of Minnesota Minneapolis,

More information

Application of Game Theory in Inventory Management

Application of Game Theory in Inventory Management Application of Game Theory in Inventory Management Rodrigo Tranamil-Vidal Universidad de Chile, Santiago de Chile, Chile Rodrigo.tranamil@ug.udechile.cl Abstract. Game theory has been successfully applied

More information

A Programme Implementation of Several Inventory Control Algorithms

A Programme Implementation of Several Inventory Control Algorithms BULGARIAN ACADEMY OF SCIENCES CYBERNETICS AND INFORMATION TECHNOLOGIES Volume, No Sofia 20 A Programme Implementation of Several Inventory Control Algorithms Vladimir Monov, Tasho Tashev Institute of Information

More information

Persuasion by Cheap Talk - Online Appendix

Persuasion by Cheap Talk - Online Appendix Persuasion by Cheap Talk - Online Appendix By ARCHISHMAN CHAKRABORTY AND RICK HARBAUGH Online appendix to Persuasion by Cheap Talk, American Economic Review Our results in the main text concern the case

More information

Analysis of a Production/Inventory System with Multiple Retailers

Analysis of a Production/Inventory System with Multiple Retailers Analysis of a Production/Inventory System with Multiple Retailers Ann M. Noblesse 1, Robert N. Boute 1,2, Marc R. Lambrecht 1, Benny Van Houdt 3 1 Research Center for Operations Management, University

More information

Optimizing Replenishment Intervals for Two-Echelon Distribution Systems with Fixed Order Costs

Optimizing Replenishment Intervals for Two-Echelon Distribution Systems with Fixed Order Costs Optimizing Replenishment Intervals for Two-Echelon Distribution Systems with Fixed Order Costs Kevin H. Shang Sean X. Zhou Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina 27708, USA Systems

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

A MANAGER S ROADMAP GUIDE FOR LATERAL TRANS-SHIPMENT IN SUPPLY CHAIN INVENTORY MANAGEMENT

A MANAGER S ROADMAP GUIDE FOR LATERAL TRANS-SHIPMENT IN SUPPLY CHAIN INVENTORY MANAGEMENT A MANAGER S ROADMAP GUIDE FOR LATERAL TRANS-SHIPMENT IN SUPPLY CHAIN INVENTORY MANAGEMENT By implementing the proposed five decision rules for lateral trans-shipment decision support, professional inventory

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

Biform Games: Additional Online Material

Biform Games: Additional Online Material Biform Games: Additional Online Material Adam Brandenburger Harborne Stuart July 2006 These appendices supplement Brandenburger and Stuart [1, 2006], [2, 2006] ( Biform Games ). Appendix C uses the efficiency

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes theory, which is the main subject of this course and its sequel, is based on the Efficient Market Hypothesis, that arbitrages

More information

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Daniel McFadden Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley April 8, 2002 I. This note is concerned with the economics of

More information

Load Balancing and Switch Scheduling

Load Balancing and Switch Scheduling EE384Y Project Final Report Load Balancing and Switch Scheduling Xiangheng Liu Department of Electrical Engineering Stanford University, Stanford CA 94305 Email: liuxh@systems.stanford.edu Abstract Load

More information

Supply Chain Coordination 1

Supply Chain Coordination 1 Supply Chain Coordination 1 Fuqiang Zhang Olin Business School, Washington University in St. Louis, MO 63130 zhang@olin.wustl.edu Supply chain coordination is among the central issues in supply chain management.

