How Does Assortment Affect Grocery Store Choice?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "How Does Assortment Affect Grocery Store Choice?"

Transcription

1 How Does Assortment Affect Grocery Store Choice? Richard A. Briesch (Southern Methodist University)* Pradeep K. Chintagunta (University of Chicago)** Edward J. Fox (Southern Methodist University)*** September 2004 Revised July 2005 Revised July 2006 Revised September 2007 Revised January 2008 * Assistant Professor of Marketing, Edwin L. Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University, Dallas, TX; phone: ; TUrbriesch@mail.cox.smu.edu UT ** Robert Law Professor of Marketing, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL; phone ; TUpradeep.chintagunta@gsb.uchicago.eduUT *** Associate Professor of Marketing, Edwin L. Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University, Dallas, TX; phone: ; TUefox@mail.cox.smu.edu UT The authors would like to thank David Bell and John Slocum for their comments and suggestions. The second author also thanks the Kilts Center for Marketing at the Chicago GSB for financial support. Any mistakes or omissions are the sole responsibility of the authors.

2 2 How Does Assortment Affect Grocery Store Choice? We investigate the impact of product assortments, along with convenience, prices and feature advertising, on consumers grocery store choice decisions. Extending recent research on store choice, we add assortments as a predictor, specify a very general structure for heterogeneity, and estimate store choice and category needs models simultaneously. Using household-level market basket data, we find that assortments are generally more important than retail prices in store choice decisions. We find that the number of brands offered in retail assortments has a positive effect on store choice for most households, while the number of stock-keeping-units [SKUs] per brand, sizes per brand and proportion of SKUs sold at a store that are unique to that store (a proxy for presence of private labels) have a negative effect on store choice for most households. We also find more heterogeneity in response to assortment than to either convenience or price. Optimal assortments therefore depend on the particular preferences of a retailer s shoppers. Finally, we find a correlation in householdlevel responses to assortment and travel distance (r=0.43), suggesting that the less important assortment is to a consumer s store choices, the more the consumer values convenience and vice versa. (keywords: assortment, store choice, shopping behavior, retail, random effects)

3 Introduction Why do consumers shop at the stores they do? Marketing academics and practitioners have long recognized the importance of this question because it affects not only where consumers buy, but what and how much they buy. Shoppers consistently say that retail assortments affect their store choice decisions, ranking it third in importance behind convenient locations and low prices as a choice criterion (Arnold, Ma and Tigert 1978; Arnold and Tigert 1981; Arnold, Roth and Tigert 1981; Arnold, Oum and Tigert 1983). The most widely-used theory implies that shoppers prefer larger assortments. The law of retail gravitation, the foundational theory of store choice, suggests that the probability of choosing a retail outlet is positively related to its size but inversely related to its distance from the shopper s home (Reilly 1931; Huff 1964; see Hubbard 1978 and Brown 1989 for reviews of this work; Baumol and Ide 1956 makes a similar argument). The size of the outlet, a proxy for product selection, is the product of the number of categories offered and the number of items within each category (Levy and Weitz 2004 p. 370). Because most grocery stores carry the same categories, differences in product selection across stores depend almost entirely on variation in category assortments. Retail gravitation models have been used extensively in the analysis of retail competition and for retail site selection decisions. In contrast, recent studies have failed to find a positive relationship between assortment size and category sales in grocery stores (IRI and Bishop 1993; Dreze, Hoch and Purk 1994; Broniarczk, Hoyer and McAlister 1998). In fact, one study of an internet grocer found a significant negative relationship between assortment size and category sales (Boatwright and Nunes 2001) implying that grocery stores are over-assorted. However, Fox, Montgomery and Lodish (2004) calculated assortment elasticities for grocery (and nongrocery) retailers and found that assortment size positively affects the probability that shoppers patronize their stores. Using the data from Boatwright and Nunes (2001), Borle, et

4 2 al. (2005) also found that the assortment reductions which increase category sales negatively affect long-term patronage. In this study, we propose and estimate a model of grocery store choice with assortment variables as predictors, along with convenience (defined as travel distance to the store), price (defined as cost of the basket) and feature advertising. Our research objectives are to understand how product assortments affect grocery store choice decisions, to determine how important assortments are in those decisions and to address conflicting findings about assortment size in the extant literature. Drawing on that literature (e.g., Broniarczyk, Hoyer and McAlister 1998, Boatwright and Nunes 2001, and Corstjens and Lal 2000), we characterize assortments based on the (i) number of brands, (ii) number of stock keeping units (SKUs) per brand, (iii) number of sizes per brand, (iv) proportion of SKUs that are unique to the retailer (a proxy for private label) and (v) availability of a household s favorite brands. Our key findings: In general, the number of brands in an assortment and the presence of a household s favorite brands increase that household s probability of choosing a store; the number of SKUs per brand, the number of sizes per brand and the number of unique SKUs do not. These results suggest that the effect of assortment on store choice is more nuanced than previously known and that the effect of adding or deleting an SKU depends upon how it fits in the category assortment Does it increase/decrease the number of brands or sizes offered? Is it unique to that retailer? Is it a favorite of many households? The conflicting findings in the literature may be a result of more limited characterizations of assortment. Unobserved heterogeneity, reflected in the distribution of household-level response parameters, was found to be much greater for assortment than for other determinants of store choice. While shoppers uniformly prefer lower prices and shorter travel distances,

5 3 our analysis suggests that shoppers prefer different assortment characteristics. Specifically, a substantial minority prefer stores that offer more SKUs per brand, more sizes per brand, and more unique SKUs but fewer different brands. Our analysis of consumer heterogeneity reveals that response to assortment is correlated with response to travel distance (r=0.43). Thus, the less importance a household ascribes to assortment, the more it values convenience and vice versa. This finding is consistent with the tradeoff suggested by Baumol and Ide (1956) and Brown (1978). Contrary to shoppers self reports, we find that store choice decisions are generally more responsive to changes in assortment than to changes in price. Beyond these key findings, our study contributes to the literature on store choice in two additional ways. First, it extends the approach of Bell, Ho and Tang (1998) to include product assortment and demonstrates its effect on store choice decisions. Incorporating assortment, along with travel distance, price and feature advertising in our store choice model results in (i) better model fit and prediction, (ii) insights that are relevant to retail managers and (iii) a more complete characterization of retail competition. Second, the study identifies important differences between shoppers response to assortments and to the other key determinants of store choice convenience and prices. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section provides a review of related literature. Next, we develop the econometric model of store choice and introduce the panel dataset. This is followed by a description of the data used in the analysis. The penultimate section discusses the model fit and presents the empirical results. Finally, we discuss the results and their implications, along with topics for future research.

6 4 Related Literature Store choice has been modeled extensively at the aggregate level (assuming that all shoppers share the same preference parameters) since Hotelling s (1929) landmark analysis of spatial competition. More recently, disaggregate analysis of shopping decisions (assuming that preference parameters vary by shopper) has become possible due to market basket data from household scanner panels, advances in choice modeling, and increases in computing power (e.g., Bell and Lattin 1998; Bell, Ho, and Tang 1998; Rhee and Bell 2002, Fox, Montgomery and Lodish 2004). Disaggregate analysis has focused primarily on differences between retail everyday low price (EDLP) and promotional (HiLo) pricing formats. The benchmark disaggregate store choice model comes from Bell, Ho and Tang (1998), hereafter BHT, which investigated the effect of retail price format on patronage across consumer segments. BHT observed that consumers incur lower variable costs (i.e., pay lower prices) but higher fixed costs (i.e., less convenient locations) with EDLP stores as compared to HiLo stores. The implied tradeoff between price and convenience led them to frame the competition between stores with different pricing formats in terms of the size of consumers shopping lists; i.e., consumers choose EDLP stores if their shopping lists exceed a household-specific threshold; they choose HiLo stores when they intend to buy less. Yet previous research showed that consumers make a different tradeoff when choosing a store. Baumol and Ide (1956) and Brown (1978) observed that shoppers may be willing to travel farther to stores that offer more products in their assortments than to stores which offer fewer products. They also found that, unlike lower prices and more convenience locations, larger assortments are not always preferred. The following stylized facts guide our modeling approach. More assortment better Broniarczyk and Hoyer (2006) chose this title for their review of the growing body of evidence that shoppers may prefer smaller grocery store assortments.

