Market Design: A Selective Review

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Market Design: A Selective Review"

Transcription

1 Market Design: A Selective Review Thomas Kittsteiner Axel Ockenfels Abstract We argue that the design of market and negotiation rules significantly affects outcomes, and that small design changes can have substantial consequences. We focus on three particular environments online markets, electricity markets and partnership dissolution mechanisms and show how a combined theoretical and empirical approach to market design research may help to improve the governance of markets and negotiations. Dr. Thomas Kittsteiner: London School of Economics, Department of Management, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, t.m.kittsteiner@lse.ac.uk. Prof. Dr. Axel Ockenfels: University of Cologne, Department of Economics, Albertus Magnus Platz, D Cologne, Germany, ockenfels@uni-koeln.de (

2 A. Introduction The design of market rules that govern the interaction of traders and other market participants dates back to the ancient world. Auction markets were common in ancient Rome and even the Roman empire was once sold in an auction. 1 Goethe designed new market rules when he sold one of his manuscripts to his publisher Vieweg. Around 200 years later it turned out that Goethe's rules are a special case of Vickrey's famous auction design, and that Goethe was probably aware of the economic advantages of his design (Moldovanu and Tietzel (1998), and Vickrey (1961)). Despite the long history of auctions and other exchanges, market design has not gained momentum as a scientific discipline until recently, when the theoretical and empirical market design literature started to grow rapidly and at accelerating rates. This development has many explanations, including a surge in privatization activities, availability of reliable and fast computer technologies, and progress in game theory and experimental economics. These developments made it possible, for instance, to design smart auction markets that can deal with various complexities, such as complementarities among objects (e.g., in spectrum licenses 2 ), or to design various stable matching markets that suffered from congestion, unravelling and incentive problems. 3 Moreover, e-commerce and online trading pose new design challenges, partly because trade is among anonymous, geographically dispersed traders in C2C markets, and products are complex and multi-dimensional in most B2B markets. In general a market-designer's task is to find market rules that eventually will lead to a desired market outcome. 4 A market outcome is given by a (final) allocation of traded objects and by monetary payments between market participants. The task of the market-designer is often complicated by allocational complexities and asymmetric information (about preferences). To illustrate the first point, consider a local government who wants to privatize a bus network by selling the individual routes separately. Due to complementarities, a buyer's preference over bus-routes specifies his willingness to pay for any possible package of routes. Even if the seller is completely informed about the (potential) buyers' preferences, it is still a non-trivial task to split up and allocate the network in the profit-maximising way. 5 In fact, a considerable literature in Operations Research is concerned with allocational complexities in auctions and markets (for a recent survey see Anandalingam et al. (2005) and de Vries and Vohra (2003). Another difficult, but less understood class of allocational complexities arises 1

3 in the presence of allocative externalities; e.g., the value of a spectrum license may depend on the entire allocation of licenses to (possibly different) bidders (see Jehiel and Moldovanu (2001, forthcoming)). In this article, however, we will mainly focus on the second issue: governance structures in case of asymmetric information. From the economist's perspective, a market where participants are ignorant about each others preferences is a game with incomplete information. The literature in mechanism- and auction design, a sub-discipline of game theory, analyses how equilibrium behaviour in these market games depends on their rules, and, by the same token, how rules that implement desired market outcomes look like. That is, mechanism design and auction theory examine market incentives, reveal market failures, and thus provide useful guidance in market design. 6 However, although important, theoretical considerations alone typically do not guarantee a sensible market design. This is true in particular in those cases, in which reality is too complex to be solved analytically. Here, the role of theory is in developing intuition and identifying trade-offs in design choices by isolating a particular effect rather than capturing as much reality as possible. But typically, theory needs to be complemented with other tools such as computational, empirical and experimental methods (see Roth (2002), Ariely et al. (2005)). In particular, laboratory experiments can be used to test the validity of various economic theories, to test hypotheses that cannot be investigated with the help of field data, and to test new market mechanisms that do not yet exist. In section B.I.3., we will demonstrate how a mixture of theoretical, empirical and experimental research can help to investigate the issues involved in designing online-auctions. One of the important lessons that can be learned from theoretical and empirical research is that there is generally no one-fits-it-all design. Every market environment is different and has its own particularities. Indeed, one aim of this article is to demonstrate that details can be very important; that is, even small design flaws can have a substantial impact on traders' behaviour and the performance of the market. For this purpose, we chose three examples from very different kinds of markets: 7 online auctions, electricity markets and partnership dissolution. B. The design of online auctions EBay is an attractive area to study market design. Part of the reason is ebay's enormous success. In 2005, more than 180 million users were registered on ebay (of which 72 million are 2