More information

Reused Product Pricing and Stocking Decisions in Closed-Loop Supply Chain

Reused Product Pricing and Stocking Decisions in Closed-Loop Supply Chain Reused Product Pricing and Stocking Decisions in Closed-Loop Supply Chain Yuanjie He * California State Polytechnic University, Pomona, USA Abolhassan Halati California State Polytechnic University, Pomona,

More information

STOCHASTIC INVENTORY SYSTEMS IN A SUPPLY CHAIN WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: CYCLE STOCKS, SAFETY STOCKS, AND CONSIGNMENT STOCK

STOCHASTIC INVENTORY SYSTEMS IN A SUPPLY CHAIN WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: CYCLE STOCKS, SAFETY STOCKS, AND CONSIGNMENT STOCK STOCHASTIC INVENTORY SYSTEMS IN A SUPPLY CHAIN WITH ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: CYCLE STOCKS, SAFETY STOCKS, AND CONSIGNMENT STOCK CHARLES J. CORBETT The Anderson School at UCLA, Box 951481, Los Angeles, California

More information

Operations and Supply Chain Management Prof. G. Srinivasan Department of Management Studies Indian Institute of Technology, Madras

Operations and Supply Chain Management Prof. G. Srinivasan Department of Management Studies Indian Institute of Technology, Madras Operations and Supply Chain Management Prof. G. Srinivasan Department of Management Studies Indian Institute of Technology, Madras Lecture - 36 Location Problems In this lecture, we continue the discussion

More information

Inventory Management and Risk Pooling. Xiaohong Pang Automation Department Shanghai Jiaotong University

Inventory Management and Risk Pooling. Xiaohong Pang Automation Department Shanghai Jiaotong University Inventory Management and Risk Pooling Xiaohong Pang Automation Department Shanghai Jiaotong University Key Insights from this Model The optimal order quantity is not necessarily equal to average forecast

More information

1 Error in Euler s Method

1 Error in Euler s Method 1 Error in Euler s Method Experience with Euler s 1 method raises some interesting questions about numerical approximations for the solutions of differential equations. 1. What determines the amount of

More information

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II Danilo R. Trupkin Class Notes (very preliminar) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model 1 Introduction One shortcoming of the Solow model is that the saving rate is exogenous

More information

In this paper we study how the time-series structure of the demand process affects the value of information

In this paper we study how the time-series structure of the demand process affects the value of information MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Vol. 51, No. 6, June 25, pp. 961 969 issn 25-199 eissn 1526-551 5 516 961 informs doi 1.1287/mnsc.15.385 25 INFORMS Information Sharing in a Supply Chain Under ARMA Demand Vishal Gaur

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Supply Chain Coordination with Financial Constraints and Bankruptcy Costs

Supply Chain Coordination with Financial Constraints and Bankruptcy Costs Submitted to Management Science manuscript Supply Chain Coordination with Financial Constraints and Bankruptcy Costs Panos Kouvelis, Wenhui Zhao Olin Business School, Washington University, St. Louis,

More information

Demand forecast sharing in a dual-channel supply chain

Demand forecast sharing in a dual-channel supply chain European Journal of Operational Research 174 (2006) 646 667 Production, Manufacturing and Logistics Demand forecast sharing in a dual-channel supply chain Xiaohang Yue *, John Liu School of Business Administration,

More information

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1 Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition Both the monopoly and the perfectly competitive market structure has in common is that neither has to concern itself

More information

Single-Period Balancing of Pay Per-Click and Pay-Per-View Online Display Advertisements

Single-Period Balancing of Pay Per-Click and Pay-Per-View Online Display Advertisements Single-Period Balancing of Pay Per-Click and Pay-Per-View Online Display Advertisements Changhyun Kwon Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering University at Buffalo, the State University of New

More information

OPRE 6201 : 2. Simplex Method

OPRE 6201 : 2. Simplex Method OPRE 6201 : 2. Simplex Method 1 The Graphical Method: An Example Consider the following linear program: Max 4x 1 +3x 2 Subject to: 2x 1 +3x 2 6 (1) 3x 1 +2x 2 3 (2) 2x 2 5 (3) 2x 1 +x 2 4 (4) x 1, x 2

More information

We study the important problem of how to assure credible forecast information sharing between a supplier

We study the important problem of how to assure credible forecast information sharing between a supplier MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Vol. 52, No. 8, August 2006, pp. 1239 1258 issn 0025-1909 eissn 1526-5501 06 5208 1239 informs doi 10.1287/mnsc.1060.0521 2006 INFORMS Strategic Commitments for an Optimal Capacity Decision