7 5 Assortment is fundamentally different from price and convenience in that lower prices and more convenience are uniformly preferred, but larger assortments are not. For this reason, we will neither restrict nor expect the effect of assortment on store choice to be positive. Assortment is multidimensional Broniarczyk, Hoyer and McAlister (1998) determined that three factors affect consumers perceptions of assortment in a category the number of SKUs, the amount of shelf space devoted to the category and the availability of the consumer s favorite item (note that the terms item, product and SKUs will be used interchangeably). Hoch, Bradlow and Wansink (1999) determined that product attributes affect consumers perceptions of an assortment. In practice, these attributes are largely category-specific (e.g., Hardie, Johnson, and Fader 1996). However, the number of brands and sizes are attributes that can be applied parsimoniously across categories (Boatwright and Nunes 2001). The availability of private label items in assortments can also have an effect on store loyalty (Corstjens and Lal 2000). We require a parsimonious model using variables that can be measured in our panel dataset, so we have chosen the following measures of category assortments: (i) number of brands offered, (ii) number of SKUs per brand, (iii) number of sizes per brand, (iv) proportion of SKUs that are unique to the retailer (a proxy for private label) and (v) availability of a household s favorite brands. Assortment preferences are heterogeneous Broniarczyk, Hoyer and McAlister (1998) showed that shoppers perceptions of a retail assortment depend on the availability of their favorite items. Clearly, favorite items vary by individual. In addition, the ideal size of an assortment depends on shopping costs (Baumol and Ide 1956). Because shopping costs are a function of wage rates, education, expertise, etc., the ideal assortment size also varies by individual. We model heterogeneity in assortment response in two ways. First, we include the availability of the consumer s preferred brands in our definition of assortment. Second, we capture unobserved heterogeneity in assortment response by specifying a random effects

8 6 model. Unobserved heterogeneity in assortment response is also allowed to covary with response to prices and travel distance. Model We specify a model that exploits two sources of variation in panel data betweenhousehold retailer preferences and within-household needs over time. Our approach is similar to that of BHT but extends their framework to incorporate product assortment. Our model assumes that, after deciding to make a shopping trip, the process by which the shopper chooses a store can be summarized in the following three steps: 1) Determine which categories the household needs. 2) Calculate the utility of shopping for those household needs at each competing store chain. The utility depends on travel distances to the nearest store of the chain as well as demonstrated preference for that store (fixed component). The utility also depends on expected prices, feature advertising and assortments for categories that the household needs at the time of the visit (variable component). 3) Choose the store chain that offers the highest utility. The primary difference between our approach and that of BHT is how withinhousehold variation (step 1 above) is modeled. BHT assumes that the shopper constructs a list of planned purchases that is not observed by the researcher prior to choosing a store. BHT models the probability that purchased items were on this shopping list as a function of household inventories, consumption rates, and retailer price discounts. We assume instead that, when choosing a store, consumers pay attention to the categories they need. This assumption results in a model of time-varying attention that, while similar to BHT s shopping list model, is different in three important ways. First, we model selective attention at the category rather than SKU-level. This aggregation makes our model internally consistent because product assortment is defined at the category level (Levy and Weitz 2004 p. 370) and consistent with the extant literature showing that needs are realized at

9 7 the category-level (e.g., Spiggle 1987, Chib, Seetharaman, and Strijnev 2004). Second, needs are independent of the store while the shopping list may not be. Consider a shopper whose household needs apples. That shopper might know of an advertised discount on apples at a particular store or prefer the quality of its apples strongly enough that s/he would plan to buy apples only if that store were chosen. Modeling a store-specific shopping list would greatly complicate our analysis and so is left for future research. Third, modeling household needs allows for the possibility that categories not purchased may have been needed a priori. After all, the shopper may encounter prices in the store that exceed her/his reservation price or products that are out-of-stock. Note that our approach does not preclude the possibility that shoppers purchase categories that are not needed, i.e., impulse purchases. Impulse purchase decisions are made in-store after the store choice decision. Impulse purchasing is therefore more relevant to category incidence models and so is left for future research in this area. A final difference between our model and that of BHT is that we assume unobserved heterogeneity is continuously distributed while BHT specified a discrete mixture model. While there is no consensus about the relative virtues of continuous versus discrete specifications of heterogeneity (Allenby and Rossi 1999; Wedel, et al 1999; Andrews, Ainslie, and Currim 2002), our continuous heterogeneity assumption enables us to investigate covariation in response to assortment, price and travel distance, a key objective of our paper. Category Needs Modeling within-household variation in store choice requires that we determine the probability that household h (h=1,, H) needs category c h (c h =1,, C h indexes the categories consumed by household h; the h subscript will be suppressed hereafter) on store visit v h (v h =1,, V h ; again the h subscript will be suppressed hereafter). I hvc is an indicator variable that is set to one when household h purchases in category c on visit v. Note that I hvc

10 8 does not contain an s subscript and so is not specific to a store. This is based on our assumption that category purchases are a reflection of household needs (Chib, Seetharaman and Strijnev 2004) with households paying attention to the prices, assortments and feature advertising of products in those categories that they need. We also assume that the needs of household h for category c on store visit v can be represented by Pr(I hvc ), the probability that I hvc = 1. Further, the drivers of category need, i.e., Pr(I hvc ), are a household s intrinsic preference to purchase that category, the household s inventory in the category and the rate at which that inventory is consumed. Note that Pr(I hvc ) > 0 even for categories that are not subsequently purchased, indicating a non-zero probability that consumers need and so pay attention to those categories as well. Since category needs, Pr(I hvc ), depend on the household s inventory and the rate at which that inventory is consumed, we need to operationalize these variables. Following the arguments of Erdem, Imai and Keane (2003) and Nevo and Hendel (2002), we do not construct an inventory variable. Instead, we reason that inventory is always increased by the amount of the most recent category purchase and then consumed at a non-negative rate. Because the probability of category purchase is negatively related to inventory level (Chib, Seetharaman, and Strijnev 2004), we expect that: (i) as the quantity of the most recent category purchase increases, the probability that the category will be purchased decreases; and (ii) as time since the most recent category purchase increases, the probability that the category will be purchased also increases. Note that both time since the most recent category purchase and quantity of that purchase are observed in the data. We specify a threshold crossing model of category need with the systematic component of indirect utility specified in equation (2.1) (note that the total indirect utility includes this systematic component and a random component). W hvc = γ + γ T T ) + γ ( Q Q ) + γ ( T T )( Q Q ) (2.1) 0hc 1hc ( hvc hc 2hc hvc hc 3hc hvc hc hvc hc

11 9 where T hvc is the time (in days) since household h s most recent purchase in category c, Thc the average time between household h s purchases in category c, Q hvcb is the quantity that household h bought on the most recent purchase in category c and is Q hc is the average quantity of household h s purchases in category c. T hvcb and Q hvc are mean centered by household to control for differences in average consumption rates. The interaction between time since the most recent category purchase and quantity purchased on that occasion is also included in equation (2.1); this allows consumption rates to vary over time. Assuncao and Meyer (1993) showed that the consumption rate should be highest immediately after a purchase, then decrease as inventory is depleted. Thus, we expect the interaction parameter γ 3hc to be negative. Assuming that the random component of the indirect utility, ξ, follows an hvc extreme value distribution, we specify Pr(I hvc ) in equation (2.2). Pr(I hvc ) = (1+exp(-W hvc )) -1 (2.2) Store Choice Borrowing BHT s general framework, we specify the utility of household h choosing store chain s (s=1,, S) on store visit v in equation (2.3) as a function of fixed and variable components plus an error term. U hsv = Fixed hs +Variable hsv +ε hsv (2.3) Note that we are modeling the choice of a store chain rather than an individual store. This permits a more parsimonious characterization of the shopping alternatives captured in multioutlet panel data. Fixed Component - The fixed component of utility depends on the factors shown in equation (2.4). Fixed hs = β 0hs +β 1h L hs +β 2h ln(d hs +1) (2.4)

12 10 where β 0hs is a household-specific intercept for store chain s, L hs is a store loyalty variable, and DBhsB is the distance from household h s home to the closest store of chain s (in miles). The household subscript on all parameters will be addressed in our discussion of unobserved heterogeneity later in this section. Store loyalty is defined in equation (2.5). L hs = (N hs +1/S)/(N h +1) (2.5) where N hs is the number of visits made by household h to store chain s during the initialization period and N h is the total number of store visits by household h during that period. Thus, it is approximately the proportion of visits made to store chain s during the initialization period. We expect loyalty to be a positive predictor of store choice. Travel distance is log-transformed so that, consistent with retail gravitation models, it has a decreasing marginal effect. Variable Component The variable component of utility is specified in equation (2.6) as a linear combination of three factors. Variable hsv = Price hsv +Feat hsv +Assort hsv (2.6) where Price hsv captures the effect of prices, Feat hsv captures the effect of feature advertising, and Assort hsv captures the effect of assortment on household h s utility of shopping at store chain s on visit v. The variable component of utility is computed by summing category price, feature, and assortment measures, each weighted by the probability that the household needs the category at the time of the visit. Price - Price hsv is specified in equation (2.7) as the probability that the category is needed, multiplied by both the expected price at store chain s and the expected quantity. C h 3hcs c= 1 ( I ) E( Q ) E( P ) Price = β Pr (2.7) hsv hvc hvc svc

13 11 where E(Q hvc ) is quantity of category c that household h would be expected to purchase on visit v and E(P svc ) is the expected price-per-unit in category c at store chain s during visit v. E(Q hvc ) is operationalized as the average quantity purchased by household h over the entire period of our dataset in equation (2.8). E ( Q htc ) = Qhc (2.8) Note that using average household purchase quantity over time in the expected spending variable does not introduce endogeneity because it is not correlated with visit-level prices, promotions or other causal variables (Ainslie and Rossi 1998 p.97 made a similar argument for using average category expenditure over time as a covariate for their brand choice model). E(P svc ) is operationalized as the average price-per-unit of products in category c at store chain s during visit v as shown in equation (2.9). E ( P svc ) = Psvc (2.9) Using actual prices as a proxy for expected prices during visit v implies rational expectations. We could have operationalized expected prices in other ways, such as exponentially smoothing previous prices. However, we find empirical support for the rational expectations assumption in the data (see the web-based appendix). We leave it to future research to determine how category-level price expectations are formed. Feature Advertising Feat hsv is specified in equation (2.10) as the probability that the category is needed, multiplied by an indicator variable of feature advertising in the category. Feat hsv C β 4hsc c= 1 = C c= 1 Pr( I Pr( I hvc hvc ) )F svc (2.10)

