More Time, More Work: How Time Limits Bias Estimates of Project Duration and Scope

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "More Time, More Work: How Time Limits Bias Estimates of Project Duration and Scope"

Transcription

1 1 More Time, More Work: How Time Limits Bias Estimates of Project Duration and Scope Abstract We propose that time limits systematically bias predictions of workers completion times, even when the limits are uninformative and cannot affect worker s behavior. We show evidence for this bias in controlled laboratory studies and in a field survey. We find that longer time limits contribute to a misperception that the task involves more work, even for experienced managers making estimates in a familiar setting. This scope and duration bias has important behavioral implications, including an excessive preference for flat fee compensation contracts over contracts based on time spent working. Keywords: Deadlines, Time Judgments, Scope Perception, Over learned Response, Estimation Bias Highlights: Judges systematically over estimate task completion time when time limit is longer. The biasing effect of time limits persists even when the time limits are completely uninformative and cannot affect workers time spent on the task. This happens because of changes in the perceived scope of work on account of an overgeneralized association between longer deadlines and bigger tasks. The bias is shown to explain an over reliance on flat fee contracts.

2 2 Meeting time limits and deadlines is a pervasive reality for managers. The deadlines a manager faces are often externally imposed and depend on other factors besides the scope of the work to be done. For example, a firm s clients often impose deadlines, which may in turn have been imposed on the client by pre determined market timetables, statutory requirements, or other factors. The manager working under these time limits then needs to make important decisions, which often involve estimating the time required by workers, such as planning internal timelines and allocating needed resources. In this paper, we demonstrate that time estimates made under externally imposed deadlines suffer from a robust and consequential bias. For managers, how much time workers are expected to take to complete a project is often a crucial input into key decisions. Underestimating the resources needed could delay or even preclude project completion. On the other hand, over allocating resources may represent a substantial opportunity cost or actual out of pocket cost. Likewise, the efficiency of how resources are procured may depend on the accuracy of estimated completion time. Consider, for example, a manager who is deciding between paying a temporary contract worker a flat fee for completing a project and paying the worker a metered rate (e.g. per hour). If the manager over estimates the amount of time the worker will take, the manager may agree to an expensive flat rate contract, and therefore over pay compared to the per hour cost. On the other hand, if the manger under estimates the amount of time the worker will take and chooses the per hour contract, the manager may face unexpectedly high costs. Prescriptive models of cost benefit analysis assume that the manager can either accurately estimate relevant inputs, such as workers time, or can at least estimate an unbiased probability distribution for the time needed (Dumond & Mabert, 1988; Williams & Sugden, 1978). Foundational work in industrial and organizational psychology put a great deal of effort into defining and timing the

3 3 steps in industrial processes (e.g., Lowry, Maynard, & Stegemerten, 1940), precisely because of the importance of having accurate inputs into such decision processes. While this approach is well suited for the manufacturing assembly line, it is a much more difficult task for managers in the modern information economy where tasks are often highly variable, require greater human intervention, and rely more on worker flexibility and initiative. Managers making these judgments often face insufficient objective information, either to directly base the judgment on or to facilitate learning from their own past judgments. In the absence of such information, managers may rely on intuition, heuristics, and anecdotal information from various sources. The business press, for example, provides such generalized advice, and often touts the benefits of maintaining tightly controlled worker environments. Managers can read about the benefits of a very tight deadline for worker productivity (Schaffer, 2012), the dangers of extended deadlines (Halvorson, 2013) and why managers should (metaphorically) kick workers in the pants (Herzberg, 1986). How accurately would these managers, operating under a short vs. long external deadline, estimate the time workers will take to complete a project, a potentially crucial input into their decisions? In this paper, we address this important question, unanswered by the prior literature. We investigate how decision makers subjective estimates of workers completion times for a task are affected by a time limit. We find that people provide higher estimates for the time to complete a task when the time limit for completion is longer. In our studies, estimating longer completion times for later deadlines, while potentially normative in some settings, persists even when the time limits are not informative and cannot influence workers actual completion times. We propose and test a novel scope perception account of our findings, in which longer time limits increase the perceived scope of the work. We distinguish our account from a motivation based account in which managers believe that shorter time limits increase workers pace, and rule out multiple alternative explanations, including numeric

4 4 heuristics such as anchoring. We test our account in five studies, using both lay subjects and experienced managers, familiar and novel tasks, and both hypothetical scenarios and incentivecompatible tasks. Estimating Task Completion Time Estimating task completion time is a duration judgment of a prospective event, and such judgments have been found to often be biased (over or under estimated) and extremely malleable (see Roy, Christenfeld, & McKenzie, 2005 and Halkjelsvik & Jørgensen, 2012 for reviews). Prospective duration judgments have been found to be affected by irrelevant factors, including arousal and vividness (Ahn, Liu, & Soman, 2009; Caruso, Gilbert, & Wilson, 2008) and a tendency to focus on the minute details of the target event and neglect other potential information, including past experiences (Buehler & Griffin, 2003). Even exposure to prior instances of task completion does not ensure accurate estimates. In particular, time judgments for events that have been experienced in the past are systematically affected by contextual factors, including the interval between the occurrence of the event and time of judgment (Neter, 1970), availability of attentional resources (Block, 1992) and retrieval of cues from memory (Block, 1992; Zauberman, Levav, Diehl, & Bhargave, 2010). These biases result in inaccurate recall and make it difficult for decision makers to learn from experience (Meyvis, Ratner, & Levav, 2010). Therefore, even experienced decision makers with access to accurate feedback may sometimes fail to utilize past completion time distributions (Buehler, Griffin, & Ross, 1994; Gruschke & Jørgensen, 2008) in making prospective time estimates.

5 5 In fact, managers may not recognize the benefit of replacing their subjective time estimates with more accurate information. The ambiguity involved in open ended time estimation can make these predictions particularly susceptible to over confidence bias (Klayman, Soll, González Vallejo, & Barlas, 1999), even among professionals making estimates about a familiar task (Jørgensen, Teigen, & Moløkken, 2004) and successful time managers (Francis Smythe & Robertson, 1999). Collectively, these factors may make managers susceptible to an over reliance on flawed judgment heuristics and noninformative cues in the decision environment, potentially including external time limits. Some research has suggested that time estimates are affected by time limit cues, including selfgenerated time goals in lab studies (König, 2005; Thomas & Handley, 2008), naturally occurring and experimentally manipulated deadlines (Buehler et al., 1994), as well as customers expected times in applied settings with experienced professionals (Aranda & Easterbrook, 2005; Grimstad & Jørgensen, 2007; Jørgensen & Sjøberg, 2004). In one field study, for example, software companies made shorter delivery time estimates with a 3 week deadline than without (Jørgensen & Grimstad, 2010). However, prior research on the effects of time limits has not tested the accuracy of these estimates, identified the underlying process or investigated the consequences for decision making. How Time Limits Can Impact Estimates In our investigation, we will distinguish between three distinct possibilities for how time estimates under non diagnostic external time limits are made. First, the time limit might not affect estimates of time, beyond providing an upper bound on the maximum possible time. This would be consistent with prior research in other domains, which has demonstrated insensitivity to important but ambiguous cues, particularly when individual judgments are made in isolation, as opposed to jointly (Hsee, Loewenstein, Blount, & Bazerman, 1999; Hsee, 1996; Shen & Urminsky, 2013).

6 6 A second possibility is that people believe that shorter time limits motivate workers to complete tasks faster. While the idea that people work more slowly when more time is available to them, known as Parkinson s Law (Parkinson, 1955), has been broadly influential, the empirical evidence is quite mixed. Lab studies have also found evidence that people spend more time when the time limit is experimentally manipulated to be longer, particularly for open ended tasks where no alternative activities are available (Aronson & Landy, 1967; Brannon, Hershberger, & Brock, 1999; Bryan & Locke, 1967; Jørgensen & Sjøberg, 2001 as reported in Halkjelsvik & Jørgensen, 2012). However, other experimental studies, using close ended tasks, have found no significant effect of manipulated time limits on time spent working (Amabile, DeJong, & Lepper, 1976; Burgess, Enzle, & Schmaltz, 2004), and being randomly assigned to a later deadline may even lead to more procrastination, rather than more time spent on the task (Ariely & Wertenbroch, 2002). It could be that people are well calibrated amateur psychologists in this domain, such that they either have learned or can infer how laxer or stricter time limits actually affect workers motivation. If this is the case, we would expect people s judgments to reflect the actual relationship between completion times and time limits, such that estimates differ only to the degree that the time limits can and do affect completion times. However, people may apply this belief even when they are not wellcalibrated as to the magnitude of the effect of specific time limits. This is consistent with the view that biases in judgments often arise from an over generalization of useful heuristics (Baron 1972). Lastly, we introduce a novel third possibility: people may judge the time to complete the task primarily based on the perceived scope of the work, and it is their judgments of project scope that are influenced by time limits. If people commonly use time limits which are customized for the project scope as a cue for inferring the unobserved scope of the work, they may do so even when the time limits are not informative, such as when the time limit is externally (or even randomly) determined. As a

7 7 result, people would estimate that a task with a longer time limit will take longer, not because they think people will work slower, but because the task seems larger. Such over learned responses have been found in other judgment domains, even when the cues are not informative (distance based on visual clarity, Brunswik 1943; frequency based on subjective value, Dai, Wertenbroch, & Brendl 2008; value of a service based on its duration, Yeung & Soman 2007). According to this novel scope perception account, time limits could affect managers estimated task completion times primarily because of their impressions of the task, rather than due to their beliefs about workers behavior or motivation. Thus, when time limits vary but the project scope is fixed, the time limit would bias estimates. Furthermore, the effect of time limits on estimates could persist even when the time limit cannot logically affect the worker s pace (e.g. when the workers do not know about the specific externally imposed time limits the manager is aware of). This provides a crucial testable difference between our proposed cognitive account and the lay theory motivational accounts. In our studies, we investigate specifically how one person (the manager) estimates the time it will take another person (the worker) to complete a task, rather than how long it would take a person to do the task themselves. Prior research has shown that the way people make completion time predictions for themselves may be different from how they reason about the times of others (Buehler et al., 2012; but also see Roy et al. 2013), particularly when there are deadlines (Buehler et al., 1994). Further, predictions about one s self can be influenced by factors such as motivated reasoning (Kunda, 1990), self presentation motives (Leary, 1996) and strategic goal setting (Locke, Latham, Smith, Wood, & Bandura, 1990). Therefore, investigating how people estimate task completion times specifically for others, under different time limits, enables us to separate our research question about biases in belief formation from confounding factors that can arise in predicting one s own future behavior. Study 1: The Joint Effect of Time Limits on Workers Times and Judges Estimates

8 8 In the first study, we measure the accuracy of predictions about how much time other people will take to complete a real activity. The study was conducted in two phases, with two different populations, one serving as workers completing a task, and one as judges, estimating the workers time. Method: In Phase 1, participants in a laboratory (n=116) were assigned the role of workers and were all asked to solve the same digital jigsaw puzzle. Each worker was randomly assigned to one of three between subject conditions, and given either unlimited time, 5 minutes (a relatively short time limit), or 15 minutes (a long time limit) to complete the puzzle. All the workers were paid a flat fee of $3 in all three conditions, regardless of how long they took to solve the puzzle. They were informed about their compensation and time limit before starting the timed puzzle. In order to make sure that participants did not think that they might have to wait until time was up after solving the puzzle, they were told that they could either move on to participate in another study or leave the lab after they completed the puzzle and answered a few follow up questions. The jigsaw puzzle was administered using a computer interface from the online puzzle site jigzone.com. The interface showed a timer which started counting immediately after the first piece was moved, and which stopped and continued displaying the final time when all the pieces were in place. While all participants solved the same puzzle, each participant started off with a different random arrangement of the puzzle pieces (see Appendix A for an example). As participants moved the puzzle pieces on the screen, the pieces snapped together only when the two pieces fit. As a result, the puzzle could not be solved incorrectly, ensuring the same outcome quality across workers. After each worker finished the puzzle, the completion time was recorded, and the participant was asked a few follow up questions about their experience participating in the study and their familiarity with jigsaw puzzles. In Phase 2, a separate sample of online participants (n=103) were assigned the role of judges, and were provided with detailed information about the Phase 1 study, including a picture of the initial

9 9 unsolved and final solved puzzle (Appendix A). They were provided full information about all three time limit conditions the various workers faced, and the compensation in the study. The information emphasized that each worker had been randomly assigned to one of the three time limit conditions, could not choose or influence their time limit and received the same $3 flat fee for their work in all conditions. Furthermore, judges knew workers were only doing one task in the allotted time and were free to leave as soon as they completed the study. Judges knowledge of these study characteristics is important to rule out inferences about the workers multi tasking or waiting for the time limit to elapse. Judges were asked to predict the task completion time for an average worker under each of the three different time limits (order counter balanced). Each judge estimated the average completion time for one time limit and then, on a separate screen, for the other two time limits. Judges were told that they could earn a bonus of up to $1 based on how accurately they predicted the task completion time. Judges were told that one of their predictions would be randomly drawn and read about how the linear accuracy incentive would be computed from the selected prediction. After making their predictions, judges were asked a few follow up questions regarding their beliefs about the completion time, their assessment of workers feelings while solving the puzzle, and their own familiarity with jigsaw puzzles. Results Phase 1: Workers Completion Times: All workers solved the puzzle within the allotted time. The average times it took workers to solve the puzzle were similar in all three conditions (M Short = 2.24, SD = 0.79; M Long = 2.75, SD = 1.89; M Unlimited Time =2.23, SD = 1.10; F(2,113)=1.92, p=.151). Post hoc tests indicated that people completed the task marginally faster under the short and unlimited time limits than the long time limit (M Short vs. M Long : p=.09; M Short vs. M Unlimited : p=.98; M Long vs. M Unlimited : p=.09;) 1. Therefore, even when time limits were three times longer (compared to the 5 minute limit) or absent altogether, the differences in actual time taken by the workers were small. 1 As an additional robustness check, the findings replicated using log transformed time estimates to address the different variances in the estimates under different time limits.