More information

Economics of Insurance

Economics of Insurance Economics of Insurance In this last lecture, we cover most topics of Economics of Information within a single application. Through this, you will see how the differential informational assumptions allow

More information

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 1 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing In this section we consider how firms compete when there are few sellers an oligopolistic market (from the Greek). Small

More information

A simulation study on supply chain performance with uncertainty using contract. Creative Commons: Attribution 3.0 Hong Kong License

A simulation study on supply chain performance with uncertainty using contract. Creative Commons: Attribution 3.0 Hong Kong License Title A simulation study on supply chain performance with uncertainty using contract Author(s) Chan, FTS; Chan, HK Citation IEEE International Symposium on Intelligent Control Proceedings, the 13th Mediterrean

More information

Optimal Control of a Production-Inventory System with both Backorders and Lost Sales

Optimal Control of a Production-Inventory System with both Backorders and Lost Sales Optimal Control of a Production-Inventory System with both Backorders and Lost Sales Saif Benjaafar, 1 Mohsen ElHafsi, 2 Tingliang Huang 3 1 Industrial and Systems Engineering, University of Minnesota,

More information

Impressum ( 5 TMG) Herausgeber: Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft Der Dekan. Verantwortlich für diese Ausgabe:

Impressum ( 5 TMG) Herausgeber: Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft Der Dekan. Verantwortlich für diese Ausgabe: WORKING PAPER SERIES Impressum ( 5 TMG) Herausgeber: Otto-von-Guericke-Universität Magdeburg Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft Der Dekan Verantwortlich für diese Ausgabe: Otto-von-Guericke-Universität

More information

Customers with positive demand lead times place orders in advance of their needs. A

Customers with positive demand lead times place orders in advance of their needs. A Replenishment Strategies for Distribution Systems Under Advance Demand Information Özalp Özer Department of Management Science and Engineering, Stanford University, Stanford, California 94305 ozalp@stanford.edu

More information

How to Win the Stock Market Game

How to Win the Stock Market Game How to Win the Stock Market Game 1 Developing Short-Term Stock Trading Strategies by Vladimir Daragan PART 1 Table of Contents 1. Introduction 2. Comparison of trading strategies 3. Return per trade 4.

More information

Using Shapley Value To Allocate Savings in a Supply Chain

Using Shapley Value To Allocate Savings in a Supply Chain Using Shapley Value To Allocate Savings in a Supply Chain John J. Bartholdi, III and Eda Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya School of Industrial and Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta,

More information

Second degree price discrimination

Second degree price discrimination Bergals School of Economics Fall 1997/8 Tel Aviv University Second degree price discrimination Yossi Spiegel 1. Introduction Second degree price discrimination refers to cases where a firm does not have

More information

Risk-Pooling Effects of Emergency Shipping in a Two-Echelon Distribution System

Risk-Pooling Effects of Emergency Shipping in a Two-Echelon Distribution System Seoul Journal of Business Volume 8, Number I (June 2002) Risk-Pooling Effects of Emergency Shipping in a Two-Echelon Distribution System Sangwook Park* College of Business Administration Seoul National

More information

Information and Responsiveness in Spare Parts Supply Chains

Information and Responsiveness in Spare Parts Supply Chains Information and Responsiveness in Spare Parts Supply Chains Table of Contents 1.0 Motivation... 3 2.0 What is Supply Chain?... 3 2.1 Spare Parts Supply Chain... 4 2.2 Spare Part Supply Chain Characteristics...