14 12 where F svc is a binary variable indicating whether at least one SKU in category c was feature advertised by store chain s during visit v. The need-weighted advertising variable, Pr(I hvc )F svcb, is divided by the sum of those weights (i.e., the sum of probabilities that individual categories are needed) to ensure that the effect of feature advertising does not depend on basket size. This avoids collinearity with Price hsv which does depend on basket size. Feature advertising activity should increase the probability of choosing a store so we expect β 4hsc to be positive. Assortment Assort hsv is specified in equation (2.11) as the average of category-level assortment variables weighted by the probability that the household needs the category. Assort hsv C 5h c= 1 = C β Pr( I c= 1 Pr( I hvc hvc ) A ) hsvc (2.11) where A hsvc is a household-specific assortment variable for category c at store chain s during visit v. Again, that the need-weighted assortment variable, Pr(I hvc )A hsvcb, is divided by the sum of those weights (i.e., the sum of probabilities that individual categories are needed) so that the effect of assortment does not depend on basket size. Previous research has determined that assortment is multidimensional (Broniarczyk, Hoyer, and McAlister 1998; Hoch, Bradlow and Wansink 1999; Boatwright and Nunes 2001). Accordingly, the assortment variable A hsvc is specified in equation (2.12) to incorporate the number of SKUs, brands, and sizes that the retailer offers, availability of the household s preferred brands, as well as the proportion of items that are unique to the retailer (a proxy for private label items). where A hsvc = SKU svc +β 6h Size svc +β 7h Brand svc +β 8h FavBrand hsvc +β 9h Unique svc (2.12)

15 13 SKU svc is the number of SKUs/brand in category c scanned by the store chain during the week of visit v divided by the average number of SKUs/brand in category c across all store chains and all weeks; the parameter is set to one for model identification, Size svc is the number of different sizes/brand in category c scanned by the store chain during the week of visit v divided by the average number of sizes/brand in category c across all store chains and all weeks. Brand svc is the number of brands in category c scanned by the retailer during the week of visit v divided by the average number of brands in category c across all store chains and all weeks. FavBrand hsvc is the average of (0,1) variables indicating whether household h s three most frequently purchased brands in category c are carried in the retailer s assortment (weighted by the number of previous purchases the household made of each brand). The measure is effectively the proportion of the household s favorite brands that are carried by the retailer. Unique svc is the proportion of SKUs in category c scanned during the week of visit v that are unique to the store chain divided by the proportion of SKUs in category c that are unique across all store chains and all weeks. Together, these five variables capture the dimensions of assortment that were found to be significant in previous research, are available in our panel dataset and can be parsimoniously applied across categories. Each of these variables except FavBrand is normalized by the market average so it comparable across categories (see the web-based appendix). The parameters in equation (2.12) vary across households, as indicated by the h subscripts. They are modeled as random effects, assuming that the parameters share a common variance component which is set to unity for identification (see Erdem 1996 for a discussion of identification conditions). Within-household variation in Assort hsv comes from two sources: changes in which categories the household needs and changes in retailer assortments over time. To determine how much variation comes from each source, we estimated one-way analyses of variance for weekly brand, SKU/brand, and size/brand counts in ten categories at four grocery retailers

16 14 (see Table 4 in the next section for details about the data). We found that between-category differences explain the vast majority of variation (more than 88%) in assortment compared to within-category differences over time. This analysis suggests that we do not have to assume that shoppers correctly anticipate changing assortments through time in order to form accurate expectations. We need only assume that shoppers know the relative assortments levels in categories that they purchase. BHT showed that the effect of price on store choice is moderated by consumers preference to purchase categories at specific stores. We incorporate this preference, which they called category-specific store loyalty, into price, feature advertising and assortment response using the hierarchical equations (2.13). β khcs = β kh + β k+7 L hcs, k = 3,4,5 (2.13) Thus, price, feature advertising and assortment response parameters are linear combinations of an intercept and category-specific store loyalty term. Category-specific store loyalty, L hcs, is defined in equation (2.14) much as store loyalty, L hs, was defined previously. L hcs = (N hcs +1/S)/(N hc +1) (2.14) where N hcs is the number of purchases that household h made at store chain s in category c during the initialization period, and N hc is the number of purchases that household h made in category c across all stores during the initialization period. Assuming that the random error term in equation (2.3) follows an extreme value distribution, the probability that household h chooses store s on visit v, Pr(y hsv =1), is specified in equation (2.15). S ( y 1) = exp( Fixed + Variable ) / exp( Fixed + Variable ) Pr hsv = hs hsv hi hiv (2.15) i= 1 A summary of predictors can be found in Table 1. <Put Table 1 about here>

17 15 Accounting for Heterogeneity We incorporate heterogeneity into the category needs and store choice components of the model by specifying random effects. Specifically, Θ h is defined as the vector of householdspecific coefficients for both the category needs and store choice equations, Θ h ={Β 0,Γ 1,, Γ Ch }. We assume Θ h to follow a multivariate normal distribution with mean Θ 0 and variance Σ. We define the category needs string for household h in equation (2.16) h h h ( I hvc ; Θ ) = ( I hvc Pr( I hvc = 1; Θ ) + ( 1 I hvc )( 1 Pr( I hvc = 1; Θ ) hc l (2.16) V h C h where V h C h is the number of categories that might needed across all of household h s V h store visits and I hvc is an indicator variable for the household s purchase of category c on visit v. We define the store choice string for household h in equation (2.17) Vh S h h ( Yhs ; Θ, I h11 LI hv ) = ( = Θ ) hc Pr y h hsv 1;, I hv1 LI hvch hs yhsv l (2.17) v= 1 s= 1 where Y hs is the vector of store choices and S is the number of store chains. Using equations (2.16) and (2.17), we write the likelihood function for all households in equation (2.18) H hs hc ( l ( Yhs; Θ, I h1,.., I hc ) l ( I hvc; Θ) ) f ( Θ; Σ) dθ h l ( I, Θ, Σ) = (2.18) h= 1 where f(θ;σ) is the distribution of the parameter vector, Θ, conditional on the covariance matrix, Σ. We assume this distribution to be multivariate normal. For both the store choice and shopping list models, the error terms are assumed to be extreme-value distributed, which results in a binary logit model for the probability Pr( ) in equation (2.16) and a multinomial logit for the probability Pr( ) in equation (2.17). Estimation details are provided in the webbased appendix.

18 16 Data Our dataset is an enhanced multi-outlet panel from Chicago covering a 104-week period between October 1995 and October This panel dataset is different from those commonly used by marketing researchers because panelists recorded all of their packaged goods purchases using in-home scanning equipment. Thus, purchase records are not limited to a small sample of grocery stores. Because purchases made at grocery and non-grocery (e.g., drug, warehouse club and mass merchandise) stores are recorded, we are able to accurately determine the timing and quantity of the last purchase in every category prior to each store visit. The category needs models are estimated using ten product categories: chocolate candy, carbonated beverages, coffee, diapers, dog food, household cleaners, laundry detergent, salty snacks, sanitary napkins, and shampoo. These ten categories offer a broad representation of high and low frequency, high and low penetration, as well as food and nonfood (including health and beauty care) categories. Together, these categories comprise roughly 10% of the average market basket. Descriptive statistics for these categories are reported in Table 2. <Put Table 2 about here> As noted previously, panelists recorded purchases at all grocery stores. We model choices at the four largest store chains which together account for 91% of store visits and 92% of spending at known grocery outlets in the market. Following BHT, we identify these retailers based on their advertised pricing strategy: EDLP1, EDLP2, HiLo1, and HiLo2. More purchases were made at HiLo (77% of trips; 76% of spending) than EDLP (14% of trips; 16% of spending) stores. Initial testing suggested that many panel households had not faithfully recorded all of their purchases. To avoid bias from underreported purchases, we limited our dataset to

19 17 households that recorded at least one grocery shopping trip in every month and spent an average of at least $20 per week in grocery stores. We included only visits with spending of at least $8; i.e., during which substantial purchases were made (as opposed to, for example, buying a pack of gum or a single-serve drink). We further required that seventy-five percent of the household s grocery purchases were made at the four largest store chains to ensure that we captured the household s preferred outlet. The resulting dataset contains 169 households (392 of the 581 available households were excluded because they might not have faithfully recorded all purchases). The first third of the panel duration (35 out of 104 weeks) was used to initialize category purchases. After the initialization period, households made an average of 66 visits to the four largest grocery store chains (std dev=39) and spent an average of $79 per trip (std dev=$31). We randomly selected 25% of these store visits for out-of-sample testing. The other 75% were used for estimation. The estimation sample contains 69 weeks of data, 11,005 store visits, and 52,489 binary category purchase observations. Binary category purchase observations were used only if a household bought that category at least five times during the two-year duration of the data and at least twice after the initialization period. Our dataset was augmented with locations of the panel households and grocery stores. These locations allowed us to compute travel distances from a shopper s home (defined as the centroid of the panelist s zip+4; actual street addresses were unavailable due to privacy concerns) to the closest store of each chain, the standard operationalization of spatial convenience. Note that travel distances are actual road distances, not Euclidean distances. <Put Table 3 about here> The market positions and strategies of the four retailers are evident from the descriptive data in Table 3. HiLo stores were visited far more frequently, with HiLo 2 visited nearly twice as often as HiLo 1 (55.1% vs. 28.2%). Together, the two EDLP retailers