10 10 Results Phase 2: Judges Time Estimates: In contrast, using a between subjects comparison of the first estimates, judges expected large differences in the time it took workers with different time limits to complete the task. Overall, judges average estimates were significantly higher than the actual workers times in each of the three time limit conditions (Short Time: M Judges = 3.55 vs. M Workers = 2.24, t(68) = 7.21, p<.001; Long Time: M Judges = 6.62 vs. M Workers = 2.75, t(77) = 6.86, p<.001; Unlimited Time: M Judges = 5.98 vs. M Workers = 2.23, t(68) = 6.33, p<.001). More importantly, the over prediction increased with longer time limits (interaction F(2,213) = 8.36, p<.001; see Figure 1). Estimates for the short time limit condition were significantly lower than for either the long time limit (F(1,145) = 16.67, p<.001) or the unlimited time conditions (F(1,136) = 15.38, p<.001). After their first estimate, each judge made two unanticipated additional time estimates on a subsequent page, for the two other time limit conditions. Within subjects comparisons of all three estimates replicated the findings. The average estimate for the short time limit, long time limit, and the unlimited time limit conditions were 4.03 minutes (SD= 1.60), 5.94 minutes (SD=2.65), and 6.89 minutes (SD=4.34) respectively. The estimate was significantly lower in the short time limit condition compared to both the long time limit (t(133)=5.16, p<.001) and the unlimited time limit (t(142)=5.28, p<.001) conditions. Estimates were not significantly different between the long time limit and the unlimited time limit conditions in either between or within subjects comparisons. Overall, we find a substantial bias of time limits on completion time estimate, which does not seem to be explained by a lack of effort or experience on the judges part. The amount of time judges took to read the instructions and their self reported knowledge or experience with puzzles did not affect estimates or moderate the effect of time limits. Furthermore, judges were well calibrated when making estimates involving a diagnostic cue, correctly predicting that workers with low self rated knowledge of

11 11 puzzles would take longer to complete under each of time limits (see Appendix C for supplemental analysis). The findings were also not well explained by the judges lay beliefs about the effect of time limits on workers pace. We asked the judges whether they thought people would work slower, faster, or at the same pace when more time was available. While the majority (70%) of judges believed that people would take longer when more time was available (i.e., expressed a belief in Parkinson s law), this belief did not moderate the effect of time limits on completion time estimates. Furthermore, the differences in judges beliefs about how accountable workers felt to finish the puzzle as soon as possible or about workers task goals (to finish quickly or to take longer and enjoy it) across the different time limit conditions did not explain the findings. Thus, the observed bias does not seem to be attributable to judges beliefs about how time limits affect the workers state of mind. Discussion: The results of Study 1 provide an initial demonstration of the time limit bias: people erroneously estimated more time for others to complete a task when there is a longer time limit (or no time limit), compared to a shorter time limit. We replicated this finding in all additional studies we conducted (as reported in Appendix D). One potential explanation of our findings is that the bias could have arisen, in part, from a mistaken heuristic. First, we note that since judges were presented with all three time limits, they were making their estimates under the same set of potential anchors, and a simple anchoring account (Halkjelsvik & Jørgensen 2012) cannot explain the findings. A more subtle concern is that judges could have made the same over estimates in the time limit conditions that they would have made in the unlimited time condition but bounded their estimates by the time limit (Huttenlocher, Hedges, & Bradburn, 1990). If judges simply recoded all completion times above five minutes to five, for example, the estimates in the short time limit condition should be similar

12 12 to the bounded estimates in the unlimited time condition. However, even after truncating all estimates to a maximum of five minutes, judges estimates were significantly higher in the unlimited time limit condition than in the short time limit condition (M 5Mins = 3.55, SD = 0.69; M Unlimited = 4.37, SD=0.79; t(60)=4.35, p<.01). We find the same result comparing data in the 15 minute time condition after bounding at 5 minutes (M 15Mins = 4.50, SD = 0.86) to the short time limit condition (t(69)=4.95, p<.01). Alternatively judges might have mentally eliminated from consideration all times greater than the time limit, possibly coding them as failing in the task and therefore not qualifying for inclusion. Judges might have then effectively reported conditional average times, based only on the subset of workers who they believed would finish by the time limit. To test both this censoring account and the bounding account above, we ran a replication study (n=88, reported in Appendix D) with more detailed elicitation. We asked judges to estimate the proportion of workers who would have completed the task in each of several time ranges, including the proportion who they thought did not complete the task in the allotted time. Judges estimated that, on average, 92% of the workers (SD= 14.80) would complete the puzzle in under 5 minutes in the short time limit condition, but only 37% of the workers (SD=25.21) would complete the puzzle in 5 minutes or less time in the longer time limit condition (t(65)=11.14, p<.001). This finding is inconsistent with the truncation and censoring accounts. Likewise, this result cannot be explained by anchoring, as both estimates were of the proportion of people, rather than of the average time. Why did the time limits bias judges estimates in Study 1? The time estimates are consistent with both a motivational lay theory account (e.g., people work faster when there is less time ) and a scope perception account, in which judges predictions are driven by differences in perceptions of the task itself. In general, lay theories of motivation may contribute to such biases, particularly when task completion is open ended. However, in our setting, we did not find support for this account. While a

13 13 majority of participants did endorse the motivational lay theory (i.e., Parkinson s Law), those beliefs did not explain the effect of time limits on judge s estimates. In the next study we construct a setting to directly test the motivational lay theory account. Study 2: Budgeting Game with Irrelevant Time Limits Method: This study was conducted in a classroom setting in two sessions (one for each condition) using both verbal and written instructions. The participants (n=33) were under graduate students at a large mid western university who each participated in one session of the experiment as part of an Economics course requirement and who could earn an additional bonus based on their performance in the game. Participants played the role of judges (e.g., project managers) in a budget setting exercise. They needed to budget for a hypothetical worker, who was paid a constant wage rate of 10 cents per minute for the time taken to finish the job, to paint a 20 feet by 10 feet wall. In the scenario, the organization had set a time limit to complete the project either a short time limit (60 minutes) or a long time limit (120 minutes), varied between subjects that the hypothetical worker did not know about. Judges were then asked to budget for the task, by choosing how much money to allocate for the worker s compensation (based on the time to complete the project and the constant wage rate) from the $12.00 available. Judges were incentivized to not over budget or under budget. They would earn more if they had budgeted less and the project was still completed (see Appendix A for the complete instructions provided to judges). However, if they budgeted less money than turned out to be necessary, the participant, having failed the budgeting exercise, would not receive any bonus. The judges were informed that the worker s time to complete the task would be determined by drawing a number randomly from a uniform distribution between 30 minutes and 90 minutes.

14 14 Judges therefore had an incentive to provide as low a time estimate as possible (i.e. by budgeting as low an amount as possible) without under guessing (in which case they would not be eligible for any bonus at all). Most importantly, since the outcome depended only on the worker time randomly drawn from a known distribution, the optimal strategy was completely independent of the time limit. As shown in Appendix B, the optimal bid for risk neutral judges in either time limit condition (60 minutes or 120 minutes) was the same, $4.63, which corresponds to predicting that the worker would take approximately 46 minutes. This guess would have earned the judges a bonus of $0.88 in the game, on average. Results: Comprehension checks suggested that judges understood that the final completion times were drawn from a uniform distribution between 30 minutes to 90 minutes 2. Although the optimal bid, (based on the information known to the judges) was the same in both conditions, judges bid significantly less in the short time limit condition than in the long time limit condition, implying a lower time estimate (M short = $5.26, SD=0.98; M long = $6.09, SD=1.33; t(31) = 2.05, p <0.05; see Figure 2). In both the time limit conditions, the average bid was also significantly higher than the optimal bid of $4.63 (Short time limit: t(18)=2.82, p=.01; Long time limit: t(13)=4.08, p=.001). Therefore, the longer time limit influenced judges to budget more money for the task, even though they knew that the hypothetical workers were not aware of the time limit, and the time limit did not even affect the randomly drawn time used to determine the bonus. Discussion: This study suggests that the influence of time limits on managers time estimates can affect their decisions (e.g. budgeting), even when the time limits are completely irrelevant to the decision. Since painting is an open ended task, it could be that judges thought about a higher quality of work, requiring more time, when the time limit was longer. Given that the optimal strategy was to simply 2 In the 60 minute time limit condition there were 5 judges whose bids represented a completion time of more than 60 minutes, contrary to the directions. We truncated their bids to the maximum time available for the reported analysis, and we get the same results even if we discard these participants from the analysis.

15 15 solve the math problem the task implied, this would have been a bias as well. Furthermore, we replicated the findings in a study that again used jigsaw puzzles as a close ended constant quality task (n=74, see Appendix D), and in which the hypothetical workers did not know about the time limit. These findings cannot be explained by a motivational lay theory, since the workers were unaware of, and therefore could not be influenced by, the time limits. Why do randomly determined time limits which workers don t even know about lead judges to make different completion time estimates? We have proposed that participants may have different perceptions of the work involved under different time limits, even when the time limit does not represent a valid cue. The judges may overgeneralize from the fact that more effortful tasks often have longer time limits, such that they infer scope of work based on even non diagnostic time limits. To explain our findings, this scope perception bias would need to be robust and pervasive, occurring even when participants are provided with substantial information and engage in active deliberation. In particular judges in Study 1 were provided with detailed information about the task (e.g. they saw a picture of the puzzle and knew the number of pieces) and the bias was not moderated by the time they spent answering. Thus, a scope perception account of this finding would require that consideration of a specific time limit influences the spontaneous subjective judgment of task difficulty, potentially incorporating factors such as the similarity of the puzzle pieces or the difficulty of sorting through them to find matching pieces. This is analogous to a manager who has information about the objective quantifiable parameters of the deliverable, but whose time estimates may still depend on subjective assessment of the difficulty workers will have in completing the task. While our results thus far are consistent with the scope perception account, we have not presented direct evidence for this possibility. In the next two studies we construct a direct test of the

16 16 scope perception account by having managers estimate an objectively quantifiable aspect of the work (e.g. number of puzzle pieces). Study 3: Scope Estimation with Jigsaw Puzzles Method: Online participants (n=118) acting as judges read information about told about the puzzles available on including the range of puzzles sizes and the best and average solutions times among visitors for puzzles of various sizes (see Appendix A). Next, they read a hypothetical scenario in which one such puzzle was selected and administered to a group of students. Judges were told that the average time taken to solve the puzzle was 28 minutes. However, unlike the prior puzzle studies, in this study the judges did not know which puzzle it was or how many pieces it had. Instead, we use their estimates of the number of puzzle pieces as an objectively quantifiable measure of the perceived scope of work. Judges were assigned to one of three time limit conditions. In the scenario, the same puzzle was administered to another person (the worker), who either worked on it under no time limit, or was randomly assigned (using a coin flip) to one of two conditions a short time limit condition (30 minutes) or a long time limit condition (45 minutes). Judges were either told about the unlimited time setting only or about both the short and long time limits, depending on the condition (see Appendix A). Each judge estimated the number of pieces in the puzzle, and then, on a separate screen, the worker s task completion time. Thus, we can quantify both the number of puzzle pieces, one aspect of the believed scope of work, and the rate of work (pieces per minute) implied by their estimates. Results: Replicating the previous studies, judges predicted that workers would take significantly more time in the longer time limit condition than in the shorter time limit condition (M Short = 24.28, SD=5.23; M Long = 36.58, SD= 6.86; t(70)=8.56, p<.001). The estimated task completion time in the unlimited

17 17 condition (M Unlimited = 31.97, SD=30.62) was not statistically different from either of the time limit conditions. Next, we tested whether this difference in estimated task completion time also affected beliefs about differences in the scope of work, as operationalized by estimated number of pieces in the puzzle. Judges estimated that the puzzle had significantly more pieces when the deadline was 45 minutes than when the deadline was 30 minutes (M Short = , SD=58.82; M Long = , SD=96.86; t(70)= 2.46, p=.02), consistent with the scope of work account. Estimates in the unlimited condition (M Unlimied = , SD=62) were in between, significantly lower than in the long time limit condition (t(80)=3.43, p<.01) but not different from the short time limit condition. Lastly, we tested whether the judges estimates implied that the workers would work more quickly or be less likely to procrastinate when less time was available to them. We computed the implied rate of work, the estimated number of pieces divided by estimated completion time, for each judge. The implied rate of work (pieces per minute) was only slightly higher in the shorter time limit condition and the difference was not significant (M Short =5.62, SD=3.74; M Long = 4.83, SD=2.14; t(70) = 1.11, p=0.27). Thus, we find only a small (non significant) difference in the rate of work, but a large significant difference in the perceived scope, between the longer and the shorter time limit conditions. This finding is consistent with our scope perception account, but does not support the alternative that the bias in time estimation is due to a general association between shorter time limits and faster rate of work. As in Study 1, we confirmed that judges understood that the worker s time limit was assigned at random (94%), and the results were unchanged if we exclude the four judges who failed this comprehension test. Likewise, the effect of deadlines on the estimated number of puzzle pieces was not moderated by the amount of time judges took, either to read the instructions or to make their decisions, suggesting that insufficient processing cannot explain the findings.

18 18 Discussion: In study 3, we find that judges perceived a larger scope of work (number of puzzle pieces) when a workers had a longer (randomly assigned) time limit for the task. These results provide direct evidence for scope perception bias as the primary explanation for the effect of time limits on completion time estimates. In contrast, this finding cannot be explained by quality inferences, time limits signaling private information, or an over generalized belief about longer time limits yielding slower work. In the next study, we directly elicit beliefs about rate of work and replicate our findings among experienced managers making estimates in a naturalistic setting (a direct marketing campaign). Study 4: Scope Perception Bias in Managerial Decision Making Method: In an artifactual field experiment (Harrison & List, 2004), we interviewed managers of small tomedium businesses (SMB, under 100 employees), who were responsible for deciding printing needs for their companies (n=203, recruited from a paid online panel as part of an unrelated survey). A sizable subset of the managers (35%) indicated that they had prior experience not only in purchasing printing services, but specifically in running direct marketing campaigns. After completing survey questions about their use of office printing services, participants read a scenario in which they were asked to imagine that they had hired a third party vendor to send out customized mailers as part of a direct marketing campaign (see Appendix A for the study materials). The vendor would use its own list of potential customers, customizing the mailers based on other information they had about the individuals. In the scenario, after the vendor finalized the list of people to target from their database, it would take 4 weeks to customize the mailers before sending them out. Participants were then randomly assigned to either the short (4 weeks) or long (6 weeks) time limit conditions. In the long time limit condition, the scenario elaborated that they had just come across an industry report which suggested that direct mail was least effective during late summer and they had therefore instructed the vendor to delay the mailing by 2 weeks, so that the mailers instead went out in

19 19 early fall. We reiterated that this was a last minute decision after the list of potential target customers had already been finalized, and that because of this change the vendor now had 6 weeks to customize the mailers before sending them out. This manipulation creates a later deadline without any implications for project scope. Participants, acting as judges, were randomly assigned to either estimate the completion time (number of weeks it would take the firm to prepare the customized mailers), or estimate the project scope (number of mailers which would be prepared), between subjects. Judges in all conditions then estimated the typical worker s rate (the number of mailers prepared by a worker in a day). All estimates were elicited using an ordinal measure with six different numerical ranges (see Appendix A). The judges also estimated the number of prospective customers they thought were within the mailing area of the direct marketing campaign, indicated whether they personally had any prior experience with direct marketing campaigns, and provided their zip code. We merged in an estimate of population density based on census data for each participant s zip code. Results Estimated Time: We used ordinal regression to test for the effect of the time limit on the participants estimates, which were elicited in terms of pre defined ranges. The subset of judges (n = 101) who were asked to estimate how long the project would take gave longer times when the time limit was longer (Interpolated means: M Short = 1.62, SD=0.80; M Long = 2.73, SD= 1.27; Wald(1)= 26.52, p <.001). This replicates our prior finding that longer time limits lead to the expectation that the same project will take longer among an experienced set of managers making estimates in a setting familiar to them. Could the difference in time estimates have resulted from different anticipated rates of work, either due to a belief that workers would pace themselves according to the available time or because of an over generalized association between longer time limits and slower rate of work? Judges in this study

20 20 directly estimated the rate of work (mailers prepared per worker per day), allowing us to test this account. While the judges did estimate a directionally slower pace of work in the longer time limit condition, the difference was not significant (M Short = vs. M Long = , Wald(1) = 1.03, p=.31). Furthermore, in a multivariate ordinal regression predicting project completion time, we find that shorter time limits yielded significantly lower completion time estimates ( = 2.11, Wald(1) =26.94, p<.001) controlling for estimated rate and there was no effect of estimated rate ( = , Wald(1) =.876, p=.35). This suggests that the differences in judges time estimates under different deadline conditions cannot be explained by their belief that workers would work faster when less time was available. Results Estimated Scope of Work: To more directly test our proposed scope of work account, we asked the other half of the judges (n=102) to estimate the total number of mailers that would be prepared by the vendor. The judges estimated fewer mailers when the time limit was short than when two additional weeks were available (approximately 12,000 vs. 17,000, interpolating between ranges). An ordinal regression confirms that the estimated amount of work in the shorter time limit condition was marginally less than in the longer time limit condition ( =.69, Wald(1) = 3.30, p=.07). In contrast, the rate of work (mailers per worker per day) estimated by this group of managers, did not significantly depend on the time limit (M Short = 464 vs. M Long = 356, Wald(1) = 0.98, p=.32). Overall, a multivariate ordinal regression (Appendix C) reveals that judges estimated a larger scope for the completed project (more mailers sent) when the time limit was longer ( =.003, Wald(1) = 20.51, p <.001), controlling for their zip code s population density ( = , Wald(1) = 10.21, p =.001) and estimated rate of work (mailers per day, = 1.11, Wald(1) = 7.19, p <.01). Discussion: In study 4, we replicate our previous finding, this time among small business managers, that longer task completion times are estimated when a non informative deadline is longer. Importantly,