More information

Research Article Pricing Model for Dual Sales Channel with Promotion Effect Consideration

Research Article Pricing Model for Dual Sales Channel with Promotion Effect Consideration Mathematical Problems in Engineering Volume 06 Article ID 80403 0 pages http://dxdoiorg/055/06/80403 Research Article Pricing Model for Dual Sales Channel with Promotion Effect Consideration Chuiri Zhou

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Simulation-based Optimization Approach to Clinical Trial Supply Chain Management

Simulation-based Optimization Approach to Clinical Trial Supply Chain Management 20 th European Symposium on Computer Aided Process Engineering ESCAPE20 S. Pierucci and G. Buzzi Ferraris (Editors) 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Simulation-based Optimization Approach to Clinical

More information

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Alex Edmans LBS, NBER, CEPR, and ECGI Itay Goldstein Wharton Wei Jiang Columbia May 8, 05 A Proofs of Propositions and

More information

Knowledge Management in Call Centers: How Routing Rules Influence Expertise and Service Quality

Knowledge Management in Call Centers: How Routing Rules Influence Expertise and Service Quality Knowledge Management in Call Centers: How Routing Rules Influence Expertise and Service Quality Christoph Heitz Institute of Data Analysis and Process Design, Zurich University of Applied Sciences CH-84

More information

A Production Planning Problem

A Production Planning Problem A Production Planning Problem Suppose a production manager is responsible for scheduling the monthly production levels of a certain product for a planning horizon of twelve months. For planning purposes,

More information

Performance Analysis of a Telephone System with both Patient and Impatient Customers

Performance Analysis of a Telephone System with both Patient and Impatient Customers Performance Analysis of a Telephone System with both Patient and Impatient Customers Yiqiang Quennel Zhao Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Winnipeg Winnipeg, Manitoba Canada R3B 2E9

More information

Inventory Theory. 25.1 Inventory Models. Chapter 25 Page 1

Inventory Theory. 25.1 Inventory Models. Chapter 25 Page 1 Chapter 25 Page 1 Inventory Theory Inventories are materials stored, waiting for processing, or experiencing processing. They are ubiquitous throughout all sectors of the economy. Observation of almost

More information

Inventory Management - A Teaching Note

Inventory Management - A Teaching Note Inventory Management - A Teaching Note Sundaravalli Narayanaswami W.P. No.2014-09-01 September 2014 INDIAN INSTITUTE OF MANAGEMENT AHMEDABAD-380 015 INDIA Inventory Management - A Teaching Note Sundaravalli

More information

A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses. Michael R. Powers[ 1 ] Temple University and Tsinghua University

A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses. Michael R. Powers[ 1 ] Temple University and Tsinghua University A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses Michael R. Powers[ ] Temple University and Tsinghua University Thomas Y. Powers Yale University [June 2009] Abstract We propose a

More information

What is the (Real Option) Value of a College Degree?

What is the (Real Option) Value of a College Degree? What is the (Real Option) Value of a College Degree? JEFFREY R. STOKES 313 Curris Business Building Department of Finance College of Business Administration University of Northern Iowa, Cedar Falls, IA

More information

We consider a firm that produces multiple variants of a product. Products are assembled using a combination

We consider a firm that produces multiple variants of a product. Products are assembled using a combination MANUFACTURING & ERVICE OPERATION MANAGEMENT Vol., No., pring 0, pp. 6 70 issn 5-464 eissn 56-5498 0 06 informs doi 0.87/msom.00.07 0 INFORM The Role of Component Commonality in Product Assortment Decisions

More information

CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction

CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction Benjamin Edelman Hoan Soo Lee Working Paper 09-074 Copyright 2008 by Benjamin Edelman and Hoan Soo Lee Working papers are in draft form. This working paper

More information

A.2 The Prevalence of Transfer Pricing in International Trade

A.2 The Prevalence of Transfer Pricing in International Trade 19. Transfer Prices A. The Transfer Price Problem A.1 What is a Transfer Price? 19.1 When there is a international transaction between say two divisions of a multinational enterprise that has establishments

More information

Working Paper Does retailer power lead to exclusion?