20 18 accounted for fewer than 20% of store visits. This disparity is consistent with the high penetration of the two HiLo retailers, whose stores are within 1.6 (HiLo 1) and 1.2 (HiLo 2) miles of panelists homes on average. There are far fewer EDLP stores in the market as reflected in average travel distances from panelists homes of 4.9 (EDLP 1) and 5.8 (EDLP 2) miles. Across the ten categories for which we have detailed merchandise files, HiLo retailers charged higher prices on average than EDLP retailers. This is consistent with descriptive data from BHT and Bell and Lattin (1998). On the other hand, the HiLo/EDLP distinction does not explain the indexed measures of the average number of brands, SKUs/brand or sizes/brand for each category. Moreover, the ranges of these three indices of assortment reflect substantial differences among retailers. Because of our focus on assortments, we report raw category assortment numbers the number of SKUs, unique SKUs, brands, SKUs/brand, and sizes/brand scanned weekly at each retailer in Table 4. Across retailers, the largest numbers of SKUs are found in carbonated beverages and salty snacks; the smallest number in diapers. There are no consistent patterns in the number of unique SKUs, suggesting substantial variation in private label penetration across categories. The largest number of brands is offered in salty snacks, the smallest number in diapers. More SKUs/brand are offered in feminine hygiene products than in any other category; the fewest SKUs/brand are found in shampoo and household cleaners. The most sizes/brand are offered in diapers; the fewest sizes/brand are offered in the shampoo category. <Put Table 4 about Here> Results In this section, we test three alternative models to determine which fits best. We then report the parameter estimates and associated inferences for the best-fitting model. Next, we report elasticity estimates and conduct a sensitivity analysis to put our findings in context.

21 19 Model Fit Fit statistics for three different model specifications are shown in Table 5. The baseline specification (a) is BHT with the modifications described in the previous section but no assortment variables. Specification (b) is the full model detailed in the previous section. It includes assortment variables and a category-specific store loyalty parameter for assortment response. Specification (c) is a restricted version of the full model in which the categoryspecific loyalty parameter for assortment response is constrained to zero (this was suggested by an anonymous reviewer). The table includes both in and out-of-sample fit tests. In sample, we use the Consistent Akaike s Information Criterion (CAIC) and Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC) to assess the three specifications. For all three, we evaluate the full likelihood as well as the partial likelihood of store choice (i.e., conditioned on category needs). Information criteria for both full and partial likelihoods indicate that specification (c), which includes assortment variables but no category-specific store loyalty in assortment response, is preferred. Specification (c) also offers a higher store choice hit rate in sample than the other specifications do. In the holdout sample, we assess model fit by comparing log likelihoods (again both full and partial likelihoods) and store choice hit rates. Out-of-sample log likelihoods also indicate that specification (c) is preferred to both the baseline specification (a) and specification (b) with both assortment variables and category-specific store loyalty in assortment response. While specification (b) offers a higher store choice hit rate out-ofsample than specification (c), the difference is small. Consistent with these model fit test results, the remaining analyses will focus on specification (c). <Put Table 5 about here>

22 20 Parameters Parameter estimates for the store choice component of the model are shown in Table 6. Focusing first on the mean parameter estimates in the center of the table, we find that the store loyalty parameter is positive (p-value=0.000) which suggests inertial behavior in store choice. This is consistent with Rhee and Bell s (2002) finding that persistence in store choice is a strong negative predictor of future store switching. The distance parameter is negative (p-value=0.000), demonstrating shoppers disutility for travel to and from the store. <Put Table 6 about here> Recall that hierarchical equations for price and feature response (2.13) incorporate category-specific store loyalty. The intercepts of these hierarchical equations implicitly assume category-specific store loyalty to be zero. The intercept of the hierarchical equation for price response is negative but not significantly different from zero (p-value=0.167). In contrast, category-specific store loyalty has a significant negative effect on price response (pvalue=0.048). Taken together, the parameter estimates of the hierarchical equation for price response imply that, the more category purchases a household makes at a store, the more that category s prices affect the household s preference for that store. This finding is consistent with selective attention to prices and can be explained by bounded rationality arguments. Neither the intercept nor the category-specific store loyalty term in the hierarchical equation for feature response is significantly different from zero (p-value=0.792 and p- value=0.264, respectively). Thus, after controlling for price, shoppers are not significantly more likely to choose a store which advertises items in the categories they need. This finding is consistent with Bodapati and Srinivasan (2006), who determined that feature advertising is not important to most shoppers. We further investigated this result by estimating two alternative specifications: (i) one in which the binary feature advertising variable is household-specific; i.e., it reflects whether or not the household s favorite brands were

23 21 advertised, and (ii) another in which feature advertising is a predictor in the category needs equation rather than in the store choice equation (it is not clear in which equation feature advertising belongs). Both of these alternative specifications were rejected based on CAIC and BIC criteria. The assortment parameter is negative and significant (p-value=0.000), though the sign of this parameter is an artifact of how the assortment variable is constructed. The assortment variable is a positive function of the number of SKUs/brand (by construction), a positive function of the number of sizes/brand (p-value=0.007), a negative function of the number of brands offered (p-value=0.000), a negative function of the availability of the household s favorite brands (p-value=0.000), and a positive function of the proportion of unique SKUs offered (p-value=0.000). Multiplying the assortment parameter by the five measures of assortment, we find that the probability of choosing a store is positively affected by the number of brands offered and the availability of the household s favorite brands, but negatively affected by the number of SKUs/brand and sizes/brand as well as the number of unique SKUs offered. To ensure that these results are not driven by collinearity among the assortment measures, we estimated the model without EDLP 1 as a choice alternative (EDLP 1 offers substantially more brands, SKUs/brand, and sizes/brand than any other store chain). We found that, except for sizes/brand which became negative and non-significant, the signs of the assortment variable parameters did not change and the parameters remained significant when EDLP 1 was dropped from the analysis. We conclude that collinearity induced by the extensive assortments at EDLP 1 is not driving our results. Turning to the heterogeneity standard deviations in the right-most panel of Table 6, we observe that all are significant except the heterogeneity in price response. It appears that household-level differences in price response cannot be reliably estimated because they are driven by category-specific store loyalty and/or covariation with other predictors of store

24 22 choice. Interestingly, we find significant heterogeneity in feature advertising response despite a despite a non-significant parameter mean. This suggests that feature advertising can be important in the store choice decisions of some households. Note that heterogeneity standard deviations for the five measures of assortment are set to one to identify heterogeneity in assortment response. Using the heterogeneity standard deviations, we can compare the relative variability in distance and assortment response. The standardized beta for distance is -1.97/0.97=-2.03; the standardized beta for assortment 0.25/0.58= Thus, there is far more heterogeneity among households in assortment response than in distance response. Mindful of the heterogeneity in assortment response, we consider the implications of the parameter estimates for how the average shopper evaluates assortments. All else equal, the average shopper prefers stores which offer more brands, particularly his/her favorite brands. All else equal, the average shopper is not attracted to stores which offer more SKUs/brand or sizes/brand. Private labels, for which the number of unique SKUs is a proxy, also fail to attract the average shopper to the store. Thus, offering a higher proportion of national brands would seem to make a store more attractive to the average shopper. To gain insight into the tradeoffs that shoppers make when choosing a store, we now consider heterogeneity covariances between the key determinants of store choice. We compute correlations between the household-specific distance, price and assortment parameters for ease of interpretation. The only significant correlation is between distance and assortment (r=-0.43; p-value=0.000); neither of the other correlations (between price and distance and between price and assortment) has a p-value below Thus, shoppers appear willing to trade off travel distances for more attractive assortments and vice versa. The specification of category needs is not the focus of this investigation, so parameter estimates for equation (2.1) are not reported here but are available from the authors. We

25 23 note, however, that these parameter estimates support the validity of our results. Across the ten category models, all statistically significant parameter estimates have the expected sign. Further, although the none of the interaction parameters in category needs models are significant, some of the parameter heterogeneity standard deviations are significant. This implies that consumers may not consume certain categories (e.g., carbonated beverages) at constant rates. Elasticities Narrowing our focus to the key determinants of store choice, we compute market share elasticities from the parameter estimates. Table 7 reports these elasticities at three points in the parameter heterogeneity distribution: at the mean parameter estimate (in the upper panel), plus and minus one heterogeneity standard deviation (in the middle and lower panels, respectively). Representing heterogeneity in this way (as opposed to integrating over the heterogeneity distribution) shows the extent to which distance, price, and assortment response vary across households. In each case only the variable of interest is evaluated at different points in the heterogeneity distribution; others are evaluated at the mean parameter estimate. Beginning with the top panel, we find that the distance elasticities have greater magnitudes than do price and assortment elasticities for all store chains. This supports the conventional wisdom that convenience is the most important determinant of store choice. Price and assortment elasticities in the upper panel are of similar magnitudes to one another and are all below unity. The small magnitude of price elasticities is consistent with empirical evidence of inelastic category prices (Neslin and Shoemaker 1983; Bolton 1989). EDLP store shares are more sensitive than HiLo store shares to changes in all three determinants of store choice distance, price and assortment. EDLP 1 s share is most sensitive; HiLo 2 s share is least sensitive. <Put Table 7 about here>