21 21 while 35% of the judges reported that they had prior experience of running direct marketing campaigns like the one we had described in the study scenario, having more directly related experience did not reduce the effect of time limits on estimates of task completion time, scope or rate of work. We also provided evidence that this finding is consistent with a scope perception bias and cannot be attributed to beliefs about workers pace varying with the time limit. We find that a direct measure of the scope of work, number of mailers being sent, did vary with the time limit. Controlling for other factors, judges estimated a significantly larger amount of work when the deadline was longer, consistent with the scope perception account. In contrast, we did not find a significant difference in estimates of the worker s rate of work based on the differences in time limits. Thus far, we have focused on investigating how time limits bias estimates of completion times. This bias could have important practical implications, to the degree that the biased time estimates are then incorporated into decisions. In the next study, we examine the potential behavioral consequence of the scope perception bias for manager s decisions about compensating workers. In many industries like retail and hospitality (Rocco, 2013) and auto services (MacPherson, 2014) managers can hire workers either with a per unit time compensation plan (e.g. hourly wages, where the payment is based on amount of time spent working) or a flat fee compensation plan (where the payment is fixed, either salaried or for completing a given task, regardless of time spent). Decisions between different types of contracts are determined by the extent to which effort or output can be monitored (Hölmstrom, 1979), transactional costs of performing such monitoring and controlling activities (Williamson, 1981), uncertainty in the environment (Prendergast, 2000), stage in the organizational life cycle (Madhani, 2010) and the potential for sorting and self selection of the best fit employees into an organization (Lo, Ghosh, & Lafontaine, 2011). We propose that the scope perception bias can be an important unrecognized factor in these decisions when external deadlines are present, leading managers to sub

22 22 optimally prefer flat fee contracts over time based contracts particularly when the time limits are longer. Study 5: Time Estimates and Choice of Contracts Method Phase 1: Workers: We used the same study design as in Study 1, only varying the type of compensation. Workers (n=113) were randomly assigned to one of four conditions in a 2 (time limit: short, 5 minutes vs. long, 15 minutes) x 2 (contract type: flat fee vs. per minute) design. Workers in the flat fee conditions were paid either $1 (in the short time limit condition) or $3 (in the long time limit condition), regardless of how long it took them to complete the puzzle. Workers in the per minute condition were paid 25 cents per minute (rounded up to the nearest minute) for the time taken. Results Phase 1: Workers Completion Times and Estimates: As in Study 1, we do not find a significant main effect of time limit on time taken to solve the puzzle (M Short = 2.46, SD=1.24, M Long = 2.87, SD=2.12, t(111)=1.26, p=0.21) 3. However, we did observe a significant main effect of contract type, with perminute workers taking longer to solve the puzzle than flat fee workers (M Flat Fee = 2.16, SD=0.98, M Per Minute Fee = 3.19, SD=2.15, t(111)=3.31, p<.01). Regardless of contract type, there was no significant effect of time limit on the time taken by the workers (Flat Fee: M Short = 2.14, SD=1.15, M Long = 2.19, SD=0.79; t(56)=.19, p=.85; Per Minute Fee: M Short = 2.81, SD=1.25, M Long = 3.60, SD=2.77; t(53)=1.35, p=0.18; interaction F(1,109) =1.37, p=.24. Therefore, although the workers in general took more time to complete the task under per minute contracts, they did not take significantly more time when more time was available to them while working under either contract type. Method Phase 2: Judges: In Phase 2, an adult online sample (n=171) played an incentivized game in which they were employers who would receive a lump sum payment for getting a jigsaw puzzle 3 Three workers took a little over 5 minutes in the short time limit condition, and these were truncated to 5 minutes. The results do not change if we do not truncate and use the raw numbers for time taken.

23 23 completed. In this game, they needed to employ a worker to solve the puzzle for them and would incur an employee cost, which was deducted from their revenue. The judges earned the remaining money, after deducting the cost of hiring the worker, as profit, which they were paid for real. The study used a 2(time limit: short, long) x 2(recruiting fee for flat rate workers: present, absent) full factorial design. Judges were randomly assigned to one of the two time limit conditions (short, 5 minutes vs. long, 15 minutes) and one of two recruiting fee conditions (extra fee for flat rate workers or not), and then chose which contract type (flat fee or per minute fee) to pay the worker. Judges knew that workers had been randomly assigned to contract types. The specific instructions that judges read in a sample condition (long time limit, flat fee) are shown in Appendix B. The cost of hiring a worker with a per minute contract was the same in all four conditions: 25 cents per minute, rounded up to the nearest minute, for the time taken by the worker to solve the puzzle (up to $1.25 in the short time limit condition, and up to $3.75 in the long time limit condition). The cost of hiring a worker with a flat fee contract varied by condition, depending on the time limit and whether an additional recruiting fee was charged for the use of a flat fee worker. In the two norecruiting fee conditions, the cost for hiring a flat fee worker was either $1.50 (long time limit condition) or $1 (short time limit). In the recruiting fee conditions, the cost for hiring a flat fee worker also included an additional fee (framed as paid to the recruiting agency) of either $0.60 (long time limit, for a total of $2.10) or $0.10 (short time limit, for a total of $1.10). The total budget available to the judges was either $2.00 (short time limit) or $4.00 (long time limit) when there was no extra fee payable to the recruiting agency for hiring a worker with a flat fee contract. In the two conditions where this recruiting fee was introduced, the employer s budget was increased correspondingly to either $2.10 (short time limit) or $4.60 (long time limit), to equalize the maximum possible earnings (see Table 1 for Judges potential profits in each condition). As mentioned

24 24 earlier, the judges profit after deducting the cost of hiring the worker from the allotted budget was theirs to keep. Thus, judges faced a tradeoff between a known amount of profit if they chose the flat fee, or an unknown profit (which depended on how long their worker would take) if they chose the perminute fee. After reading about the worker compensation options, the judges were told that their own outcome would be based on the completion time of a randomly selected actual worker, who had solved the puzzle under the contract chosen by the judge, subject to the specified time limit. We also provided judges with information on the typical demographic profile of a worker (based on Phase 1 of the study which had already been run), and showed them the puzzle interface instructions (including two pictures of the exact puzzle) that the workers had seen. To ensure comprehension, judges were prompted to reenter three critical pieces of information before they indicated their choice: the total time limit available, the total cost of hiring a flat fee worker, and the cost per minute of hiring a per minute worker. Judges then made their choice between the flat fee and per minute fee contract options. After their choice of contracts, judges were asked to estimate the worker s completion time both in the contract they had chosen, and under the other (unchosen) contract type. They were also presented with a hypothetical choice between a sure amount (equal to their profit from choosing the flat fee option) and a gamble which, unbeknownst to them, was constructed from the results of Phase 1 to match the actual distribution of profits under the per minute contract (see Table 2). Lastly, they answered a few questions about risk aversion, cognitive ability, and knowledge of jigsaw puzzles. After all data were collected, the profit earned was computed by pairing each participant with a randomly chosen participant in the appropriate condition in Phase 1, and the money was paid to each judge.

25 25 Results Phase 2: Judges Time Estimates and Contract Choices.: The recruiting fee conditions were designed so that the minimum profit in the per minute conditions for the short and long time limit were equal (unlike the non recruiting fee conditions). We found no main effects of the recruiting fee manipulation and it did not interact with any other factors (see Appendix). Since the contract choices did not depend on the worst case cost, we collapse across these conditions in the remaining analyses. In the long time limit condition, 89% of the judges chose the flat fee contract, earning a profit of $2.50 (after paying the $0.60 fee, if applicable, and deducting worker cost). In contrast, only 51% of the judges in the 5 short time limit condition chose the flat fee contract, earning $1.00 (after paying a $0.10 fee, if applicable, and deducting worker cost). The time limit had a highly significant effect on the probability of choosing the flat fee contract ( , To compensate judges who chose the per minute fee, we randomly picked a per minute worker s actual completion time for each judge and deducted the cost of that worker. Those judges who chose the per minute contract actually earned significantly more profit than they would have if they had chosen the flat fee contract, in both the long time limit condition (M per minute = $3.67, M flat fee = $2.50; = $1.17, t(9)=6.01, p<.001) as well as in the short time limit condition (M per minute = $1.12, M flat fee = $1.00; = $0.12; t(39)=2.68, p=.01, see Figure 3). An expected value maximizer with unbiased beliefs would be less likely to choose the flat fee contract in the long (vs. short) time limit condition, but our judges were instead significantly more likely to do so. In effect, judges choosing the flat fee contract in the long time limit condition paid an almost 50% premium to insure themselves against the unlikely outcome that their earnings would be lower because their per minute worker took too long. After making their contract choice, the judges estimated the task completion times for workers with the chosen contract type. Replicating the prior studies, judges estimated significantly more time in 4 The results are unchanged if exclude four judges who entered incorrect information in the comprehension tests.

26 26 the long time limit conditions than in the short time limit conditions (M Short = 3.38, SD=0.86; M Long = 7.22, SD=3.26; t(169)= 10.30, p<.001). Subsequently, judges were asked to estimate the average worker s task completion time under the alternative contract type (the one they had not chosen). Nearly all participants chose the option that would have provided a higher profit if their time estimates had been correct (84% in the short vs. 91% in the long time condition). These findings suggest that judges chose unnecessary fixed fee contracts, foregoing potential profits, primarily because they misestimated task completion times. As shown in Figure 4 estimated time for per minute workers fully mediated the effect of deadlines on contract choices. Controlling for per minute worker time estimates, time limits do not significantly impact contract choices. Could these findings be attributed to a lack of attention or consideration among some judges? We measure judges depth of reasoning (Cognitive Reflection Test, Frederick 2005), and the CRT scores did not moderate the effect of deadlines on the type of contract chosen. Likewise, the amount of time judges took and their self reported knowledge and experience with jigsaw puzzles did not moderate the effect. Thus, we find no evidence that the findings are driven by lack of attention or consideration. In studying these contract choices, it is also important to consider the potential role of risk preferences as an alternative account. The contract choice represents a gamble between a fixed profit under the flat fee contract and an uncertain profit that could be either higher or lower with the perminute contract (Grund & Sliwka, 2010). Even judges making well calibrated estimates could have been willing to sacrifice expected earnings for reduced risk, preferring the sure bet flat fee contract when faced with the riskier long time limit. To test this, we had the judges make a hypothetical choice between a fixed amount (equivalent to the profit with the flat fee contract) and a gamble constructed to be equivalent to the actual probabilities and outcomes represented by the per minute contract (i.e., calculated from workers times in Phase 1, see Table 2). The choice was represented as a separate

27 27 hypothetical gamble, unrelated to the employment game, and judges were not told that the gamble was equivalent to their contract choice. Judges choices differed between the contract choice and the equivalent gamble, contrary to the risk aversion account. In the long time limit condition, were more likely (89%) of the judges chose the flat fee contract that ensured a certain payment of $2.50, but significantly fewer (61%) chose the certain amount of $2.50 rather than the gamble equivalent of the per minute contract (McNemar's ,.001). In the short time limit condition, marginally more judges chose the certain option in the gamble than chose the equivalent flat fee option in the contract choice (M Flat Fee = 51%, M Certain Amount = 37%, McNemar's ,.06, see Figure 5). A logit model confirms that significantly more judges chose the flat fee contract under the longer time limit, even after controlling for risk preferences via the equivalent gamble chosen (b=1.89, Z=4.51, p<.001). We also found no interaction between a separate measure of risk aversion and the effect of deadline on type of contract chosen. Thus the preference for flat fee contracts in the long time limit condition cannot be explained by risk preferences. Discussion: The results of study 5 demonstrate a strong preference for a flat fee contract under longer deadlines, driven by a time limit bias in completion time estimates and resulting overestimate for the cost of hiring a per minute worker. We rule out alternative explanations of the preference for flat fee contracts under longer time limits, including risk preferences, inattention and miscomprehension. A further concern might be that judges often hire multiple temporary workers at once, rather than just one. Could the differences in behavior among workers eliminate this behavioral consequence of the scope perception bias? In a follow up study, judges chose which contract to use to hire 50 puzzlesolving workers (Study S6 in Appendix D), and we strongly replicate our findings. This provides evidence that the implications of the scope perception bias for contract decisions are also robust.

28 28 Our findings suggest that most judges choose the contract that they believe has higher expected value, conditional on their (upward biased) worker completion time estimates. This suggests that the effect of time limits on contract preferences would be eliminated when the flat fee contract is sufficiently expensive. In an additional study (n=83), we tested a flat fee of $3.00 (i.e. doubling the cost of hiring flat fee workers) in the long time limit condition. In this case, the preference for flat fee was eliminated, with only 29% of judges choosing the flat fee. Thus, once the cost disparity was high enough that the flat fee contract would be less profitable even under their biased time estimates, judges showed a preference for the per minute rate. This further suggests that judges choices were not based on an aversion to per minute contracts, but instead arose from an optimization with flawed inputs. Given that experienced managers estimates are susceptible to the effect of time limits, as shown in Study 4, we would expect these findings to extend to actual managers. In a small scale replication of Study 5, we presented the long time limit scenario to 40 MBA students who all had some prior managerial experience. Among this more experienced population, predictions of the average time for a per minute worker were significantly higher than for a flat fee worker (M Per Minute =12.28 vs. M Flat Fee=9.21; t(39)=3.74, p<.001). Correspondingly, 85% of people chose the less profitable flat fee contract, even though only 43% preferred the equivalent sure gamble (McNemar's ,.001). General Discussion Across five experiments, we provide evidence that people are more likely to overestimate task completion time for others when more time is available, even when the external deadline is completely non diagnostic. We provide evidence that this effect is largely due to an over generalized association between time limits and task scope, such that a decision maker perceives a greater scope of work when the deadline is longer. This over learned response persists even among experienced managers and can

29 29 contribute to inefficient contract choices. These findings are extremely robust, and have been replicated in all the data collected (reported in full in the Appendix), including for estimates of everyday activities. In our studies, we rule out multiple alternative accounts and confounds. Judges made estimates in contexts where there was no effect of time limits on the rate of work (Study 1), or where the optimal decision was independent of the time limit information (Study 2). In most of our studies, the judges knew about all the time limits conditions, precluding a simple anchoring account (Halkjelsvik & Jørgensen 2012). We also rule out various distributional heuristic accounts by eliciting judges beliefs about the distribution of workers task completion times, including their beliefs about the proportion of workers who would not complete in the allotted time (Study 1). Both our general findings and the direct measurement of task scope (Studies 3 and 4) are consistent with our proposed scope perception account, in which tasks with longer time limits are seen as involving more work. This effects even when judges were informed that the time limit was randomized (Studies 2 and 3), or that it was varied due to an incidental reason, after the scope of work had been fixed (Study 4), which addresses a potential information signal of time limits. We also rule out a motivational lay theory account, in which time estimates are based on beliefs about how time limits affect workers pace, both by using unknown time limits (Study 2) and measuring the believed rate of work (Studies 3 and 4). Our studies have focused on how estimates of others task completion times are affected by deadlines. When tasks are delegated to others, prior research (Burson, Faro, & Rottenstreich, 2010) has suggested that there can be systematic differences between how managers and workers evaluate incentives, due to differences in the inputs to that evaluation, such as probability of completion and subjective appeal of the incentive. In the domain of temporal judgments, prior research has generally found minimal differences between observers and actors judgments (Roy, Christenfeld & Jones 2013),

30 30 although with some exceptions (Buehler et al 2012). This raises the question of whether a similar bias might affect workers judgments of their own completion times, undermining the effectiveness of their plans, in some circumstances. Peetz, Buehler, and Wilson (2010) provide initial evidence that is potentially consistent with this hypothesis, showing that considering a real task farther from the deadline leads to more optimistic predictions of completion times, without affecting actual times. Understanding how deadlines impact beliefs about one s own completion times and thereby impact procrastination, planning and goal pursuit are important questions for future research. This bias in time estimation could impact a broad range of managerial decisions, suggesting important questions for future research. We test one such implication in Study 5, finding that decision makers over value flat fee contracts (versus per unit time contracts) when the available time limit is longer, due to the bias in estimated task completion time for their employees. Managers might also be overly impressed by a workers completion time when an externally determined time limit (e.g., set by a client) is longer and then judge the same performance as poor when the time limit is shorter. This kind of time estimate based bias in evaluations could impact promotion, compensation, and other performance appraisal decisions (Levy & Williams, 2004). The effect of deadlines on time overestimates could also lead managers to over value explicit control and underestimate the extent of workers internal motives or indirect external incentives to perform well (DeVoe & Iyengar, 2004; Gneezy & Rustichini, 2000; Heath, 1999). Our results provide an example of how understanding managers specific judgment biases in the inputs to their decisions can serve as a useful starting point for a broader investigation into the misapplication of management practices.