Working Paper Does retailer power lead to exclusion? econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Rey, Patrick;

More information

Research Article Two-Period Inventory Control with Manufacturing and Remanufacturing under Return Compensation Policy

Research Article Two-Period Inventory Control with Manufacturing and Remanufacturing under Return Compensation Policy Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society Volume 2013, Article ID 871286, 8 pages http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2013/871286 Research Article Two-Period Inventory Control with Manufacturing and Remanufacturing

More information

An integrated Single Vendor-Single Buyer Production Inventory System Incorporating Warehouse Sizing Decisions 창고 크기의사결정을 포함한 단일 공급자구매자 생산재고 통합관리 시스템

An integrated Single Vendor-Single Buyer Production Inventory System Incorporating Warehouse Sizing Decisions 창고 크기의사결정을 포함한 단일 공급자구매자 생산재고 통합관리 시스템 Journal of the Korean Institute of Industrial Engineers Vol. 40, No. 1, pp. 108-117, February 2014. ISSN 1225-0988 EISSN 2234-6457 http://dx.doi.org/10.7232/jkiie.2014.40.1.108 2014 KIIE

More information

Interconnection Agreements between Competing Internet Service Providers

Interconnection Agreements between Competing Internet Service Providers Proceedings of the 33rd Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 000 Interconnection Agreements between Competing Internet Service Providers Rajiv Dewan*, Marshall Freimer, and Pavan Gundepudi

More information

Chapter 7. 7.1 Introduction. Distribution Strategies. Traditional Warehousing. 7.3. Intermediate Inventory Storage Point Strategies

Chapter 7. 7.1 Introduction. Distribution Strategies. Traditional Warehousing. 7.3. Intermediate Inventory Storage Point Strategies 7.1 Introduction McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter 7 Distribution Strategies Copyright 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Focus on the distribution function. Various possible distribution

More information

Load Balancing with Migration Penalties

Load Balancing with Migration Penalties Load Balancing with Migration Penalties Vivek F Farias, Ciamac C Moallemi, and Balaji Prabhakar Electrical Engineering, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 9435, USA Emails: {vivekf,ciamac,balaji}@stanfordedu

More information

In this paper, we consider an adaptive base-stock policy for a single-item inventory system,

In this paper, we consider an adaptive base-stock policy for a single-item inventory system, A Single-Item Inventory Model for a Nonstationary Demand Process Stephen C. Graves Leaders for Manufacturing Program and A. P. Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge

More information

Modeling Stochastic Inventory Policy with Simulation

Modeling Stochastic Inventory Policy with Simulation Modeling Stochastic Inventory Policy with Simulation 1 Modeling Stochastic Inventory Policy with Simulation János BENKŐ Department of Material Handling and Logistics, Institute of Engineering Management

More information

A Comparison of the Optimal Costs of Two Canonical Inventory Systems

A Comparison of the Optimal Costs of Two Canonical Inventory Systems A Comparison of the Optimal Costs of Two Canonical Inventory Systems Ganesh Janakiraman 1, Sridhar Seshadri 2, J. George Shanthikumar 3 First Version: December 2005 First Revision: July 2006 Subject Classification:

More information

Case study of a batch-production/inventory system E.M.M. Winands 1, A.G. de Kok 2 and C. Timpe 3

Case study of a batch-production/inventory system E.M.M. Winands 1, A.G. de Kok 2 and C. Timpe 3 Case study of a batch-production/inventory system E.M.M. Winands 1, A.G. de Kok 2 and C. Timpe 3 The plant of BASF under consideration consists of multiple parallel production lines, which produce multiple

More information

Equilibrium: Illustrations

Equilibrium: Illustrations Draft chapter from An introduction to game theory by Martin J. Osborne. Version: 2002/7/23. Martin.Osborne@utoronto.ca http://www.economics.utoronto.ca/osborne Copyright 1995 2002 by Martin J. Osborne.

More information

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models 780 w Interest Rate Models The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates Before discussing how a bond market-maker would delta-hedge, we first need to specify how bonds behave. Suppose we try to model a zero-coupon

More information

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities Elena Del Rey and Laura Romero October 004 Abstract In this paper we investigate the optimal choice of prices and/or exams by universities

More information

Congestion-Dependent Pricing of Network Services

Congestion-Dependent Pricing of Network Services IEEE/ACM TRANSACTIONS ON NETWORKING, VOL 8, NO 2, APRIL 2000 171 Congestion-Dependent Pricing of Network Services Ioannis Ch Paschalidis, Member, IEEE, and John N Tsitsiklis, Fellow, IEEE Abstract We consider