26 24 Turning to the two lower panels in the table, we find that computing distance and price elasticities at different points in the heterogeneity distribution does not cause their signs to change lower prices and less travel are uniformly preferred. In contrast, the sign of assortment elasticities changes when the elasticities are computed at minus one heterogeneity standard deviation. Recalling that assortment is the weighted sum of five different measures, the changing sign suggests that not all customers are attracted to stores that offer more brands, more of their favorite brands, fewer SKUs/brand, fewer sizes/brand, and fewer unique (i.e., private label) SKUs. In other words, different shoppers are attracted to stores with assortments that differ in terms of these characteristics. In addition, the magnitudes of assortment elasticities computed at plus and minus one heterogeneity standard deviation are considerably larger than those computed at the mean parameter estimate. Comparing assortment and price elasticities computed at +1 and -1 heterogeneity standard deviations reveals that the magnitudes of assortment elasticities are higher in all cases. Thus, across households, changes in assortments appear to affect store choices more than the same proportional changes in prices. Sensitivity Analyses To determine the joint implications of response parameters, heterogeneity variances and covariances, we compute expected changes in market share (integrating over the entire heterogeneity distribution) if each retailer were to modify its prices or assortments. We report this sensitivity analysis in Table 8 using switching matrices that show how market shares of all store chains (presented by row) would change if a particular store chain (presented by column) increased either its (i) prices, (ii) number of brands, (iii) SKUs/brand, (iv) sizes/brand, (v) proportion of favorite brands or (vi) proportion of unique SKUs by three percent in all categories. Clearly, the predictive validity of our estimates for three-percent increases in these variables depends on the range of the data used for estimation, but the

27 25 results in Table 8 nonetheless illustrate the competitive implications. Note that this table reports integrated probabilities which may vary slightly from the point elasticities reported in Table 7 at +1, 0 and -1 heterogeneity standard deviations. <Put Table 8 about here> First, we consider a hypothetical three-percent increase in prices. If EDLP 1 or EDLP 2 were to raise its prices, it would lose 0.7% market share. The HiLo retailers would lose somewhat less market share if they were to increase prices. Note that the shares of all retailers are price inelastic, consistent with empirical studies of category prices (Neslin and Shoemaker 1983; Bolton 1989). Price changes at HiLo 2 would have the biggest impact on the shares of other retailers because of the retailer s high baseline sales. Next, we consider hypothetical increases in the five components of assortment. Note that changing one variable (SKUs/brand, for example) assumes that the other assortment variables (number of brands, for example) remain fixed; we acknowledge that this is a strong assumption. Nevertheless, we find that EDLP 1, the lowest-share retailer, is most sensitive to changes in assortment while HiLo 2, the highest-share retailer, is least sensitive. Across retailers, we find that own market shares are most affected by changing in the number of brands that retailers offer. Share gains from increasing the number of brands ranges from 0.4% for HiLo 2 to 2.4% for EDLP 1. Retailers would also benefit by offering more of shoppers favorite brands, with share gains ranging from 0.3% for HiLo 2 to 1.4% for EDLP 1. Retailers are less sensitive to increases in the number of SKUs/brand and the number of sizes/brand, both of which would result in small market share losses for the retailer. Finally, retailers shares are not at all sensitive to changes in the proportion of unique items offered. Thus, changing the proportion of private label items does not seem to affect store choice substantially. Note that cross effects are smaller than own effects (except if HiLo 2 were to change its assortments) and nearly always have the expected sign.

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain 1) Introduction Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain Big data is generally defined in terms of the volume and variety of structured and unstructured information. Whereas structured data is stored

More information

Consumer Store Choice Dynamics: An Analysis of the Competitive Market Structure for Grocery Stores

Consumer Store Choice Dynamics: An Analysis of the Competitive Market Structure for Grocery Stores Consumer Store Choice Dynamics: An Analysis of the Competitive Market Structure for Grocery Stores PETER T. L. POPKOWSKI LESZCZYC University of Alberta ASHISH SINHA University of Waikato HARRY J. P. TIMMERMANS

More information

Does Promotion Depth Affect Long-Run Demand?

Does Promotion Depth Affect Long-Run Demand? Does Promotion Depth Affect Long-Run Demand? September, 2002 Eric Anderson GSB, University of Chicago 1101 E. 58 th St., Chicago, IL 60637 eric.anderson@gsb.uchicago.edu Duncan Simester Sloan School of

More information

Chapter 3 Local Marketing in Practice

Chapter 3 Local Marketing in Practice Chapter 3 Local Marketing in Practice 3.1 Introduction In this chapter, we examine how local marketing is applied in Dutch supermarkets. We describe the research design in Section 3.1 and present the results

More information

Simultaneous or Sequential? Search Strategies in the U.S. Auto. Insurance Industry

Simultaneous or Sequential? Search Strategies in the U.S. Auto. Insurance Industry Simultaneous or Sequential? Search Strategies in the U.S. Auto Insurance Industry Elisabeth Honka 1 University of Texas at Dallas Pradeep Chintagunta 2 University of Chicago Booth School of Business September

More information

The Impact of Retail Location on Retailer Revenues: An Empirical Investigation

The Impact of Retail Location on Retailer Revenues: An Empirical Investigation The Impact of Retail Location on Retailer Revenues: An Empirical Investigation January 007 Edward J. Fox Associate Professor of Marketing, Edwin L. Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University,

More information

Multiple Linear Regression in Data Mining

Multiple Linear Regression in Data Mining Multiple Linear Regression in Data Mining Contents 2.1. A Review of Multiple Linear Regression 2.2. Illustration of the Regression Process 2.3. Subset Selection in Linear Regression 1 2 Chap. 2 Multiple

More information

This research investigates the impact of a large-scale assortment reduction on customer retention, utilizing a

This research investigates the impact of a large-scale assortment reduction on customer retention, utilizing a Vol. 24, No. 4, Fall 2005, pp. 616 622 issn 0732-2399 eissn 1526-548X 05 2404 0616 informs doi 10.1287/mksc.1050.0121 2005 INFORMS The Effect of Product Assortment Changes on Customer Retention Sharad

More information

IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 23

IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 23 IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 23 Note Before using this information and the product it supports, read the information in Notices on page 25. Product Information This edition applies to version 23, release

More information

Simultaneous or Sequential? Search Strategies in the U.S. Auto. Insurance Industry

Simultaneous or Sequential? Search Strategies in the U.S. Auto. Insurance Industry Simultaneous or Sequential? Search Strategies in the U.S. Auto Insurance Industry Elisabeth Honka 1 University of Texas at Dallas Pradeep Chintagunta 2 University of Chicago Booth School of Business October

More information

Simple Linear Regression Inference

Simple Linear Regression Inference Simple Linear Regression Inference 1 Inference requirements The Normality assumption of the stochastic term e is needed for inference even if it is not a OLS requirement. Therefore we have: Interpretation

More information

For several of the largest supermarket product categories, such as carbonated soft drinks, canned soups,

For several of the largest supermarket product categories, such as carbonated soft drinks, canned soups, Vol. 23, No. 1, Winter 2004, pp. 66 81 issn 0732-2399 eissn 1526-548X 04 2301 0066 informs doi 10.1287/mksc.1030.0041 2004 INFORMS Multiple Discreteness and Product Differentiation: Demand for Carbonated

More information

Statistics and Marketing. Peter E. Rossi and Greg M. Allenby

Statistics and Marketing. Peter E. Rossi and Greg M. Allenby Statistics and Marketing Peter E. Rossi and Greg M. Allenby Statistical research in marketing is heavily influenced by the availability of different types of data. The last ten years have seen an explosion

More information

IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 22

IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 22 IBM SPSS Direct Marketing 22 Note Before using this information and the product it supports, read the information in Notices on page 25. Product Information This edition applies to version 22, release

More information

SPSS TRAINING SESSION 3 ADVANCED TOPICS (PASW STATISTICS 17.0) Sun Li Centre for Academic Computing lsun@smu.edu.sg

SPSS TRAINING SESSION 3 ADVANCED TOPICS (PASW STATISTICS 17.0) Sun Li Centre for Academic Computing lsun@smu.edu.sg SPSS TRAINING SESSION 3 ADVANCED TOPICS (PASW STATISTICS 17.0) Sun Li Centre for Academic Computing lsun@smu.edu.sg IN SPSS SESSION 2, WE HAVE LEARNT: Elementary Data Analysis Group Comparison & One-way

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

STATISTICA Formula Guide: Logistic Regression. Table of Contents

STATISTICA Formula Guide: Logistic Regression. Table of Contents : Table of Contents... 1 Overview of Model... 1 Dispersion... 2 Parameterization... 3 Sigma-Restricted Model... 3 Overparameterized Model... 4 Reference Coding... 4 Model Summary (Summary Tab)... 5 Summary