31 31 References Ahn, H. K., Liu, M. W., & Soman, D. (2009). Memory markers: How consumers recall the duration of experiences. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 19(3), Amabile, T. M., DeJong, W., & Lepper, M. R. (1976). Effects of externally imposed deadlines on subsequent intrinsic motivation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 34(1), 92. Aranda, J., & Easterbrook, S. (2005). Anchoring and adjustment in software estimation (Vol. 30). ACM. Ariely, D., & Wertenbroch, K. (2002). Procrastination, deadlines, and performance: Self control by precommitment. Psychological Science, 13(3), Aronson, E., & Landy, D. (1967). Further steps beyond Parkinson s law: A replication and extension of the excess time effect. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 3(3), Baron, J. (1972). Semantic components and conceptual development. Cognition, 2(3), Baron, J. (1990). Harmful heuristics and the improvement of thinking. Contributions to Human Development, 21, Bassett, G. A. (1979). A study of the effects of task goal and schedule choice on work performance. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 24(2), Block, R. A. (1992). Prospective and retrospective duration judgment: The role of information processing and memory. Time, Action and Cognition: Towards Bridging the Gap, Brannon, L. A., Hershberger, P. J., & Brock, T. C. (1999). Timeless demonstrations of Parkinson s first law. Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, 6(1), Brunswik, E. (1943). Organismic achievement and environmental probability. Psychological Review, 50(3), 255. Bryan, J. F., & Locke, E. A. (1967). Parkinson s Law as a goal setting phenomenon. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 2(3),

32 32 Buehler, R., & Griffin, D. (2003). Planning, personality, and prediction: The role of future focus in optimistic time predictions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 92(1), Buehler, R., Griffin, D., Lam, K. C., & Deslauriers, J. (2012). Perspectives on prediction: Does third person imagery improve task completion estimates? Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 117(1), Buehler, R., Griffin, D., & Ross, M. (1994). Exploring the planning fallacy : Why people underestimate their task completion times. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 67(3), Burgess, M., Enzle, M. E., & Schmaltz, R. (2004). Defeating the potentially deleterious effects of externally imposed deadlines: Practitioners rules of thumb. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 30(7), Burson, K. A., Faro, D., & Rottenstreich, Y. (2010). ABCs of principal agent interactions: Accurate predictions, biased processes, and contrasts between working and delegating. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 113(1), Caruso, E. M., Gilbert, D. T., & Wilson, T. D. (2008). A Wrinkle in Time Asymmetric Valuation of Past and Future Events. Psychological Science, 19(8), Dai, X., Wertenbroch, K., & Brendl, C. M. (2008). The value heuristic in judgments of relative frequency. Psychological Science, 19(1), DeVoe, S. E., & Iyengar, S. S. (2004). Managers theories of subordinates: A cross cultural examination of manager perceptions of motivation and appraisal of performance. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 93(1), Dumond, J., & Mabert, V. A. (1988). Evaluating project scheduling and due date assignment procedures: an experimental analysis. Management Science, 34(1),

33 33 Francis Smythe, J., & Robertson, I. (1999). Time related individual differences. Time & Society, 8(2 3), Gjesme, T. (1975). Slope of gradients for performance as a function of achievement motive, goal distance in time, and future time orientation. The Journal of Psychology, 91(1), Gneezy, U., & Rustichini, A. (2000). Pay enough or don t pay at all. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), Grimstad, S., & Jørgensen, M. (2007). Inconsistency of expert judgment based estimates of software development effort. Journal of Systems and Software, 80(11), Grund, C., & Sliwka, D. (2010). Evidence on performance pay and risk aversion. Economics Letters, 106(1), Gruschke, T. M., & Jørgensen, M. (2008). The role of outcome feedback in improving the uncertainty assessment of software development effort estimates. ACM Transactions on Software Engineering and Methodology (TOSEM), 17(4), 20. Gutierrez, G. J., & Kouvelis, P. (1991). Parkinson s law and its implications for project management. Management Science, 37(8), Halkjelsvik, T., & Jørgensen, M. (2012). From origami to software development: A review of studies on judgment based predictions of performance time. Psychological Bulletin, 138(2), 238. Halvorson, H. G. (2013). Here s What Really Happens When You Extend a Deadline. Harvard Business Review. August 19, Retrieved from what really happenswhen Harrison, G. W., & List, J. A. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), Heath, C. (1999). On the social psychology of agency relationships: Lay theories of motivation overemphasize extrinsic incentives. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 78(1),

34 34 Herzberg, F. (1986). One more time: how do you motivate employees? New York: The Leader Manager, Hölmstrom, B. (1979). Moral hazard and observability. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), Hsee, C. K. (1996). The evaluability hypothesis: An explanation for preference reversals between joint and separate evaluations of alternatives. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 67(3), Hsee, C. K., Loewenstein, G. F., Blount, S., & Bazerman, M. H. (1999). Preference reversals between joint and separate evaluations of options: A review and theoretical analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 125(5), Hull, C. L. (1932). The goal gradient hypothesis and maze learning. Psychological Review, 39(1), Huttenlocher, J., Hedges, L. V., & Bradburn, N. M. (1990). Reports of elapsed time: Bounding and rounding processes in estimation. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory and Cognition, 16(2), Jochimsen, B. (2009). Service Quality in Modern Bureaucracy: Parkinson s Theory at Work. Kyklos, 62(1), Jørgensen, M., & Grimstad, S. (2010). Software Development Effort Estimation Demystifying and Improving Expert Estimation. In A. Tveito, A. M. Bruaset, & O. Lysne (Eds.), Simula Research Laboratory by Thinking Constantly About It (pp ). Berlin: Springer. Jørgensen, M., & Sjøberg, D. I. (2001). Impact of effort estimates on software project work. Information and Software Technology, 43(15), Jørgensen, M., & Sjøberg, D. I. (2004). The impact of customer expectation on software development effort estimates. International Journal of Project Management, 22(4),

35 35 Jørgensen, M., Teigen, K. H., & Moløkken, K. (2004). Better sure than safe? Over confidence in judgement based software development effort prediction intervals. Journal of Systems and Software, 70(1), Kahneman, D., & Frederick, S. (2002). Representativeness revisited: Attribute substitution in intuitive judgment. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, & D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment (pp ). New York: Cambridge University Press. Kim, B. K., & Zauberman, G. (2013). Can Victoria s Secret Change the Future? A Subjective Time Perception Account of Sexual Cue Effects on Impatience. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 142(2), Kivetz, R., Urminsky, O., & Zheng, Y. (2006). The goal gradient hypothesis resurrected: Purchase acceleration, illusionary goal progress, and customer retention. Journal of Marketing Research (Vol. XLIII), Klayman, J., Soll, J. B., González Vallejo, C., & Barlas, S. (1999). Overconfidence: It depends on how, what, and whom you ask. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 79(3), König, C. J. (2005). Anchors distort estimates of expected duration. Psychological Reports, 96(2), Kunda, Z. (1990). The case for motivated reasoning. Psychological Bulletin, 108(3), Latham, G. P., & Locke, E. A. (1975). Increasing productivity and decreasing time limits: A field replication of Parkinson s law. Journal of Applied Psychology, 60(4), Leary, M. R. (1996). Self presentation: Impression management and interpersonal behavior. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Levy, P. E., & Williams, J. R. (2004). The social context of performance appraisal: A review and framework for the future. Journal of Management, 30(6),

36 36 Lo, D., Ghosh, M., & Lafontaine, F. (2011). The Incentive and Selection Roles of Sales Force Compensation Contracts. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(4), Locke, E. A., Latham, G. P., Smith, K. J., Wood, R. E., & Bandura, A. (1990). A theory of goal setting & task performance (Vol. 21). Prentice Hall Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Lowry, S. M., Maynard, H. B., & Stegemerten, G. J. (n.d.). Time and motion study and formulas for wage incentives New York. McGraw Hill Book Co. Madhani, P. M. (2010). Realigning fixed and variable pay in sales organizations: An organizational life cycle approach. Compensation & Benefits Review, 42(6), Meyvis, T., Ratner, R. K., & Levav, J. (2010). Why don t we learn to accurately forecast feelings? How misremembering our predictions blinds us to past forecasting errors. Journal of Experimental Psychology. General, 139(4), Neter, J. (1970). Measurement errors in reports of consumer expenditures. Journal of Marketing Research, Parkinson, C. N. (1955). Parkinson s law. The Economist. November 19, Retrieved from Peetz, J., Buehler, R., & Wilson, A. (2010). Planning for the near and distant future: How does temporal distance affect task completion predictions? Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 46(5), Prendergast, C. (2000). The tenuous tradeoff between risk and incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 110(5), Roy, M. M., Christenfeld, N. J., & Jones, M. (2013). Actors, observers, and the estimation of task duration. The Quarterly Journal of Experimental Psychology, 66(1), Roy, M. M., Christenfeld, N. J., & McKenzie, C. R. (2005). Underestimating the duration of future events: Memory incorrectly used or memory bias? Psychological Bulletin, 131(5),

37 37 Schaffer, Robert H. (2012). Make the Job a Game. Harvard Business Review. September 10, Retrieved from the job a game Shen, L., & Urminsky, O. (2013). Making Sense of Nonsense The Visual Salience of Units Determines Sensitivity to Magnitude. Psychological Science, 24(3), Teigen, K. H., & Jørgensen, M. (2005). When 90% confidence intervals are 50% certain: On the credibility of credible intervals. Applied Cognitive Psychology, 19(4), Thomas, K. E., & Handley, S. J. (2008). Anchoring in time estimation. Acta Psychologica, 127(1), Williams, A., & Sugden, R. (1978). The principles of pratical cost benefit analysis. New York: Oxford University Press. Williamson, O. E. (1981). The economics of organization: the transaction cost approach. American Journal of Sociology, Yeung, C. W., & Soman, D. (2007). The duration heuristic. Journal of Consumer Research, 34(3), Zauberman, G., Levav, J., Diehl, K., & Bhargave, R. (2010) Feels So Close Yet So Far The Effect of Event Markers on Subjective Feelings of Elapsed Time. Psychological Science, 21(1),

38 38 Figures Estimated Time or Time Taken (minutes) Judge (Estimate) Worker (Actual) 5 Mins. (Short) 15 Mins. (Long) Unlimited Time Note: Vertical lines are +/ 2SE Figure 1: Time taken by workers and time estimated by judges as a function of time limits (Study 1) 8 Budget Allocated for the same task ($) Mins. (Short) 120 Mins. (Long) Note: Vertical lines are +/ 2SE Figure 2: Budget allocated for the same task in different hidden time limit conditions (Study 2)

39 39 $4.50 $4.00 Flat Fee Contract Per Minute Contract Average Bonus Earned ($) $3.50 $3.00 $2.50 $2.00 $1.50 $1.00 $0.50 $ Mins. (Short) 15 Mins. (Long) Note: Vertical lines are +/ 2SE Figure 3: Profits earned by judges based on choice to hire a worker either using a flat fee contract or a per minute contract and the actual time taken by the chosen worker (Study 5) Estimated Task Completion Time Of Per Minute Workers β 1 = 8.35, t=17.2, p<.001 β 2 = +0.56, z=4.38, p<.001 Time Limit 15 Minutes=0 5Minutes=1 β 3 = 2.05, z= 5.10, p<.001 β 3 = 0.84, z=1.31, p=.18 β 2 = +0.63, z=4.48, p=.001 Choice of Flat Fee Contracts Figure 4: Full Mediation of the choice of flat fee contracts by judges estimated completion time for per minute workers (Study 5)

40 40 % choosing Flat Fee or Sure Amount 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% Flat Fee Contract Sure Amount in Equivalent Gamble 5 Mins. (Short) 15 Mins. (Long) Note: Vertical lines are +/ 2SE Figure 5: Judges choices of flat fee contracts and sure amounts in an equivalent gamble as a function of time limits (Study 5)

41 41 Tables If Flat Fee Contract Selected: If Per Minute Contract Selected: Time Limit Terms Cost of hiring worker Profit earned by judge Range of costs for hiring worker Range of profit earnings by judge No Recruiting Fee Conditions: 5 minutes (Short Time) Budget = $2; Flat Fee = $1; Per Unit Time rate = $0.25/min $1 $1 $0.25 $1.25 $1.75 $ minutes (Long Time) Budget = $4; Flat Fee = $1.50; Per Unit Time rate = $0.25/min $1.50 $2.50 $0.25 $3.75 $3.75 $0.25 Recruiting Fee Conditions: 5 minutes (Short Time) Budget = $2.10; Flat Fee = $1.10 (including $.10 recruiting fee); Per Unit Time rate = $0.25/min $1.10 $1 $0.25 $1.25 $1.85 $ minutes (Long Time) Budget = $4.60; Flat Fee = $2.10 (including $.60 recruiting fee); Per Unit Time rate = $0.25/min $2.10 $2.50 $0.25 $3.75 $4.35 $0.85 Table 1: Judges' potential profits in different conditions (Study 5) Condition Option A Option B Exactly one of the following amounts: Deadline = 15 minutes (Long) Deadline = 5 minutes (Short) A fixed amount of $2.50 for sure A fixed amount of $1 for sure 33% chance of winning $3.50, or 26% chance of winning $3.25, or 15% chance of winning $3.00, or 7% chance of winning $2.50, or 11% chance of winning $2.25, or 4% chance of winning $2.00, or 4% chance of winning 25 cents Exactly one of the following amounts: 29% chance of winning $1.50, or 32% chance of winning $1.25, or 14% chance of winning $1.00, or 25% chance of winning 75 cents Table 2: Gambles constructed from potential profit payments using actual workers time (Study 5)

42 More Time, More Work: How Time Limits Bias Estimates of Project Duration and Scope SUPPLEMENTAL ONLINE APPENDICES

43 Appendix A: Study Materials (including Stimuli and Instructions) 1. Interface from jigzone.com used in Study 1 and Study 5 Exhibit A.1: Jigzone.com interface which was integrated in a Qualtrics Survey. The workers saw the pieces spread out in a random order when they started. The interface only allowed two correct pieces to come together and indicated this with a snap sound. The time elapsed was displayed on the left. The same picture was shown to the judges. Exhibit A.2: Additional picture of the completed 20 piece jigsaw puzzle shown to judges when their job was described to them in Studies 1 and 5.