More information

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly WSG10 7/7/03 4:24 PM Page 145 10 Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly OVERVIEW An oligopoly is an industry comprising a few firms. A duopoly, which is a special case of oligopoly, is an industry consisting

More information

Inventory Management. Topics on inventory management

Inventory Management. Topics on inventory management Inventory Management ISyE 3104 Fall 2013 Topics on inventory management Objective An introduction to the fundamental concepts, tradeoffs and methods in inventory management Topics Deterministic inventory

More information

Computing the Electricity Market Equilibrium: Uses of market equilibrium models

Computing the Electricity Market Equilibrium: Uses of market equilibrium models Computing the Electricity Market Equilibrium: Uses of market equilibrium models Ross Baldick Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering The University of Texas at Austin April 2007 Abstract We discuss

More information

Optimization of Stochastic Inventory Control with Correlated Demands. Roger Lederman

Optimization of Stochastic Inventory Control with Correlated Demands. Roger Lederman Optimization of Stochastic Inventory Control with Correlated Demands Roger Lederman Honors Thesis in Computer Science Advisors: Amy Greenwald Aaron Cohen 1 1 Introduction and Motivation An application

More information

Online Appendix to Stochastic Imitative Game Dynamics with Committed Agents

Online Appendix to Stochastic Imitative Game Dynamics with Committed Agents Online Appendix to Stochastic Imitative Game Dynamics with Committed Agents William H. Sandholm January 6, 22 O.. Imitative protocols, mean dynamics, and equilibrium selection In this section, we consider

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

Introduction to Engineering System Dynamics

Introduction to Engineering System Dynamics CHAPTER 0 Introduction to Engineering System Dynamics 0.1 INTRODUCTION The objective of an engineering analysis of a dynamic system is prediction of its behaviour or performance. Real dynamic systems are

More information

Network Traffic Modelling

Network Traffic Modelling University of York Dissertation submitted for the MSc in Mathematics with Modern Applications, Department of Mathematics, University of York, UK. August 009 Network Traffic Modelling Author: David Slade

More information

INTEGRATED OPTIMIZATION OF SAFETY STOCK

INTEGRATED OPTIMIZATION OF SAFETY STOCK INTEGRATED OPTIMIZATION OF SAFETY STOCK AND TRANSPORTATION CAPACITY Horst Tempelmeier Department of Production Management University of Cologne Albertus-Magnus-Platz D-50932 Koeln, Germany http://www.spw.uni-koeln.de/

More information

FIXED CHARGE UNBALANCED TRANSPORTATION PROBLEM IN INVENTORY POOLING WITH MULTIPLE RETAILERS

FIXED CHARGE UNBALANCED TRANSPORTATION PROBLEM IN INVENTORY POOLING WITH MULTIPLE RETAILERS FIXED CHARGE UNBALANCED TRANSPORTATION PROBLEM IN INVENTORY POOLING WITH MULTIPLE RETAILERS Ramidayu Yousuk Faculty of Engineering, Kasetsart University, Bangkok, Thailand ramidayu.y@ku.ac.th Huynh Trung

More information

Equilibria and Dynamics of. Supply Chain Network Competition with Information Asymmetry. and Minimum Quality Standards

Equilibria and Dynamics of. Supply Chain Network Competition with Information Asymmetry. and Minimum Quality Standards Equilibria and Dynamics of Supply Chain Network Competition with Information Asymmetry in Quality and Minimum Quality Standards Anna Nagurney John F. Smith Memorial Professor and Dong (Michelle) Li Doctoral

More information

We consider a single-product inventory system that serves multiple demand classes, which differ in their

We consider a single-product inventory system that serves multiple demand classes, which differ in their MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Vol. 53, No. 9, September 2007, pp. 1486 1500 issn 0025-1909 eissn 1526-5501 07 5309 1486 informs doi 10.1287/mnsc.1070.0701 2007 INFORMS A Single-Product Inventory Model for Multiple

More information