More information

The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice

The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice Gautam Gowrisankaran Claudio Lucarelli Philipp Schmidt-Dengler Robert Town January 24, 2011 Abstract This paper seeks to

More information

The Proportional Odds Model for Assessing Rater Agreement with Multiple Modalities

The Proportional Odds Model for Assessing Rater Agreement with Multiple Modalities The Proportional Odds Model for Assessing Rater Agreement with Multiple Modalities Elizabeth Garrett-Mayer, PhD Assistant Professor Sidney Kimmel Comprehensive Cancer Center Johns Hopkins University 1

More information

Statistics in Retail Finance. Chapter 6: Behavioural models

Statistics in Retail Finance. Chapter 6: Behavioural models Statistics in Retail Finance 1 Overview > So far we have focussed mainly on application scorecards. In this chapter we shall look at behavioural models. We shall cover the following topics:- Behavioural

More information

Competition-Based Dynamic Pricing in Online Retailing

Competition-Based Dynamic Pricing in Online Retailing Competition-Based Dynamic Pricing in Online Retailing Marshall Fisher The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, fisher@wharton.upenn.edu Santiago Gallino Tuck School of Business, Dartmouth College,

More information

Explaining Retail Brand Performance An Application Of Prior Knowledge

Explaining Retail Brand Performance An Application Of Prior Knowledge Explaining Retail Brand Performance An Application Of Prior Knowledge Byron Sharp (Director), Erica Riebe (Senior Research Associate) and Monica Tolo (Research Associate) Marketing Science Centre University

More information

Penalized regression: Introduction

Penalized regression: Introduction Penalized regression: Introduction Patrick Breheny August 30 Patrick Breheny BST 764: Applied Statistical Modeling 1/19 Maximum likelihood Much of 20th-century statistics dealt with maximum likelihood

More information

INDIRECT INFERENCE (prepared for: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition)

INDIRECT INFERENCE (prepared for: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition) INDIRECT INFERENCE (prepared for: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition) Abstract Indirect inference is a simulation-based method for estimating the parameters of economic models. Its

More information

Example: Credit card default, we may be more interested in predicting the probabilty of a default than classifying individuals as default or not.

Example: Credit card default, we may be more interested in predicting the probabilty of a default than classifying individuals as default or not. Statistical Learning: Chapter 4 Classification 4.1 Introduction Supervised learning with a categorical (Qualitative) response Notation: - Feature vector X, - qualitative response Y, taking values in C

More information

Credit Card Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 Switching Analysis

Credit Card Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 Switching Analysis MS14/6.2: Annex 4 Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 November 2015 This annex describes data analysis we carried out to improve our understanding of switching and shopping around behaviour in the UK

More information

An Overview of Research on Potential Uses of Scanner Data in the U.S. CPI

An Overview of Research on Potential Uses of Scanner Data in the U.S. CPI An Overview of Research on Potential Uses of Scanner Data in the U.S. CPI Ralph Bradley, Bill Cook, Sylvia G. Leaver and Brent R. Moulton 1 Abstract: The staff of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics has

More information

Households incur transaction costs when choosing among off-line stores for grocery purchases. They may

Households incur transaction costs when choosing among off-line stores for grocery purchases. They may Vol. 31, No. 1, January February 2012, pp. 96 114 ISSN 0732-2399 (print) ISSN 1526-548X (online) http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1110.0678 2012 INFORMS Quantifying Transaction Costs in Online/Off-line Grocery

More information

How To Find Out What Search Strategy Is Used In The U.S. Auto Insurance Industry

How To Find Out What Search Strategy Is Used In The U.S. Auto Insurance Industry Simultaneous or Sequential? Search Strategies in the U.S. Auto Insurance Industry Current version: April 2014 Elisabeth Honka Pradeep Chintagunta Abstract We show that the search method consumers use when

More information

Uncovering Consumer Decision Rules under Complex Dynamic Environments: The Case of Coalition Loyalty Programs

Uncovering Consumer Decision Rules under Complex Dynamic Environments: The Case of Coalition Loyalty Programs Uncovering Consumer Decision Rules under Complex Dynamic Environments: The Case of Coalition Loyalty Programs Andrew Ching Masakazu Ishihara Very Preliminary and Incomplete April 18, 2014 Abstract We propose

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Probabilistic versus random-utility models of state dependence: an empirical comparison

Probabilistic versus random-utility models of state dependence: an empirical comparison Intern. J. of Research in Marketing 20 (2003) 87 96 www.elsevier.com/locate/ijresmar Probabilistic versus random-utility models of state dependence: an empirical comparison P.B. Seetharaman* John M. Olin

More information

Understanding Retail Assortments In Competitive Markets 1

Understanding Retail Assortments In Competitive Markets 1 Understanding Retail Assortments In Competitive Markets 1 Kanishka Misra 2 Kellogg School of Management June 26, 2008 1 I wish to thank my advisors Eric Anderson, Karsten Hansen, Igal Handel Aviv Nevo,

More information

Auxiliary Variables in Mixture Modeling: 3-Step Approaches Using Mplus

Auxiliary Variables in Mixture Modeling: 3-Step Approaches Using Mplus Auxiliary Variables in Mixture Modeling: 3-Step Approaches Using Mplus Tihomir Asparouhov and Bengt Muthén Mplus Web Notes: No. 15 Version 8, August 5, 2014 1 Abstract This paper discusses alternatives

More information

Grocery Store Buying Behavior - Evidence From Loyalty Program Data

Grocery Store Buying Behavior - Evidence From Loyalty Program Data Grocery Store Buying Behavior: Evidence From Loyalty Program Data Sara M. Ashman Card-based customer loyalty programs are designed to track individual- and/or household-level shopping behavior at the point

More information

EDLP, Hi-Lo, and Margin Arithmetic

EDLP, Hi-Lo, and Margin Arithmetic EDLP, Hi-Lo, and Margin Arithmetic Stephen J. Hoch, Xavier Dreze, Mary E. Purk Graduate School of Business University of Chicago October 1993 Revised April 1994 In Press, Journal of Marketing Stephen J.

More information

White paper. Gerhard Hausruckinger. Approaches to measuring on-shelf availability at the point of sale

White paper. Gerhard Hausruckinger. Approaches to measuring on-shelf availability at the point of sale White paper Gerhard Hausruckinger Approaches to measuring on-shelf availability at the point of sale Contents The goal: to raise productivity The precondition: using the OOS index to record out-of-stock

More information

Analysis of Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models

Analysis of Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models Analysis of Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models Emily M. Casleton December 17, 2010 1 Introduction The main purpose of this project is to explore the Bayesian analysis of Dynamic Linear Models (DLMs). The main

More information

SUMAN DUVVURU STAT 567 PROJECT REPORT

SUMAN DUVVURU STAT 567 PROJECT REPORT SUMAN DUVVURU STAT 567 PROJECT REPORT SURVIVAL ANALYSIS OF HEROIN ADDICTS Background and introduction: Current illicit drug use among teens is continuing to increase in many countries around the world.

More information

SUPPLEMENT TO USAGE-BASED PRICING AND DEMAND FOR RESIDENTIAL BROADBAND : APPENDIX (Econometrica, Vol. 84, No. 2, March 2016, 411 443)

SUPPLEMENT TO USAGE-BASED PRICING AND DEMAND FOR RESIDENTIAL BROADBAND : APPENDIX (Econometrica, Vol. 84, No. 2, March 2016, 411 443) Econometrica Supplementary Material SUPPLEMENT TO USAGE-BASED PRICING AND DEMAND FOR RESIDENTIAL BROADBAND : APPENDIX (Econometrica, Vol. 84, No. 2, March 2016, 411 443) BY AVIV NEVO, JOHN L. TURNER, AND

More information

The primary goal of this thesis was to understand how the spatial dependence of

The primary goal of this thesis was to understand how the spatial dependence of 5 General discussion 5.1 Introduction The primary goal of this thesis was to understand how the spatial dependence of consumer attitudes can be modeled, what additional benefits the recovering of spatial

More information

We use the results of three large-scale field experiments to investigate how the depth of a current price

We use the results of three large-scale field experiments to investigate how the depth of a current price Vol. 23, No. 1, Winter 2004, pp. 4 20 issn 0732-2399 eissn 1526-548X 04 2301 0004 informs doi 10.1287/mksc.1030.0040 2004 INFORMS Long-Run Effects of Promotion Depth on New Versus Established Customers:

More information

ANNUITY LAPSE RATE MODELING: TOBIT OR NOT TOBIT? 1. INTRODUCTION

ANNUITY LAPSE RATE MODELING: TOBIT OR NOT TOBIT? 1. INTRODUCTION ANNUITY LAPSE RATE MODELING: TOBIT OR NOT TOBIT? SAMUEL H. COX AND YIJIA LIN ABSTRACT. We devise an approach, using tobit models for modeling annuity lapse rates. The approach is based on data provided

More information

Keep It Simple: Easy Ways To Estimate Choice Models For Single Consumers

Keep It Simple: Easy Ways To Estimate Choice Models For Single Consumers Keep It Simple: Easy Ways To Estimate Choice Models For Single Consumers Christine Ebling, University of Technology Sydney, christine.ebling@uts.edu.au Bart Frischknecht, University of Technology Sydney,