44 2. Complete Paper and Pencil Instructions for Study 2 Basic Instructions 1. You are a Project Manager in an Organization and you are responsible for doing budgeting for a task with will be done by a Contractor. 2. The task is very simple it is painting a 20 ft by 10 ft wall with red color for a promotional activity. 3. The Contractor has already been selected and your job is to set the budget in US Dollars based on your estimate of time which the task will take to complete. 4. If the project goes over budget (i.e. the project takes longer than you had budgeted for), the contractor will be paid for their time (as per a fixed wage rate), but you will not receive a bonus. 5. If the project comes in under budget, the contractor will receive the budgeted payment, and you will receive a bonus which depends on the difference between the Cap and the budget you set plus some fixed amount. 6. The Cap is the maximum money your Organization has set apart for this task. 7. The Organization also has a maximum time which it has set for completing this task. 8. The Contractor does not know anything about either the Cap or the maximum time set by your Organization to complete the task. That information is available only to you as a Project Manager. 9. The Contractor has strong incentive to do it as quickly as they can else they are worried about future consequences (i.e. getting hired for future jobs). So, you can be assured that the contractor will not take any longer than it takes. Contract Details 1. The Cap set by your Organization to complete the task is $ The maximum time set by your Organization to complete the task is 60 minutes (120 minutes). 3. The Contractor s wage rate is 10 cents per minutes and this is fixed. 4. If the Contractor takes t minutes to complete the work the total wages payable is $w= t*0.10. If the work remains unfinished till the total time available for its completion the money

45 payable to the contractor is the time for the entire duration i.e. 60*0.10 = $6.00 (120*0.10 = $12.00). 5. As the Project Manager, you make an offer to the Contractor which is either greater than or equal to the total wages payable. If your offer is $y and it is not less than the actual wages payable $w, then the Contractor gets $y, as per your offer, and you get a bonus which is detailed in the payoff matrix below. 6. If you make an offer, which is less than the actual wages payable, then the Contractor gets the wages payable $w and you do not get anything since you did not do a good job in estimating the time. 7. Here is the payoff matrix for you: Your Offer = $y; Actual wages payable to the Contractor = $w Goes Over Budget IF w > y Completed Under Budget IF w <= y Contractor gets USD (as wage) w y You get USD (as bonus) 0 $ max(c 2y,0) C=Cap i.e. $ III. Logistics For the purpose of this exercise, we are going to make a random draw and estimate the Contractor s wages payable at the end of the experiment. This will be done in front of you all after you are done answering the questions. IV. Additional Private Information You have leant from your reliable sources that in the past other Contractors have taken anywhere between 30 minutes to 90 minutes to complete similar tasks and any duration within this interval were equally likely. Please ensure that you have understood the above directions completely and let the experimenter know in case you have any doubts before proceeding to answer the questions below.

46 3. Distribution of Puzzle Completion Times from jigzone.com used in Study 3 Exhibit A.3: Three puzzles from jigzone.com with different number of pieces, minimum time, and average time shown to the judges in Study 3

47 4. Instructions to Judges in Study 3 Exhibit A.4: Common instructions to all judges Exhibit A.5: Additional instructions in the control (unlimited time) condition Exhibit A.6: Additional instructions in the treatment conditions

48 5. Instructions used in Study 4 Exhibit A.7: Basic Instructions provided in both the short time limit (4 weeks) and the long time limit (6 weeks) condition Exhibit A.8: Additional text added in the long time limit condition (6 weeks) Exhibit A.9: Elicitation procedure for scope of work in both the short and the long time limit condition

49 Exhibit A.10: Elicitation procedure for rate of work in both the short and the long time limit condition Exhibit A.11: Elicitation procedure for time estimation in the short time limit condition. In the long time limit condition (6 weeks) the percentages of available time were the same (25%, 37.5% etc.) and the absolute numbers were calculated accordingly (1.5 weeks, 2.25 weeks etc.)

50 6. Complete Instructions along with the graphical interface used in the Judges phase of Study 5 (15 Minutes and $4.00 budget condition is shown for illustrative purpose)

51

52 Appendix B: Optimal Strategy for the Budgeting Game (Study 2) The pay off structure was as follows: Offer/Bid = $y Wages Payable = $w Wages payable is over budget If w > y Wages payable is under budget If w <= y Actual Wage Paid in $ w y Bonus Paid in $ max( *y, 0) We know, ~ 30, 90, where is time taken by contractor in minutes to complete the work. This means, ~ 3, 9, where w is the wages payable to contractor in Dollars (1) Expected Bonus: E b Pr 0 Pr , 0 Pr ,0 Pr , 0 (2) Case I: What if 3. As per (1) this would tantamount to the manager going under budget in which case he will not earn any bonus. Hence, 3 is not possible. Case II: What if 9. In this case as per (1) Pr 1. However, knowing (1) the manager would strictly prefer a bid 9 to 9. Case III: From the above discussion it is clear that 3, 9 is the feasible range of the manager s bid. Therefore given an Uniform distribution, Pr. (3) Using (3) in (2), we get , 0 6 y 3 max 12 2, 0 (4) To solve the maximization problem in (4), we divide into two ranges 3 6 and 6 9 (i) For 3 6:

53 This is a concave function in. Solving the FOC gives us This means (ii) For 6 9: This is an increasing function of, hence is maximized at 9. This means Therefore, the optimal bid is $4.63 in which case the expected value of manager s bonus is $0.88. The figure below depicts expected bonus as a function of the bid. Figure B.1: Judges' expected bonus as a function of their bids (Study 2)

54 Appendix C: Supplemental Analysis 1. The tables below examine potential moderation of the effect of time limits (Short vs. Long) by various variables which were asked as follow up questions after the workers or judges completed the main task. For the cases with a significant (or marginally significant) moderation, the means of the DV at the different levels (Hi, Lo) of the moderator variable (using median split, if continuous) are provided for the short and the long time limits to give a sense of the direction of the interaction. For Study 5, we combined the two contract types (Flat Fee, Per Minute Fee) for a particular time limit in reported tables (e.g. 5 Minutes Flat Fee and 5 Minutes Per minute Fee were combined and reported as Short duration). Workers Study 1 DV: Time Taken Study 5 DV: Time Taken When you were solving the puzzle, do you feel that you were doing it as fast as you could? (1=Yes, 2=No) F(1,74)=0.146, p=.7 F(1,109)=2.24,p=.14 While you were working on the puzzle, which of the following best captures what you were thinking? F(1,74)=1.04, p=.3 F(1,109)=0.67,p=.41 (1=I can make more money at the CRL today if I work slower, 2=I can make more money at the CRL today if I work faster, 3=I cannot make any more or less money irrespective of how fast or slow I work) As soon as you figured out the last piece of the puzzle (i.e. what the last piece was and where to put it to solve the puzzle) what did you do? (1=I took my time to put the last piece in its slot and moved on, 2=I put the last piece in its slot right away and moved on) F(1,74)=0.102, p=.8 F(1,109)=1.15,p=.28 After you are done with this study (the puzzle task along with the follow up questions) what did you think you would be required to do? (1=Wait until 5 minutes (15 minutes, until some pre defined amount of time) are over before you can move on to participate in another study or go home, as you wish, 2=Immediately move on to participate in another study or go home, as you wish) F(1,74)=0.0, p=.98 F(1,109)=0.58,p=.44 How knowledgeable would you say that you are about jigsaw puzzles? (1=Not At All 5=Extremely) How often do you solve jigsaw puzzles? (1=Never 4=Frequently) F(1.74)=11.55, p=.001 Short time: M Hi =2.48, M Lo =2.12 Long time: M Hi =1.96, M Lo =3.20 F(1.74)=6.43, p=.01 Short time: M Hi =2.65, M Lo =2.01 Long time: M Hi =1.92, M Lo =3.18 F(1,109)=0.01,p=.90 F(1,109)=0.37,p=.54 Log of Time to read instructions about the task F(1,108)=3.62,p=.06 Short time: M Hi =3.29, M Lo =1.77 Long time: M Hi =3.91, M Lo = 1.73

55 Judges Study 1 Study 5 Think of a situation in which people have a time limit to do a task, and everyone is able to finish the task in the time provided. Which of the following statements do you most agree with? (1=When people have enough time to do a task, giving them still more time leads them to work slower and take longer, 2=When people have enough time to do a task, giving them still more time has no effect on how fast they work and how long it takes, 3=When people have enough time to do a task, giving them still more time makes them work faster and they finish sooner) DV: Time Estimate F(1,67)=0.012, p=.9 DV: Time Estimate of Chosen Contract F(1,167)=0.30,p=.58 How constrained do you think the workers felt when solving the jigsaw puzzle? (1=Not At All Constrained 5=Extremely Constrained) What is your impression of how the workers would have felt while solving the jigsaw puzzle? (1=Felt like a chore 5=Felt like it was fun) Do you think the workers felt accountable to solve the puzzle as soon as they could? (1=Definitely not 5=Definitely yes) Do you think the workers found solving the jigsaw puzzle interesting? (1=Definitely not 5=Definitely yes) Do you think workers had the goal of finishing the puzzle or the goal of taking longer to enjoy the time before finishing it? (1=Definitely wanted to finish it 5=Definitely wanted to take longer to enjoy it more) F(1,67)=11.44, p<.01 Short time: M Hi =4.00, M Lo =3.46 Long time: M Hi =9.80, M Lo =5.59 F(1,67)=4.98, p<.05 Short time: M Hi =4.00, M Lo =3.53 Long time: M Hi =3.87, M Lo =6.92 F(1,67)=0, p=.98 F(1,67)=0.11,p=.7 F(1,67)=0.14,p=.7 How do you think workers were assigned to get the unrestricted time condition, or the 5 minute maximum time condition, or the 15 minute maximum time condition? (1=They were assigned completely at random, 2=They were assigned based on how fast and proficient they were in solving jigsaw puzzles, or some other factor) How do you personally feel about solving jigsaw puzzles? (1=Finishing the puzzle is more enjoyable than the process of solving it, 2=The process of solving the puzzle is more enjoyable than finishing it, 3=Both are enjoyable, Neither is enjoyable) Think of two groups of workers the "low knowledge" people who rated themselves as 1 or 2 and the "high knowledge" people who rated themselves as 4 or 5. There were a similar number of people in both groups in the study. How would you estimate these two groups of workers' time to solve the puzzle when there was no time limit (a time limit of 5 minutes, time limit of 15 minutes)? (low knowledge workers were slower, took the same time, high knowledge workers were slower) Proportion saying 1: P Short = 96.7%, P Long = 100% F(1,67)=3.29,p=.07 Short time: M Hi =4.00, M Lo =3.53 Long time: M Hi =7.33, M Lo =6.56 % said Low knowledge workers slower: short time limit = 66.7%; long time limit = 63.4%; unlimited time= 62.5%

56 Earlier we had told you about how we would determine the completion time of a worker to determine your bonus payment. How do you think we determined the task completion time? F(1,167)=2.21,p=.14 (1=We determined the completion time completely arbitrarily, 2=We determined this number randomly without using the completion time of an actual worker, 3=We randomly picked an actual worker who had earlier attempted the puzzle under exactly the same time limit and under exactly the same contract that you chose and used his/her actual time) How knowledgeable would you say that you are about jigsaw puzzles? (1=Not At All 5=Extremely) F(1,67)=2.23,p=.14 F(1,167)=1.43,p=.23 How often do you solve jigsaw puzzles? (1=Never 4=Frequently) F(1,67)=1.54,p=.22 F(1,167)=1.18,p=.28 Risk aversion: A 50% chance to win $1 (to $9) and a 50% chance to lose $4 F(1,159)=0.02,p=.90 Cognitive Reflection Test (Frederick 2005) F(1,167)=1.59,p=.21 Log of Time to read instructions about the task F(1,67)=0.23, p=.6 F(1,167)=1.66,p=.19 Judges Study 3 DV: Amount of Work How do you think people in the new test group were assigned to one of the two conditions? (1=They were assigned at random, 2=They were assigned based on how fast and proficient they were in solving jigsaw puzzles) How long does one hour feel to you? (Slider with Very Short (0) to Very Long (100) end points) Log of Time to read instructions about the task Log of Time to make the estimation Proportion saying 1: P Short = 97%, P Long = 92% F(1,68)=1.15, p=.29 F(1,68)=2.95, p=.09 Short time: M Hi =118.68, M Lo = Long time: M Hi =184.60, M Lo = F(1,68)=0.16, p=.7

57 Judges Study 4 DV: Time Estimate DV: Amount of Work DV: Rate of Work How many prospective customers do you think were there within mailing distance for the campaign described earlier? Have you ever run a direct marketing campaign in the past or had one done for you? (1=Yes,2= No) What best describes the kind of industry you are currently employed in? (1=B2B,2= B2C, 3=DNK) F(1,97)=0.86, p=.35 F(1,97)=0.14, p=.71 F(1,198)=0.15, p=.7 F(1,97)=0.24, p=.63 F(1,98)=0.08, p=.77 F(1,199)=0.68, p=.41 F(2,87)=0.85, p=.43 F(2,89)=0.24, p=.78 F(2,182)=0.13, p=.9 Population Density (inferred from ZIP codes) F(1,97)=0.09, p=.75 F(1,98)=3.74, p=.06 Short time: M Hi =2.20, M Lo =1.46 Long time: M Hi =2.77, M Lo =1.72 The Rate of Work is based on the entire data since that question was posed to both the cells F(1,199)=1.35, p=.25

58 2. Replication of primary findings with log transformed estimates of time or work as the DV, in order to account for skewed data. Workers: Log of time taken in Long vs. Short time limit Study 1 Study 5 Log (Time Taken) M Short = 0.74 vs. M Long =0.85, t(76)= 1.09, p=.27 M Short = 0.32 vs. M Long =0.89, t(111)= 1.51, p=.13 Study 1 Study 2 Study 5 Judges: Log of predicted time to complete work in Long vs. Short time limit Log (Time Estimate) M Short = 1.25 vs. M Long =1.78, t(69)= 5.64, p<.001 M Short = 3.94 vs. M Long =4.09, t(31)= 1.92, p=.06 M Short = 1.18 vs. M Long =1.85, t(169)= 10.03, p<.001 Study 3 Study 4 Judges: Log of predicted amount of work in Long vs. Short time limit Log (Time Estimate) M Short = 0.41 vs. M Long =0.62, t(100)= 1.76, p=.08 M Short = 4.71 vs. M Long =5.06, t(70)= 2.41, p=.02

59 3. Ordinal regression output (Study 4) DV: Time Taken Estimate Std. Error Wald df p value Short Time Limit <.001** Rate of Work DV: Amount of Work Estimate Std. Error Wald df p value Short Time Limit ** Rate of Work <.001** Population Density ** *significant at α <.05; **significant at α < Regressions for Mediation Analysis in Study 5 Estimated time taken for per minute contract as a function of time limit Estimate Std. Error t value p value Intercept <.001** Short Time Limit <.001** Preference for flat fee contracts as a function of time limit(logistic regression) Estimate Std. Error z value p value Intercept <.001** Short Time Limit <.001**

60 Preference for flat fee contracts as a function of estimated time taken for per minute contract (logistic regression) Estimate Std. Error z value p value Intercept <.001** Estimated time for perminute contract <.001** Preference for flat fee contracts as a function of time limit and including estimated time taken in a perminute contract as a control (logistic regression) Estimate Std. Error z value p value Intercept <.001** Short Time Limit Estimated time for perminute contract ** *significant at α <.05; **significant at α <.01

61 Additional Analysis for Study 2: Comprehension check: After judges answered the main question, we had asked them to indicate their best guess regarding the probability the contractor would take anywhere between 0 to 10 mins, or 30 to 40 mins, or 80 to 90 mins, or 110 to 120 mins to complete the task. If judges had comprehended that the final task completion time would be randomly drawn from an uniform distribution between 30 mins and 90 mins, their prediction of the probabilities would be the same for 30 to 40 mins and 80 to 90 mins, and their estimates for the other two ranges should be zero. 84.8% (short time: 84.2%; long time: 85.7%) of the judges indicated the same proportion for 30 to 40 mins and 80 to 90 mins, while, 69.7% (short time: 63.2%; long time: 78.6%) and 75.8% (short time: 68.4%; long time: 85.7%) indicated zero probability of completing between 0 to 10 mins, and 110 to 120 mins respectively. Among those judges who indicated a non zero probability of completion, 7 out of 9, and 6 out of 7 judges indicated a probability of less than or equal to 0.25% for the 0 to 10 mins and 110 to 120 mins respectively. Overall, the checks indicated fairly good comprehension of the scenario, and given our small sample size, we did not exclude any participants from the analysis. Additional Analysis Study 5: Using the exact distribution of completion times of those workers in Phase 1 who were subject to the contract type chosen by each judge in Phase 2, we compare each judge s contract choice to the expected profit associated with that choice. The flat fee contracts were more likely to be chosen despite the fact that the per minute contract would have, on average, provided a larger expected profit under either time limit, but especially under the long time limit (Long: M per minute =$3.00 to 3.60, M flat fee =$2.50; Short: M per minute =$1.25 to $1.85, M flat fee =$1.00) 1. 1 The expected costs were calculated by rounding off the average time taken by the workers working under perminute fee in either the short or the long time limit conditions and multiplying by the $0.25 rate. The expected profits varied based on whether there was a recruiting fee.