More information

Pointofview. The Modern Day Food Gatherer. Colin Ho and Junmeng Chen

Pointofview. The Modern Day Food Gatherer. Colin Ho and Junmeng Chen Pointofview The Modern Day Food Gatherer Colin Ho and Junmeng Chen Connecting What s Now to What s Next While we generally gravitate towards what is simple and efficient, there is mounting evidence that

More information

How To Understand And Understand Social Intercorrelations In A Market

How To Understand And Understand Social Intercorrelations In A Market 1 Conditional projection [Texto impreso] : how own evaluations influence beliefs about others whose choices are known / A. Yeçim Orhun and Oleg Urminsky References: p. 123-124 : 37 refs. Abstract: The

More information

Information Security and Risk Management

Information Security and Risk Management Information Security and Risk Management by Lawrence D. Bodin Professor Emeritus of Decision and Information Technology Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland College Park, MD 20742

More information

We propose a structural model to study the effect of online product reviews on consumer purchases of

We propose a structural model to study the effect of online product reviews on consumer purchases of Vol. 32, No., January February 203, pp. 53 69 ISSN 0732-2399 (print) ISSN 526-548X (online) http://dx.doi.org/0.287/mksc.20.0755 203 INFORMS Modeling Consumer Learning from Online Product Reviews Yi Zhao

More information

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

VI. Real Business Cycles Models VI. Real Business Cycles Models Introduction Business cycle research studies the causes and consequences of the recurrent expansions and contractions in aggregate economic activity that occur in most industrialized

More information

Store Brands and Category Management

Store Brands and Category Management Store Brands and Category Management Stephen J. Hoch and Leonard M. Lodish Wharton School University of Pennsylvania March 1998 Store Brands and Category Management A key benefit to the adoption of any

More information

Gender Effects in the Alaska Juvenile Justice System

Gender Effects in the Alaska Juvenile Justice System Gender Effects in the Alaska Juvenile Justice System Report to the Justice and Statistics Research Association by André Rosay Justice Center University of Alaska Anchorage JC 0306.05 October 2003 Gender

More information

Promotional Forecasting Based on Promotional Indexes in Yoghurt Production

Promotional Forecasting Based on Promotional Indexes in Yoghurt Production Promotional Forecasting Based on Promotional Indexes in Yoghurt Production MICHAL PATAK, VLADIMIRA VLCKOVA Faculty of Chemical Technology, Department of Economy and Man. of Chemical and Food Industry University

More information

How To Check For Differences In The One Way Anova

How To Check For Differences In The One Way Anova MINITAB ASSISTANT WHITE PAPER This paper explains the research conducted by Minitab statisticians to develop the methods and data checks used in the Assistant in Minitab 17 Statistical Software. One-Way

More information

An Analysis of Price Determination and Markups in the Air-Conditioning and Heating Equipment Industry

An Analysis of Price Determination and Markups in the Air-Conditioning and Heating Equipment Industry LBNL-52791 An Analysis of Price Determination and Markups in the Air-Conditioning and Heating Equipment Industry Larry Dale, Dev Millstein, Katie Coughlin, Robert Van Buskirk, Gregory Rosenquist, Alex

More information

Applied Statistics. J. Blanchet and J. Wadsworth. Institute of Mathematics, Analysis, and Applications EPF Lausanne

Applied Statistics. J. Blanchet and J. Wadsworth. Institute of Mathematics, Analysis, and Applications EPF Lausanne Applied Statistics J. Blanchet and J. Wadsworth Institute of Mathematics, Analysis, and Applications EPF Lausanne An MSc Course for Applied Mathematicians, Fall 2012 Outline 1 Model Comparison 2 Model

More information

Statistical Innovations Online course: Latent Class Discrete Choice Modeling with Scale Factors

Statistical Innovations Online course: Latent Class Discrete Choice Modeling with Scale Factors Statistical Innovations Online course: Latent Class Discrete Choice Modeling with Scale Factors Session 3: Advanced SALC Topics Outline: A. Advanced Models for MaxDiff Data B. Modeling the Dual Response

More information

How To Model The Fate Of An Animal

How To Model The Fate Of An Animal Models Where the Fate of Every Individual is Known This class of models is important because they provide a theory for estimation of survival probability and other parameters from radio-tagged animals.

More information

Business Process Services. White Paper. Price Elasticity using Distributed Computing for Big Data

Business Process Services. White Paper. Price Elasticity using Distributed Computing for Big Data Business Process Services White Paper Price Elasticity using Distributed Computing for Big Data About the Authors Rajesh Kavadiki Rajesh is part of the Analytics and Insights team at Tata Consultancy Services

More information

Poisson Models for Count Data

Poisson Models for Count Data Chapter 4 Poisson Models for Count Data In this chapter we study log-linear models for count data under the assumption of a Poisson error structure. These models have many applications, not only to the

More information

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 422 March 2009 Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Monika Piazzesi Stanford University and National

More information

38 Int. J. Internet Marketing and Advertising, Vol. 1, No. 1, 2004

38 Int. J. Internet Marketing and Advertising, Vol. 1, No. 1, 2004 38 Int. J. Internet Marketing and Advertising, Vol. 1, No. 1, 2004 Behavioural differences between consumers attracted to shopping online versus traditional supermarkets: implications for enterprise design

More information

The Importance of Brand Name and Quality in the Retail Food Industry

The Importance of Brand Name and Quality in the Retail Food Industry The Importance of Brand ame and Quality in the Retail Food Industry Contact Information Eidan Apelbaum Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics 16 Soc Sci & Humanities Bldg University of California,

More information

CHOICES The magazine of food, farm, and resource issues

CHOICES The magazine of food, farm, and resource issues CHOICES The magazine of food, farm, and resource issues 4th Quarter 2005 20(4) A publication of the American Agricultural Economics Association Logistics, Inventory Control, and Supply Chain Management

More information

More details on the inputs, functionality, and output can be found below.

More details on the inputs, functionality, and output can be found below. Overview: The SMEEACT (Software for More Efficient, Ethical, and Affordable Clinical Trials) web interface (http://research.mdacc.tmc.edu/smeeactweb) implements a single analysis of a two-armed trial comparing

More information

Accurately and Efficiently Measuring Individual Account Credit Risk On Existing Portfolios

Accurately and Efficiently Measuring Individual Account Credit Risk On Existing Portfolios Accurately and Efficiently Measuring Individual Account Credit Risk On Existing Portfolios By: Michael Banasiak & By: Daniel Tantum, Ph.D. What Are Statistical Based Behavior Scoring Models And How Are

More information

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource Daniel McFadden Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley April 8, 2002 I. This note is concerned with the economics of

More information

A credibility method for profitable cross-selling of insurance products

A credibility method for profitable cross-selling of insurance products Submitted to Annals of Actuarial Science manuscript 2 A credibility method for profitable cross-selling of insurance products Fredrik Thuring Faculty of Actuarial Science and Insurance, Cass Business School,

More information

Impact of Wal-Mart Supercenter on a Traditional Supermarket: An Empirical Investigation

Impact of Wal-Mart Supercenter on a Traditional Supermarket: An Empirical Investigation Impact of Wal-Mart Supercenter on a Traditional Supermarket: An Empirical Investigation Vishal P. Singh 1, Karsten T. Hansen 2, Robert C. Blattberg 3 February 11, 2004 1 vsingh@andrew.cmu.edu, GSIA, Carnegie

More information

Response. A Cluster Analytic Approach to Market. Functions I I I I I DONALD E. SEXTON, JR.*

Response. A Cluster Analytic Approach to Market. Functions I I I I I DONALD E. SEXTON, JR.* I I A Cluster Analytic Approach to Market Response DONALD E. SEXTON, JR.* Functions I I I I I _ I INTRODUCTION The estimation marketing policy effects with time series data is a fairly well-mined area

More information

Confectionery Online. What You ll Gain from this Report ONLINE SHOPPER INTELLIGENCE - UK

Confectionery Online. What You ll Gain from this Report ONLINE SHOPPER INTELLIGENCE - UK ONLINE SHOPPER INTELLIGENCE - UK Confectionery Online What You ll Gain from this Report This report focuses on the online confectionery shopping market in the UK, looking at data from February to July

More information

BayesX - Software for Bayesian Inference in Structured Additive Regression

BayesX - Software for Bayesian Inference in Structured Additive Regression BayesX - Software for Bayesian Inference in Structured Additive Regression Thomas Kneib Faculty of Mathematics and Economics, University of Ulm Department of Statistics, Ludwig-Maximilians-University Munich

More information

11. Analysis of Case-control Studies Logistic Regression

11. Analysis of Case-control Studies Logistic Regression Research methods II 113 11. Analysis of Case-control Studies Logistic Regression This chapter builds upon and further develops the concepts and strategies described in Ch.6 of Mother and Child Health:

More information

Spatial Statistics Chapter 3 Basics of areal data and areal data modeling

Spatial Statistics Chapter 3 Basics of areal data and areal data modeling Spatial Statistics Chapter 3 Basics of areal data and areal data modeling Recall areal data also known as lattice data are data Y (s), s D where D is a discrete index set. This usually corresponds to data

More information

Online Appendix to Are Risk Preferences Stable Across Contexts? Evidence from Insurance Data

Online Appendix to Are Risk Preferences Stable Across Contexts? Evidence from Insurance Data Online Appendix to Are Risk Preferences Stable Across Contexts? Evidence from Insurance Data By LEVON BARSEGHYAN, JEFFREY PRINCE, AND JOSHUA C. TEITELBAUM I. Empty Test Intervals Here we discuss the conditions

More information

Four Steps to Optimizing Trade Promotion Effectiveness. Figure 1. L.E.K. s Four-Step Framework for Improving Trade Promotion Programs STEP 3

Four Steps to Optimizing Trade Promotion Effectiveness. Figure 1. L.E.K. s Four-Step Framework for Improving Trade Promotion Programs STEP 3 Volume XIII, Issue 5 Four Steps to Optimizing Trade Promotion Effectiveness Trade promotion programs are pivotal to driving sales, building brand equity with consumers and strengthening channel partnerships.