62 Appendix D: Additional Studies Study S1: Effect of Deadlines on Completion Time Estimates for Everyday Activities Method We tested for the prevalence of the proposed association between time limits and estimated task completion times for common everyday activities (n=29 adult online participants). We asked participants to list 5 household chores and the average time they take to complete each one. The five most frequently mentioned chores were house cleaning (30%), washing dishes (9%), laundry (8%), vacuuming (8%) and cooking (7%). Participants were then asked, for each chore they had listed, to estimate how long another typical person would take to do the same work in two different conditions: first for a short and then longer available time limit, within subjects. The short time limit presented was 1.5 times the participants own self reported completion time, while the long time limit was 3 times the participants own self reported completion time. Results We divided the estimated completion time for others by the time which participants reported for themselves for each of the five tasks. We then compared the average of the 5 standardized time estimates for each participant across the two (short vs. long) time limit conditions. Averaging across five tasks, participants estimated an average standardized time of 1.07 (SD=0.19) in the shorter time limit condition, and 1.64 (SD=0.57) in the longer time limit condition, a statistically significant 53 percentage point increase in estimated time (t(28)=5.86, p<.001). We get the same results when we use a regression model with person fixed effects and standard errors clustered at the person level. The majority of participants (79%) gave a longer estimated completion time when more time was available for at least one of the five chores they listed. The results provides evidence that, across a range of participant chosen tasks, people tend to estimate that others will take longer to complete a task when there is a longer time limit. Therefore, the phenomenon described in the paper is very robust and happens even with everyday activities. Study S2: Eliciting Judges Distributional Beliefs Method Online participants (n=88) acted as judges and were provided with the same information about workers as in Phase 2 of Study 1. Judges were told that each worker was randomly assigned to either have a maximum time of 5 minutes (the short time limit), or a maximum time of 15 minutes (the long time limit) to solve the puzzle, and that workers could not choose or influence their time limit. The judges task was to estimate the time it took different workers to finish solving the puzzle, by indicating

63 the proportion of workers in each of a set of time ranges. Further, they were told that the three participants with the most accurate estimates would receive a bonus payment of $5 (5 times the base payment for the study). Judges were randomly assigned to estimate either the short or long time limit condition. For the short time limit condition, judges estimated how many of 100 workers times would fall into each of five one minute long intervals (i.e. "This many workers took up to 1 minute", "This many workers took more than 1 minute and up to 2 minutes,"; see figure D.1 below), or into the did not complete category. For the long time limit condition, judges similarly estimated how many of 100 workers times would fall into a set of intervals (either five three minute long intervals or three five minute long intervals, between subjects, along with the did not complete category). The online interface required the sum of all the allocations to equal 100. By asking each judge to only estimate one distribution, we made sure that the elicited distribution was not affected by prior answers to estimated time. Lastly, judges answered a few follow up questions.

64 Figure D.1: Two between subjects elicitation formats used in the Long time limit condition (15 minutes) in this study. For the short time limit (5 minutes) a format similar to the top panel was used with 1 minute ranges, along with a did not complete option Results Based on the distributions we calculated judges estimated average task completion time in the two time limit conditions. We found that judges estimated a longer completion time for workers in the longer time limit condition (M Short = 2.85, SD=0.73; M Long = 6.86, SD=2.18; t(86)=11.78, p<.001). As in Study 1, the effect of time limits on judges estimates was not moderated by judges experience or liking of puzzles, or how they thought workers felt while working on the puzzle. To test the conditional distribution account, we compared the number of workers estimated to take 5 minutes or less in the long vs. short time limit conditions. If the censoring account explains the effect of time limits, these two estimates should not be statistically different. However, judges estimated that, on average, 92% of the workers (SD= 14.80) would complete the puzzle in under 5 minutes in the short time limit condition, but only 37% of the workers (SD=25.21) would complete the puzzle in 5 minutes or less time in the longer time limit condition (t(65)=11.14, p<.001). To test the bounding account, we also compared the number of workers judges estimated to finish in up to 3 minutes in the long vs. short time limit conditions, which should be the same under the bounding account. However, judges estimated that on fewer workers would complete the puzzle in up to 3 minutes in the shorter than longer time limit condition (M short = 47%, SD =26.0; M long = 18%, SD=20.6, t(65)=4.50, p<.001). This study replicates longer estimated task completion times when more time is made available to the workers for the full estimated distribution, ruling out the bounding and conditional distributional accounts. A follow up question confirmed that nearly all the judges correctly recalled that workers were

65 randomly assigned to the different time limits (e.g., rather than based on worker s proficiency) in all the conditions. The findings are unaffected by excluding the few judges (2%) who failed the comprehension test. Study S3: Estimating Jigsaw Puzzle Completion Times with Irrelevant Time Limits Method Online participants (n=74) played the role of judges and estimated the time to complete a jigsaw puzzle. Judges read a hypothetical scenario, in which a 100 piece jigsaw puzzle was administered to an initial group of people, and no one in the group took more than 28 minutes to solve the puzzle. In the scenario, the same puzzle was then administered to a new worker, who either had unlimited time, or who was randomly assigned to one of two timed conditions based on a coin flip a maximum time of 30 minutes (short time), or a maximum time of 45 minutes (long time). As discussed in Study 1, given that there is only one way to solve the jigsaw puzzle, the workers outcomes cannot differ in quality. The key difference in this study is that the time limit was irrelevant to the worker. The judges were told that the worker in the scenario did not know about the time limit and was instructed to complete the work at his or her own pace. Judges were then asked to estimate the task completion time. Since the time limits were both unknown to the worker and determined at random, the time limit could not signal any private information or influence the workers motivation. Results In the unlimited time (control) condition, judges estimated an average completion time of minutes (SD=10.08). In the time limit conditions, judges estimated a significantly higher task completion time when the time limit was longer (M Short = minutes, SD=1.36; M Long = 30.52, SD=5.20; t(47)=2.53, p = 0.015; see figure D.2 below). Nearly all the judges understood that workers did not know about the time limit and believed they had unlimited time in the two time limit conditions (Short time: 92%; Long time: 96%). The effect of the irrelevant time limits on judges estimates persists even if we exclude the judges who did not answer the comprehension question correctly. Further, all of the judges in both the time limit conditions confirmed their understanding that the time limit was determined at random.

66 40 35 Time Estimate (Minutes) Mins. (Short) 45 Mins. (Long) Unlimited Time Note: Vertical lines are +/ 2SE Figure D.2: Estimated time for task completion in different hidden time limit conditions We once again replicate the effect of time limits on estimates, this time using irrelevant limits, which cannot be explained by beliefs about differences in worker s rate of work, quality of work or information signaling. Given that all of the judges were exposed to the same timing amounts (both the short and long time limits, as well as the 28 minute time for the prior group), regardless of condition, the effect of deadlines also cannot be explained by simple anchoring on available cues. It is also notable that this study replicates our findings for a relatively longer time task, compared to Study 1. Study S4: Hypothetical Workers, Judges Estimating Task Completion Time Method: Online participants acting as judges (n=120) participated in an estimation game where they were required to estimate the time taken by an imaginary worker to solve a jigsaw puzzle of a known number of pieces. Judges were told that in an untimed pre test, a sixty seven piece jigsaw puzzle was solved by a group of workers and no one took more than 31 minutes to solve it. Judges were required to re enter the maximum time taken by the workers in a text box to proceed. This was done to make sure that the judges registered the information. Subsequently judges were told that the same puzzle was being administered to a new worker. Half the judges were told that based on a coin flip the worker was assigned to either a short time limit (35 minutes) or a long time limit (60 minutes) condition. These judges were first asked to estimate the task completion time for the worker in a particular time limit condition (between subjects), and after they had provided their answers, in a subsequent screen were

67 asked to provide estimates for the other time limit condition (unanticipated within subjects). The other half were either told that the worker had no time limit (control), or that the worker had no time limit and the worker spends 60 minutes every day commuting to work (control with an incidental anchor). The latter judges estimated the task completion time for only one of the two control conditions. Before making their estimate, judges were told that they could earn an additional incentive of up to $1 (50% of their base pay) if their estimate was accurate. After the study, the imaginary worker s time was drawn from a uniform distribution of [1, 31] minutes and judges were paid their base pay along with additional bonus based on a linear payoff rule (5 cent deduction for every minute of deviation from the time drawn). Results: In the between subject evaluation, judges predicted significantly higher task completion time for workers who had long time limit than those who had short time limit (M Long = 25.83, SD=5.46; M Short = 33.96, SD=7.46; t(61)=4.92, p<.001). However, the estimates of predicted task completion times in the two control conditions did not differ (M Control = minutes, SD=17.82, M Control with anchor = 27.42, SD=7.24; t<1). Therefore, introduction of an anchor, which was in the same dimension as the quantity to be estimated, did not influence the predicted task completion time. In the within subjects evaluation, judges estimates mirrored their between subject predictions. In the short estimate first condition, judges estimated minutes completion time for the short time limit and minutes (SD=5.33) for the long time limit condition a significant increase (t(30)=11.18, p<.001). Similarly, judges in the long estimate first condition estimated minutes completion time for a long time limit and minutes (SD=5.03) for the short time limit condition a significant decrease (t(31)=6.17, p<.001). Therefore, not only did a longer available time limit increase the estimated task completion time, consideration of a second time limit resulted in an upward or downward revision of the previous estimate, such that more time was estimated for a longer time limit. Finally, introducing an incidental time anchor in the decision environment did not influence the predicted task completion time in the direction of the anchor. Study S5: Eliciting Scope of Work with Distribution of Task Completion Time as Input Method: Online participants (n=130) acting as judges were informed about the range of jigsaw puzzle pieces in the website jigzone.com along with the best and average time taken to complete puzzles of various sizes. In the scenario described to the judges, one puzzle (unknown to the judge) was taken from the website and was administered to a group of workers. Half the judges were told that, based on a coin flip, workers were either given 30 minutes (short time limit) or 45 minutes (long time limit) to solve the puzzle, and the other half were told that the workers had unlimited time to solve the puzzle.

68 Judges were asked to determine the number of pieces there were in the chosen puzzle in one of the time limit conditions (between subjects). Before the judges made their prediction, they were given the complete distribution of time it took the workers, in the form a histogram. Four different histograms were used (between subjects), each with an implied mean of 17.6 minutes. After the judges estimated the number of pieces in the puzzle, they were asked to estimate the average time it took the workers to complete the work in the particular condition. Figure D.3: Four Histograms showing different distributions of completion times in the 30 minutes time limit condition

Eliminating Over-Confidence in Software Development Effort Estimates

Eliminating Over-Confidence in Software Development Effort Estimates Eliminating Over-Confidence in Software Development Effort Estimates Magne Jørgensen 1 and Kjetil Moløkken 1,2 1 Simula Research Laboratory, P.O.Box 134, 1325 Lysaker, Norway {magne.jorgensen, kjetilmo}@simula.no

More information

HMRC Tax Credits Error and Fraud Additional Capacity Trial. Customer Experience Survey Report on Findings. HM Revenue and Customs Research Report 306

HMRC Tax Credits Error and Fraud Additional Capacity Trial. Customer Experience Survey Report on Findings. HM Revenue and Customs Research Report 306 HMRC Tax Credits Error and Fraud Additional Capacity Trial Customer Experience Survey Report on Findings HM Revenue and Customs Research Report 306 TNS BMRB February2014 Crown Copyright 2014 JN119315 Disclaimer

More information

Drivers and Outcomes of Perceived Fairness in Consumer Financial Decisions. Suzanne B. Shu, UCLA Sylvia Morelli, UCLA. Working draft: March 2012

Drivers and Outcomes of Perceived Fairness in Consumer Financial Decisions. Suzanne B. Shu, UCLA Sylvia Morelli, UCLA. Working draft: March 2012 Drivers and Outcomes of Perceived Fairness in Consumer Financial Decisions Suzanne B. Shu, UCLA Sylvia Morelli, UCLA Working draft: March 2012 Abstract In financial decision making, perceived fairness

More information

The Online Journal of New Horizons in Education Volume 3, Issue 3

The Online Journal of New Horizons in Education Volume 3, Issue 3 Undergraduates Who Have a Lower Perception of Controlling Time Fail To Adjust Time Estimation Even When Given Feedback Yoshihiro S. OKAZAKI [1], Tomoya IMURA [2], Masahiro TAKAMURA [3], Satoko TOKUNAGA

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

The availability heuristic in the classroom: How soliciting more criticism can boost your course ratings

The availability heuristic in the classroom: How soliciting more criticism can boost your course ratings Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 1, No. 1, July 2006, pp. 86 90 The availability heuristic in the classroom: How soliciting more criticism can boost your course ratings Craig R. Fox UCLA Anderson School

More information

A Comparison of Training & Scoring in Distributed & Regional Contexts Writing

A Comparison of Training & Scoring in Distributed & Regional Contexts Writing A Comparison of Training & Scoring in Distributed & Regional Contexts Writing Edward W. Wolfe Staci Matthews Daisy Vickers Pearson July 2009 Abstract This study examined the influence of rater training

More information

Project Decision Analysis Process

Project Decision Analysis Process Copyright Notice: Materials published by Intaver Institute Inc. may not be published elsewhere without prior written consent of Intaver Institute Inc. Requests for permission to reproduce published materials

More information

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF CLAIM COSTS

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF CLAIM COSTS ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF CLAIM COSTS Prepared by Associated Economic Consultants Ltd. August 30, 2000 Table of Contents 1. INTRODUCTION...1 FIGURE 1...4 2. DEMOGRAPHIC AND ECONOMIC FACTORS...5 2.1 Population,

More information

CPA Firms Hiring Preferences and the 150-Hour Requirement

CPA Firms Hiring Preferences and the 150-Hour Requirement CPA Firms Hiring Preferences and the 150-Hour Requirement A. Bruce Caster, Wanda Causseaux, and Courtney Droms A. Bruce Caster is Associate Professor of Accounting, Utica College. Wanda Causseaux is Assistant

More information

Savvy software agents can encourage the use of second-order theory of mind by negotiators

Savvy software agents can encourage the use of second-order theory of mind by negotiators CHAPTER7 Savvy software agents can encourage the use of second-order theory of mind by negotiators Abstract In social settings, people often rely on their ability to reason about unobservable mental content

More information

Justifying Simulation. Why use simulation? Accurate Depiction of Reality. Insightful system evaluations

Justifying Simulation. Why use simulation? Accurate Depiction of Reality. Insightful system evaluations Why use simulation? Accurate Depiction of Reality Anyone can perform a simple analysis manually. However, as the complexity of the analysis increases, so does the need to employ computer-based tools. While

More information

Abstract Title: Identifying and measuring factors related to student learning: the promise and pitfalls of teacher instructional logs

Abstract Title: Identifying and measuring factors related to student learning: the promise and pitfalls of teacher instructional logs Abstract Title: Identifying and measuring factors related to student learning: the promise and pitfalls of teacher instructional logs MSP Project Name: Assessing Teacher Learning About Science Teaching

More information

Executive Summary. Summary - 1

Executive Summary. Summary - 1 Executive Summary For as long as human beings have deceived one another, people have tried to develop techniques for detecting deception and finding truth. Lie detection took on aspects of modern science

More information

Evaluation of the Piccard Integrated Service Delivery Pilot

Evaluation of the Piccard Integrated Service Delivery Pilot Evaluation of the Piccard Integrated Service Delivery Pilot Prepared by Wade Bannister, PHD Arizona State University For the Center for the Study of Social Policy Customer Satisfaction Project Table of

More information

Banking on a Bad Bet: Probability Matching in Risky Choice Is Linked to Expectation Generation

Banking on a Bad Bet: Probability Matching in Risky Choice Is Linked to Expectation Generation Research Report Banking on a Bad Bet: Probability Matching in Risky Choice Is Linked to Expectation Generation Psychological Science 22(6) 77 711 The Author(s) 11 Reprints and permission: sagepub.com/journalspermissions.nav

More information

Risk adjustment and shared savings agreements

Risk adjustment and shared savings agreements Risk adjustment and shared savings agreements Hans K. Leida, PhD, FSA, MAAA Leigh M. Wachenheim, FSA, MAAA In a typical shared savings arrangement, claim costs during the measurement or experience period

More information

BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS. In your business planning, have you asked questions like these?

BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS. In your business planning, have you asked questions like these? BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS In your business planning, have you asked questions like these? How much do I have to sell to reach my profit goal? How will a change in my fixed costs affect net income? How much do

More information

A framing effect is usually said to occur when equivalent descriptions of a

A framing effect is usually said to occur when equivalent descriptions of a FRAMING EFFECTS A framing effect is usually said to occur when equivalent descriptions of a decision problem lead to systematically different decisions. Framing has been a major topic of research in the

More information

RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN SELF DIRECTION, EFFORT AND PERFORMANCE IN AN ONLINE INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY COURSE

RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN SELF DIRECTION, EFFORT AND PERFORMANCE IN AN ONLINE INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY COURSE RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN SELF DIRECTION, EFFORT AND PERFORMANCE IN AN ONLINE INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY COURSE William D. Armitage, Naomi Boyer, Sarah Langevin, Alessio Gaspar University of South Florida Polytechnic

More information

Behavior Rating Inventory of Executive Function BRIEF. Interpretive Report. Developed by. Peter K. Isquith, PhD, Gerard A. Gioia, PhD, and PAR Staff

Behavior Rating Inventory of Executive Function BRIEF. Interpretive Report. Developed by. Peter K. Isquith, PhD, Gerard A. Gioia, PhD, and PAR Staff Behavior Rating Inventory of Executive Function BRIEF Interpretive Report Developed by Peter K. Isquith, PhD, Gerard A. Gioia, PhD, and PAR Staff Client Information Client Name : Sample Client Client ID

More information

The Cost of Annoying Ads

The Cost of Annoying Ads The Cost of Annoying Ads DANIEL G. GOLDSTEIN Microsoft Research and R. PRESTON MCAFEE Microsoft Corporation and SIDDHARTH SURI Microsoft Research Display advertisements vary in the extent to which they

More information

Dual payoff scenario warnings on credit card statements elicit suboptimal payoff decisions. Hal E. Hershfield a & Neal J. Roese b

Dual payoff scenario warnings on credit card statements elicit suboptimal payoff decisions. Hal E. Hershfield a & Neal J. Roese b *Title page with author identifiers Running head: DUAL PAYOFF SCENARIOS Dual payoff scenario warnings on credit card statements elicit suboptimal payoff decisions Hal E. Hershfield a & Neal J. Roese b

More information

Gaining Competitive Advantage through Reducing Project Lead Times Duncan Patrick, CMS Montera Inc. Jack Warchalowski, CMS Montera Inc.

Gaining Competitive Advantage through Reducing Project Lead Times Duncan Patrick, CMS Montera Inc. Jack Warchalowski, CMS Montera Inc. Gaining Competitive Advantage through Reducing Project Lead Times Duncan Patrick, CMS Montera Inc. Jack Warchalowski, CMS Montera Inc. Introduction We all know that any successfully completed project has

More information

CROSS EXAMINATION OF AN EXPERT WITNESS IN A CHILD SEXUAL ABUSE CASE. Mark Montgomery

CROSS EXAMINATION OF AN EXPERT WITNESS IN A CHILD SEXUAL ABUSE CASE. Mark Montgomery CROSS EXAMINATION OF AN EXPERT WITNESS IN A CHILD SEXUAL ABUSE CASE Mark Montgomery Post Office Box 161 Durham, NC 27702 (919) 680-6249 mark.montgomery@mindspring.com Opinion Testimony by a Pediatrician/Nurse/Counselor/Social

More information

Picture Memory Improves with Longer On Time and Off Time

Picture Memory Improves with Longer On Time and Off Time Journal ol Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory 197S, Vol. 104, No. 2, 114-118 Picture Memory mproves with Longer On Time and Off Time Barbara Tversky and Tracy Sherman The Hebrew University

More information

Procrastination in Online Courses: Performance and Attitudinal Differences

Procrastination in Online Courses: Performance and Attitudinal Differences Procrastination in Online Courses: Performance and Attitudinal Differences Greg C Elvers Donald J. Polzella Ken Graetz University of Dayton This study investigated the relation between dilatory behaviors

More information

On Correlating Performance Metrics

On Correlating Performance Metrics On Correlating Performance Metrics Yiping Ding and Chris Thornley BMC Software, Inc. Kenneth Newman BMC Software, Inc. University of Massachusetts, Boston Performance metrics and their measurements are

More information

Basic Data Analysis. Stephen Turnbull Business Administration and Public Policy Lecture 12: June 22, 2012. Abstract. Review session.

Basic Data Analysis. Stephen Turnbull Business Administration and Public Policy Lecture 12: June 22, 2012. Abstract. Review session. June 23, 2012 1 review session Basic Data Analysis Stephen Turnbull Business Administration and Public Policy Lecture 12: June 22, 2012 Review session. Abstract Quantitative methods in business Accounting

More information

Through Proper Testing Techniques. By Perry D. Drake

Through Proper Testing Techniques. By Perry D. Drake Through Proper Testing Techniques By Perry D. Drake Seminar Objectives In this lunch session we will discuss how a marketer utilizes a database to ensure maximum return on investment via proper test design

More information

AN INTRODUCTION TO PREMIUM TREND

AN INTRODUCTION TO PREMIUM TREND AN INTRODUCTION TO PREMIUM TREND Burt D. Jones * February, 2002 Acknowledgement I would like to acknowledge the valuable assistance of Catherine Taylor, who was instrumental in the development of this

More information

Credibility: Theory Meets Regulatory Practice Matt Hassett, Arizona State University Brian Januzik, Advance PCS

Credibility: Theory Meets Regulatory Practice Matt Hassett, Arizona State University Brian Januzik, Advance PCS Credibility: Theory Meets Regulatory Practice Matt Hassett, Arizona State University Brian Januzik, Advance PCS 1. Introduction. The examination process requires actuaries to master the theoretical foundations

More information

Adaptive information source selection during hypothesis testing

Adaptive information source selection during hypothesis testing Adaptive information source selection during hypothesis testing Andrew T. Hendrickson (drew.hendrickson@adelaide.edu.au) Amy F. Perfors (amy.perfors@adelaide.edu.au) Daniel J. Navarro (daniel.navarro@adelaide.edu.au)

More information

Jessica S. Banthin and Thomas M. Selden. Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality Working Paper No. 06005. July 2006

Jessica S. Banthin and Thomas M. Selden. Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality Working Paper No. 06005. July 2006 Income Measurement in the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey Jessica S. Banthin and Thomas M. Selden Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality Working Paper No. 06005 July 2006 Suggested citation: Banthin

More information

Selecting Research Participants

Selecting Research Participants C H A P T E R 6 Selecting Research Participants OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter, students should be able to Define the term sampling frame Describe the difference between random sampling and random

More information

A Statistical Analysis of Popular Lottery Winning Strategies

A Statistical Analysis of Popular Lottery Winning Strategies CS-BIGS 4(1): 66-72 2010 CS-BIGS http://www.bentley.edu/csbigs/vol4-1/chen.pdf A Statistical Analysis of Popular Lottery Winning Strategies Albert C. Chen Torrey Pines High School, USA Y. Helio Yang San

More information

WHAT MAKES GREAT TEACHING AND LEARNING? A DISCUSSION PAPER ABOUT INTERNATIONAL RESEARCH APPLIED TO VOCATIONAL CONTEXTS

WHAT MAKES GREAT TEACHING AND LEARNING? A DISCUSSION PAPER ABOUT INTERNATIONAL RESEARCH APPLIED TO VOCATIONAL CONTEXTS WHAT MAKES GREAT TEACHING AND LEARNING? A DISCUSSION PAPER ABOUT INTERNATIONAL RESEARCH APPLIED TO VOCATIONAL CONTEXTS Background Good teaching is the core driver of high quality learning. Linked with

More information

Investors in People Impact Assessment. Final report August 2004

Investors in People Impact Assessment. Final report August 2004 Final report Investors in People Impact Assessment 2004 Final report Investors in People Impact Assessment By: Charles Michaelis Michelle McGuire Final report Contents 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... 5 1.1 BACKGROUND...5

More information

APPENDIX N. Data Validation Using Data Descriptors

APPENDIX N. Data Validation Using Data Descriptors APPENDIX N Data Validation Using Data Descriptors Data validation is often defined by six data descriptors: 1) reports to decision maker 2) documentation 3) data sources 4) analytical method and detection

More information

How To Find Out How Fast A Car Is Going

How To Find Out How Fast A Car Is Going JOURNAL OF VERBAL LEARNING AND VERBAL BEHAVIOR 13, 585-589 (1974) Reconstruction of Automobile Destruction: An Example of the Interaction Between Language and Memory ~ ELIZABETH F. LOFTUS AND JOHN C. PALMER

More information

UNDERSTANDING AND MOTIVATING ENERGY CONSERVATION VIA SOCIAL NORMS. Project Report: 2004 FINAL REPORT

UNDERSTANDING AND MOTIVATING ENERGY CONSERVATION VIA SOCIAL NORMS. Project Report: 2004 FINAL REPORT UNDERSTANDING AND MOTIVATING ENERGY CONSERVATION VIA SOCIAL NORMS Project Report: 2004 FINAL REPORT Robert Cialdini, Ph.D. Arizona State University Wesley Schultz, Ph.D. California State University, San

More information

Eye Tracking on a Paper Survey: Implications for Design

Eye Tracking on a Paper Survey: Implications for Design Eye Tracking on a Paper Survey: Implications for Design Lauren Walton 1, Jennifer Romano Bergstrom 2, David Charles Hawkins 2, Christine Pierce 1 1 The Nielsen Company, Tampa, Florida {lauren.walton, christine.pierce}@nielsen.com

More information

COMPARISON OF DESIGN APPROACHES BETWEEN ENGINEERS AND INDUSTRIAL DESIGNERS

COMPARISON OF DESIGN APPROACHES BETWEEN ENGINEERS AND INDUSTRIAL DESIGNERS INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCE ON ENGINEERING AND PRODUCT DESIGN EDUCATION 5 & 6 SEPTEMBER 2013, DUBLIN INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY, DUBLIN, IRELAND COMPARISON OF DESIGN APPROACHES BETWEEN ENGINEERS AND INDUSTRIAL

More information

THE MONTH IN PENNSYLVANIA WORKERS COMPENSATION: MARCH 2015 AT A GLANCE BY MITCHELL I GOLDING, ESQ

THE MONTH IN PENNSYLVANIA WORKERS COMPENSATION: MARCH 2015 AT A GLANCE BY MITCHELL I GOLDING, ESQ THE MONTH IN PENNSYLVANIA WORKERS COMPENSATION: MARCH 2015 AT A GLANCE BY MITCHELL I GOLDING, ESQ. KENNEDY, CAMPBELL, LIPSKI & DOCHNEY (W) 215-861-6709 ANSWER The sanctions of filing a late answer pursuant

More information

Making Sense of the Mayhem: Machine Learning and March Madness

Making Sense of the Mayhem: Machine Learning and March Madness Making Sense of the Mayhem: Machine Learning and March Madness Alex Tran and Adam Ginzberg Stanford University atran3@stanford.edu ginzberg@stanford.edu I. Introduction III. Model The goal of our research

More information

IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011. Top down approaches to discount rates

IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011. Top down approaches to discount rates IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011 IASB Agenda reference 5A FASB Agenda Staff Paper reference 63A Contacts Matthias Zeitler mzeitler@iasb.org +44 (0)20 7246 6453 Shayne Kuhaneck skuhaneck@fasb.org

More information

Sources of Validity Evidence

Sources of Validity Evidence Sources of Validity Evidence Inferences made from the results of a selection procedure to the performance of subsequent work behavior or outcomes need to be based on evidence that supports those inferences.

More information

Student Experiences in Credit Transfer at Ontario Colleges

Student Experiences in Credit Transfer at Ontario Colleges Student Experiences in Credit Transfer at Ontario Colleges Summary Report Alex Usher Paul Jarvey Introduction Student pathways increasingly rely on transfer between postsecondary institutions as greater

More information

EVALUATION METHODS TIP SHEET

EVALUATION METHODS TIP SHEET EVALUATION METHODS TIP SHEET QUANTITATIVE METHODS: Quantitative data collection methods consist of counts or frequencies, rates or percentages, or other statistics that document the actual existence or

More information

Composite performance measures in the public sector Rowena Jacobs, Maria Goddard and Peter C. Smith

Composite performance measures in the public sector Rowena Jacobs, Maria Goddard and Peter C. Smith Policy Discussion Briefing January 27 Composite performance measures in the public sector Rowena Jacobs, Maria Goddard and Peter C. Smith Introduction It is rare to open a newspaper or read a government

More information

H. The Study Design. William S. Cash and Abigail J. Moss National Center for Health Statistics

H. The Study Design. William S. Cash and Abigail J. Moss National Center for Health Statistics METHODOLOGY STUDY FOR DETERMINING THE OPTIMUM RECALL PERIOD FOR THE REPORTING OF MOTOR VEHICLE ACCIDENTAL INJURIES William S. Cash and Abigail J. Moss National Center for Health Statistics I. Introduction

More information

Organizational Application Managing Employee Retention as a Strategy for Increasing Organizational Competitiveness

Organizational Application Managing Employee Retention as a Strategy for Increasing Organizational Competitiveness Applied H.R.M. Research, 2003, Volume 8, Number 2, pages 63-72 Organizational Application Managing Employee Retention as a Strategy for Increasing Organizational Competitiveness Sunil Ramlall, Ph.D. University

More information

Good decision vs. good results: Outcome bias in the evaluation of financial agents

Good decision vs. good results: Outcome bias in the evaluation of financial agents Good decision vs. good results: Outcome bias in the evaluation of financial agents Christian König-Kersting 1, Monique Pollmann 2, Jan Potters 2, and Stefan T. Trautmann 1* 1 University of Heidelberg;

More information

ALTERNATIVE FUTURES ANALYSIS USING G.P.S.S. THE GENERAL PURPOSE SYSTEMS SIMULATOR IN MANAGEMENT

ALTERNATIVE FUTURES ANALYSIS USING G.P.S.S. THE GENERAL PURPOSE SYSTEMS SIMULATOR IN MANAGEMENT James G. Janossy City of Chicago Datacenter CL-54 Richard J. Daley Center Chicago, Illinois 60602 ALTERNATIVE FUTURES ANALYSIS USING G.P.S.S. THE GENERAL PURPOSE SYSTEMS SIMULATOR IN MANAGEMENT ABSTRACT.

More information

Analyzing Portfolio Expected Loss

Analyzing Portfolio Expected Loss Analyzing Portfolio Expected Loss In this white paper we discuss the methodologies that Visible Equity employs in the calculation of portfolio expected loss. Portfolio expected loss calculations combine

More information

D R A F T. Faculty Senate Ad Hoc Committee on Quality in Online Learning.

D R A F T. Faculty Senate Ad Hoc Committee on Quality in Online Learning. Faculty Senate Ad Hoc Committee on Quality in Online Learning. The Faculty Senate Ad Hoc Committee on the Future Direction of Quality Education is charged with: Defining quality in online/distance education

More information

Community Life Survey Summary of web experiment findings November 2013

Community Life Survey Summary of web experiment findings November 2013 Community Life Survey Summary of web experiment findings November 2013 BMRB Crown copyright 2013 Contents 1. Introduction 3 2. What did we want to find out from the experiment? 4 3. What response rate

More information

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES THE AMERICAN ACADEMY OF ACTUARIES RETIREMENT PLAN PREFERENCES SURVEY REPORT OF FINDINGS. January 2004

SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES THE AMERICAN ACADEMY OF ACTUARIES RETIREMENT PLAN PREFERENCES SURVEY REPORT OF FINDINGS. January 2004 SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES THE AMERICAN ACADEMY OF ACTUARIES RETIREMENT PLAN PREFERENCES SURVEY REPORT OF FINDINGS January 2004 Mathew Greenwald & Associates, Inc. TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION... 1 SETTING

More information

A Hands-On Exercise Improves Understanding of the Standard Error. of the Mean. Robert S. Ryan. Kutztown University

A Hands-On Exercise Improves Understanding of the Standard Error. of the Mean. Robert S. Ryan. Kutztown University A Hands-On Exercise 1 Running head: UNDERSTANDING THE STANDARD ERROR A Hands-On Exercise Improves Understanding of the Standard Error of the Mean Robert S. Ryan Kutztown University A Hands-On Exercise

More information

SPECIFIC LEARNING DISABILITY

SPECIFIC LEARNING DISABILITY SPECIFIC LEARNING DISABILITY 24:05:24.01:18. Specific learning disability defined. Specific learning disability is a disorder in one or more of the basic psychological processes involved in understanding

More information

Running head: RESEARCH PROPOSAL GUIDELINES: APA STYLE. APA Style: An Example Outline of a Research Proposal. Your Name

Running head: RESEARCH PROPOSAL GUIDELINES: APA STYLE. APA Style: An Example Outline of a Research Proposal. Your Name Research Proposal Guidelines: APA Style - 1 Running head: RESEARCH PROPOSAL GUIDELINES: APA STYLE APA Style: An Example Outline of a Research Proposal Your Name School of Health & Applied Human Sciences

More information

A Comparative Study of Database Design Tools

A Comparative Study of Database Design Tools A Comparative Study of Database Design Tools Embarcadero Technologies ER/Studio and Sybase PowerDesigner Usability Sciences Corporation 909 Hidden Ridge, Suite 575, Irving, Texas 75038 tel: 972-550-1599

More information

Organizing Your Approach to a Data Analysis

Organizing Your Approach to a Data Analysis Biost/Stat 578 B: Data Analysis Emerson, September 29, 2003 Handout #1 Organizing Your Approach to a Data Analysis The general theme should be to maximize thinking about the data analysis and to minimize

More information

Experimental methods. Elisabeth Ahlsén Linguistic Methods Course

Experimental methods. Elisabeth Ahlsén Linguistic Methods Course Experimental methods Elisabeth Ahlsén Linguistic Methods Course Experiment Method for empirical investigation of question or hypothesis 2 types a) Lab experiment b) Naturalistic experiment Question ->

More information

Usefulness of expected values in liability valuation: the role of portfolio size

Usefulness of expected values in liability valuation: the role of portfolio size Abstract Usefulness of expected values in liability valuation: the role of portfolio size Gary Colbert University of Colorado Denver Dennis Murray University of Colorado Denver Robert Nieschwietz Seattle

More information

White Paper. Managing the Challenges of Modern Research Surveys. Because some knowledge is too important not to share.

White Paper. Managing the Challenges of Modern Research Surveys. Because some knowledge is too important not to share. White Paper Managing the Challenges of Modern Research Surveys Because some knowledge is too important not to share. Managing the Challenges of Modern Research Surveys One of the most pervasive tools in

More information

Anchoring Bias in Forecast Information Sharing in a Supply Chain

Anchoring Bias in Forecast Information Sharing in a Supply Chain Anchoring Bias in Forecast Information Sharing in a Supply Chain N. Karthikram R.K. Rajagopal G. Janarthanan RKAmit Abstract This paper investigates the behavioral aspects of decision making of retailers,

More information

Glossary of Terms Ability Accommodation Adjusted validity/reliability coefficient Alternate forms Analysis of work Assessment Battery Bias

Glossary of Terms Ability Accommodation Adjusted validity/reliability coefficient Alternate forms Analysis of work Assessment Battery Bias Glossary of Terms Ability A defined domain of cognitive, perceptual, psychomotor, or physical functioning. Accommodation A change in the content, format, and/or administration of a selection procedure

More information

Favorable Interpretations of Ambiguity and Unstable Preferences for Fairness

Favorable Interpretations of Ambiguity and Unstable Preferences for Fairness Carnegie Mellon University Research Showcase @ CMU Department of Social and Decision Sciences Dietrich College of Humanities and Social Sciences 7-26-2005 Favorable Interpretations of Ambiguity and Unstable

More information

A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia

A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia Occasional Studies A Comparative Analysis of Income Statistics for the District of Columbia ACS Income Estimates vs. DC Individual Income Tax Data Jayron Lashgari Office of Revenue Analysis Office of the

More information

2013 AMERICAN COMMUNITY SURVEY RESEARCH AND EVALUATION REPORT MEMORANDUM SERIES ACS13-RER- 11

2013 AMERICAN COMMUNITY SURVEY RESEARCH AND EVALUATION REPORT MEMORANDUM SERIES ACS13-RER- 11 4/4/13 2013 AMERICAN COMMUNITY SURVEY RESEARCH AND EVALUATION REPORT MEMORANDUM SERIES ACS13-RER- 11 MEMORANDUM FOR ACS Research and Evaluation Advisory Group From: James B. Treat (signed on 04/10/2013)

More information

MANIPULATING SLOT MACHINE PREFERENCE IN PROBLEM GAMBLERS THROUGH CONTEXTUAL CONTROL BECKY L. NASTALLY, MARK R. DIXON, AND JAMES W.

MANIPULATING SLOT MACHINE PREFERENCE IN PROBLEM GAMBLERS THROUGH CONTEXTUAL CONTROL BECKY L. NASTALLY, MARK R. DIXON, AND JAMES W. JOURNAL OF APPLIED BEHAVIOR ANALYSIS 2010, 43, 125 129 NUMBER 1(SPRING 2010) MANIPULATING SLOT MACHINE PREFERENCE IN PROBLEM GAMBLERS THROUGH CONTEXTUAL CONTROL BECKY L. NASTALLY, MARK R. DIXON, AND JAMES

More information

Using Retrocausal Practice Effects to Predict On-Line Roulette Spins. Michael S. Franklin & Jonathan Schooler UCSB, Department of Psychology.

Using Retrocausal Practice Effects to Predict On-Line Roulette Spins. Michael S. Franklin & Jonathan Schooler UCSB, Department of Psychology. Using Retrocausal Practice Effects to Predict On-Line Roulette Spins Michael S. Franklin & Jonathan Schooler UCSB, Department of Psychology Summary Modern physics suggest that time may be symmetric, thus

More information

B-11-3. Response: Page 1 of 1

B-11-3. Response: Page 1 of 1 Information Request No..1 RR BCCA.BI.1.a-b Dated 04 May 16 March Insurance Corporation of British Columbia B-11-3.1 RR BCCA.BI.1.a-b Reference: Page 5-2, paragraph 6, the first bullet point refers to "An

More information

TIPS DATA QUALITY STANDARDS ABOUT TIPS

TIPS DATA QUALITY STANDARDS ABOUT TIPS 2009, NUMBER 12 2 ND EDITION PERFORMANCE MONITORING & EVALUATION TIPS DATA QUALITY STANDARDS ABOUT TIPS These TIPS provide practical advice and suggestions to USAID managers on issues related to performance

More information

Data Communications Company (DCC) price control guidance: process and procedures

Data Communications Company (DCC) price control guidance: process and procedures Guidance document Contact: Tricia Quinn, Senior Economist Publication date: 27 July 2015 Team: Smarter Metering Email: tricia.quinn@ofgem.gov.uk Overview: The Data and Communications Company (DCC) is required

More information

The 2006 Earnings Public-Use Microdata File:

The 2006 Earnings Public-Use Microdata File: The 2006 Earnings Public-Use Microdata File: An Introduction by Michael Compson* This article introduces the 2006 Earnings Public-Use File (EPUF) and provides important background information on the file

More information

Relative Effectiveness of Computer-based and Human Feedback for Enhancing Student Learning

Relative Effectiveness of Computer-based and Human Feedback for Enhancing Student Learning Relative Effectiveness of -based Feedback for Enhancing Student Learning B. Jean Mernach, Park University Abstract In an online learning environment, students are forced to rely on feedback to gauge the

More information

How To Understand And Understand Social Intercorrelations In A Market

How To Understand And Understand Social Intercorrelations In A Market 1 Conditional projection [Texto impreso] : how own evaluations influence beliefs about others whose choices are known / A. Yeçim Orhun and Oleg Urminsky References: p. 123-124 : 37 refs. Abstract: The

More information

A Practical Application of Differential Privacy to Personalized Online Advertising

A Practical Application of Differential Privacy to Personalized Online Advertising A Practical Application of Differential Privacy to Personalized Online Advertising Yehuda Lindell Eran Omri Department of Computer Science Bar-Ilan University, Israel. lindell@cs.biu.ac.il,omrier@gmail.com

More information

IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 23

IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 23 IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 23 Note Before using this information and the product it supports, read the information in Notices on page 25. Product Information This edition applies to version 23, release

More information

Progress Report Phase I Study of North Carolina Evidence-based Transition to Practice Initiative Project Foundation for Nursing Excellence

Progress Report Phase I Study of North Carolina Evidence-based Transition to Practice Initiative Project Foundation for Nursing Excellence Progress Report Phase I Study of North Carolina Evidence-based Transition to Practice Initiative Project Foundation for Nursing Excellence Prepared by the NCSBN Research Department INTRODUCTION In 2006,

More information

CONTRACT MANAGEMENT PROCESSES ACROSS THE COUNCIL PROGRAM EVALUATION AND AUDIT

CONTRACT MANAGEMENT PROCESSES ACROSS THE COUNCIL PROGRAM EVALUATION AND AUDIT CONTRACT MANAGEMENT PROCESSES ACROSS THE COUNCIL PROGRAM EVALUATION AND AUDIT June 2013 INTRODUCTION Background From the 4 th Quarter of 2011 through the 3 rd Quarter of 2012 the Metropolitan Council expended

More information

Abstract Title Page Not included in page count.

Abstract Title Page Not included in page count. Abstract Title Page Not included in page count. Title: The Impact of The Stock Market Game on Financial Literacy and Mathematics Achievement: Results from a National Randomized Controlled Trial. Author(s):

More information

PROJECT MANAGEMENT PLAN Outline VERSION 0.0 STATUS: OUTLINE DATE:

PROJECT MANAGEMENT PLAN Outline VERSION 0.0 STATUS: OUTLINE DATE: PROJECT MANAGEMENT PLAN Outline VERSION 0.0 STATUS: OUTLINE DATE: Project Name Project Management Plan Document Information Document Title Version Author Owner Project Management Plan Amendment History

More information

IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 22

IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 22 IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 22 Note Before using this information and the product it supports, read the information in Notices on page 25. Product Information This edition applies to version 22, release

More information

Frequently Asked Questions (Including Definitions)

Frequently Asked Questions (Including Definitions) My Business Income Consultation from Chubb Frequently Asked Questions (Including Definitions) Frequently Asked Questions How To Use The Tool Click on the question that you would like to have answered.

More information

MANAGING FOR THE UNEXPECTED

MANAGING FOR THE UNEXPECTED Ross Thought in Action MANAGING FOR THE UNEXPECTED Kathleen M. Sutcliffe Professor, University of Michigan, Stephen M. Ross School of Business Marlys K. Christianson Assistant Professor, University of

More information

BACKGROUND ON THE SURVEY PROCESS

BACKGROUND ON THE SURVEY PROCESS Chapter Two BACKGROUND ON THE SURVEY PROCESS In this chapter, we present an overview of the various aspects of the research survey process. 1 We emphasize that surveying should first be thought of as a

More information

Statistical & Technical Team

Statistical & Technical Team Statistical & Technical Team A Practical Guide to Sampling This guide is brought to you by the Statistical and Technical Team, who form part of the VFM Development Team. They are responsible for advice

More information

Staff Paper 6. Allowed for operating costs. 6.1 Introduction

Staff Paper 6. Allowed for operating costs. 6.1 Introduction Staff Paper 6 Allowed for operating costs This staff paper has been produced by our office to assist stakeholders in responding to the Draft Determination. The material reflected in this staff paper has

More information

A Better Approach to Target Date Strategies

A Better Approach to Target Date Strategies February 2011 A Better Approach to Target Date Strategies Executive Summary In 2007, Folio Investing undertook an analysis of Target Date Funds to determine how these investments might be improved. As

More information

Five-Year Changes in Instructional Quality and Course Enrollments in the Northeast Tennessee i3 Consortium

Five-Year Changes in Instructional Quality and Course Enrollments in the Northeast Tennessee i3 Consortium Five-Year Changes in Instructional Quality and Course Enrollments in the Northeast Tennessee i3 Consortium Quarterly Report, May July 2015 Tom Geraghty and Steve Lee, CNA Education July 2015 Unlimited

More information

THE FUTURE OF INTERNET-BASED SURVEY METHODS

THE FUTURE OF INTERNET-BASED SURVEY METHODS Chapter Seven CONCLUSIONS In this chapter, we offer some concluding thoughts on the future of Internet-based surveys, the issues surrounding the use of e-mail and the Web for research surveys, and certain

More information

How To Check For Differences In The One Way Anova

How To Check For Differences In The One Way Anova MINITAB ASSISTANT WHITE PAPER This paper explains the research conducted by Minitab statisticians to develop the methods and data checks used in the Assistant in Minitab 17 Statistical Software. One-Way

More information

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Javier García Sánchez, IAE Business School Lorenzo Preve, IAE Business School Virginia Sarria Allende, IAE Business School Abstract The expected cost of capital is a crucial

More information

E-discovery Taking Predictive Coding Out of the Black Box

E-discovery Taking Predictive Coding Out of the Black Box E-discovery Taking Predictive Coding Out of the Black Box Joseph H. Looby Senior Managing Director FTI TECHNOLOGY IN CASES OF COMMERCIAL LITIGATION, the process of discovery can place a huge burden on

More information

Paper-based Instructions Experiment 1 - TRANSLATED FROM GERMAN - (text in green indicates manipulations; comments are highlighted yellow.

Paper-based Instructions Experiment 1 - TRANSLATED FROM GERMAN - (text in green indicates manipulations; comments are highlighted yellow. Paper-based Instructions Experiment 1 - TRANSLATED FROM GERMAN - (text in green indicates manipulations; comments are highlighted yellow.) Imagine your are working as a broker at the stock market. You

More information

Michigan Department of Treasury Tax Compliance Bureau Audit Division. Audit Sampling Manual

Michigan Department of Treasury Tax Compliance Bureau Audit Division. Audit Sampling Manual Audit Division Audit Sampling Manual Disclosure This manual is not intended as a statement of law, Department policy, or of the Treasurer s official position. The information contained in this manual has

More information