More information

"SEO vs. PPC The Final Round"

SEO vs. PPC The Final Round "SEO vs. PPC The Final Round" A Research Study by Engine Ready, Inc. Examining The Role Traffic Source Plays in Visitor Purchase Behavior January 2008 Table of Contents Introduction 3 Definitions 4 Methodology

More information

Cross-Selling the Right Product to the Right Customer at the Right Time

Cross-Selling the Right Product to the Right Customer at the Right Time Cross-Selling the Right Product to the Right Customer at the Right Time Shibo Li 1 Kelley School of Business Indiana University 139 E. 1th Street Bloomington, IN 4745 Phone: 812-855-915 Fax: 812-855-644

More information

A Mathematical Study of Purchasing Airline Tickets

A Mathematical Study of Purchasing Airline Tickets A Mathematical Study of Purchasing Airline Tickets THESIS Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Mathematical Science in the Graduate School of The Ohio State University

More information

Crowdfunding the next hit: Microfunding online experience goods

Crowdfunding the next hit: Microfunding online experience goods Crowdfunding the next hit: Microfunding online experience goods Chris Ward Department of Operations and Information Systems University of Utah Salt Lake City, UT 84112 chris.ward@business.utah.edu Vandana

More information

Machine Learning Methods for Demand Estimation

Machine Learning Methods for Demand Estimation Machine Learning Methods for Demand Estimation By Patrick Bajari, Denis Nekipelov, Stephen P. Ryan, and Miaoyu Yang Over the past decade, there has been a high level of interest in modeling consumer behavior

More information

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications Conclusion and Implication V{tÑàxÜ CONCLUSION AND IMPLICATION 8 Contents 8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications Having done the selection of macroeconomic variables, forecasting the series and construction

More information

Errata and updates for ASM Exam C/Exam 4 Manual (Sixteenth Edition) sorted by page

Errata and updates for ASM Exam C/Exam 4 Manual (Sixteenth Edition) sorted by page Errata for ASM Exam C/4 Study Manual (Sixteenth Edition) Sorted by Page 1 Errata and updates for ASM Exam C/Exam 4 Manual (Sixteenth Edition) sorted by page Practice exam 1:9, 1:22, 1:29, 9:5, and 10:8

More information

Payment card rewards programs and consumer payment choice. This version: March 24, 2010

Payment card rewards programs and consumer payment choice. This version: March 24, 2010 Payment card rewards programs and consumer payment choice Andrew T. Ching a, Fumiko Hayashi b,* a Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto, Toronto, Ontario, Canada M5S 3E6 b Federal Reserve

More information

Sharing Online Advertising Revenue with Consumers

Sharing Online Advertising Revenue with Consumers Sharing Online Advertising Revenue with Consumers Yiling Chen 2,, Arpita Ghosh 1, Preston McAfee 1, and David Pennock 1 1 Yahoo! Research. Email: arpita, mcafee, pennockd@yahoo-inc.com 2 Harvard University.

More information

TIBCO Industry Analytics: Consumer Packaged Goods and Retail Solutions

TIBCO Industry Analytics: Consumer Packaged Goods and Retail Solutions TIBCO Industry Analytics: Consumer Packaged Goods and Retail Solutions TIBCO s robust, standardsbased infrastructure technologies are used by successful retailers around the world, including five of the

More information

Changing Distributions: How Online College Classes Alter Student and Professor Performance

Changing Distributions: How Online College Classes Alter Student and Professor Performance Changing Distributions: How Online College Classes Alter Student and Professor Performance Eric Bettinger, Lindsay Fox, Susanna Loeb and Eric Taylor Changing Distributions: How online college classes alter

More information

CHAPTER 5: CONSUMERS ATTITUDE TOWARDS ONLINE MARKETING OF INDIAN RAILWAYS

CHAPTER 5: CONSUMERS ATTITUDE TOWARDS ONLINE MARKETING OF INDIAN RAILWAYS CHAPTER 5: CONSUMERS ATTITUDE TOWARDS ONLINE MARKETING OF INDIAN RAILWAYS 5.1 Introduction This chapter presents the findings of research objectives dealing, with consumers attitude towards online marketing

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Final Exam Review MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) A researcher for an airline interviews all of the passengers on five randomly

More information

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix De Loecker Jan - Warzynski Frederic Princeton University, NBER and CEPR - Aarhus School of Business Forthcoming American Economic Review Abstract This is

More information

Efficient Retail Pricing in Electricity and Natural Gas Markets

Efficient Retail Pricing in Electricity and Natural Gas Markets Efficient Retail Pricing in Electricity and Natural Gas Markets Steven L. Puller Department of Economics Texas A&M University and NBER Jeremy West Department of Economics Texas A&M University January 2013

More information

Semiparametric Multinomial Logit Models for the Analysis of Brand Choice Behaviour

Semiparametric Multinomial Logit Models for the Analysis of Brand Choice Behaviour Semiparametric Multinomial Logit Models for the Analysis of Brand Choice Behaviour Thomas Kneib Department of Statistics Ludwig-Maximilians-University Munich joint work with Bernhard Baumgartner & Winfried

More information

Outline. Topic 4 - Analysis of Variance Approach to Regression. Partitioning Sums of Squares. Total Sum of Squares. Partitioning sums of squares

Outline. Topic 4 - Analysis of Variance Approach to Regression. Partitioning Sums of Squares. Total Sum of Squares. Partitioning sums of squares Topic 4 - Analysis of Variance Approach to Regression Outline Partitioning sums of squares Degrees of freedom Expected mean squares General linear test - Fall 2013 R 2 and the coefficient of correlation

More information

STATISTICS AND DATA ANALYSIS IN GEOLOGY, 3rd ed. Clarificationof zonationprocedure described onpp. 238-239

STATISTICS AND DATA ANALYSIS IN GEOLOGY, 3rd ed. Clarificationof zonationprocedure described onpp. 238-239 STATISTICS AND DATA ANALYSIS IN GEOLOGY, 3rd ed. by John C. Davis Clarificationof zonationprocedure described onpp. 38-39 Because the notation used in this section (Eqs. 4.8 through 4.84) is inconsistent

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Paper Selection by Digital Printers

An Empirical Analysis of Paper Selection by Digital Printers An Empirical Analysis of Paper Selection by Digital Printers A Thesis Presented to The Academic Faculty By Benjamin Philipp Jonen In Partial Fulfillment Of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Science

More information

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression Econometrics Simple Linear Regression Burcu Eke UC3M Linear equations with one variable Recall what a linear equation is: y = b 0 + b 1 x is a linear equation with one variable, or equivalently, a straight

More information

UNDERSTANDING TRUE LOYALTY

UNDERSTANDING TRUE LOYALTY WHITE PAPER UNDERSTANDING TRUE LOYALTY Gaining Insight into Customer Loyalty Based on Whole-Wallet Spend Understanding True Loyalty Loyal customers are disproportionately important to any business, and

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending Lamont Black* Indiana University Federal Reserve Board of Governors November 2006 ABSTRACT: This paper analyzes empirically the

More information

THE INFLUENCE OF MARKETING INTELLIGENCE ON PERFORMANCES OF ROMANIAN RETAILERS. Adrian MICU 1 Angela-Eliza MICU 2 Nicoleta CRISTACHE 3 Edit LUKACS 4

THE INFLUENCE OF MARKETING INTELLIGENCE ON PERFORMANCES OF ROMANIAN RETAILERS. Adrian MICU 1 Angela-Eliza MICU 2 Nicoleta CRISTACHE 3 Edit LUKACS 4 THE INFLUENCE OF MARKETING INTELLIGENCE ON PERFORMANCES OF ROMANIAN RETAILERS Adrian MICU 1 Angela-Eliza MICU 2 Nicoleta CRISTACHE 3 Edit LUKACS 4 ABSTRACT The paper was dedicated to the assessment of

More information

Industry Environment and Concepts for Forecasting 1

Industry Environment and Concepts for Forecasting 1 Table of Contents Industry Environment and Concepts for Forecasting 1 Forecasting Methods Overview...2 Multilevel Forecasting...3 Demand Forecasting...4 Integrating Information...5 Simplifying the Forecast...6

More information

Example G Cost of construction of nuclear power plants

Example G Cost of construction of nuclear power plants 1 Example G Cost of construction of nuclear power plants Description of data Table G.1 gives data, reproduced by permission of the Rand Corporation, from a report (Mooz, 1978) on 32 light water reactor

More information