4 actively bidding), who offered about 1.9 billion items, leading to consolidated net revenues of $4.6 billion. Furthermore, online auctions (as those conducted by ebay) have precise and simple rules. This greatly facilitates the empirical and theoretical analysis as the complexity of strategic decisions of market participants is limited, and ambiguity with respect to implicit rules is eliminated or at least low. The huge amount of transactions and the huge amount of data readily available in electronic form further facilitates the empirical analysis. As a result, the literature on online auctions (unlike the literature in many other areas of empirical Industrial Organization) has quickly led to robust insights based on a mixture of empirical, experimental and theoretical research, and (single-unit) online auctions have become one of the best understood subjects in market design research. B.I. Controlling the pace of electronic auctions 8 B.I.1. Basic issues Unlike offline auctions, which typically last only a few minutes, Internet auctions such as those on ebay, Yahoo and Amazon run many days. This reflects that the Internet allows bidders to bid from basically everywhere at any time, and that a short auction would give less bidders a chance to spot the object and to enter the auction. Lucking-Reiley et al. (1999) and Hasker et al. (2004) observed that longer auction durations on ebay tend to attract more bidders and lead to higher prices. E.g., Lucking-Reiley et al. reported that prices in 7-day auctions are approximately 24 percent higher than in shorter auctions, and in 10-day auctions they are 42 percent higher, on average. However, long durations also create challenges because bidders cannot be expected to always keep an eye on the auctions as they unfold. Many auction houses including ebay respond to this by providing bidders with artificial proxy agents. These agents bid on the bidders' behalf, automatically responding as other bids come in, and thus free bidders from the necessity to follow the auctions and the price discovery process themselves. A related design question is whether the auction should be conducted sealed-bid. That is, bidders may submit their (proxy) bids over an extended period of time - but without the opportunity to react to the bidding activity of other human or proxy bidders. Or should bidding be open, so that bidders can see how others' bidding activities evolve during the course of auction? This way, bidders would retain the right to change (proxy) bids in response to the bid 3

5 history. Many (but not all) online auction houses, such as ebay, chose an open format. From a theoretical point of view, open ascending-price auctions tend to generate more revenue for the seller. Milgrom and Weber (1981) show that competitors' bidding activities may convey relevant information that the bidders can then use in revising their estimates of value. This translates into more aggressive bidding behaviour and higher prices. 9 Another argument for open auction formats comes from behavioral economics. It has been shown in laboratory experiments that the observability of bidding activity in open secondprice auctions substantially accelerates the speed of learning the optimal bidding strategy compared to second-price sealed-bid auctions (Ariely et al. (2005)). This improves the price discovery process and increases competition among bidders so that efficiency and revenue can be enhanced, even in purely private-value environments. In line with this finding, Ivanova-Stenzel and Salmon (2004) reported that, when having the choice between sealed-bid and open, ascending-bid auctions, laboratory subjects in a private-value environment have a strong preference for the open format. However, there are also disadvantages from open bidding: open auctions can lead to lower revenues when bidders are risk-averse, and when ex ante asymmetries among bidders are strong or competition is weak (e.g., Cramton (1998)). Furthermore, open auctions facilitate collusion among bidders which can result in lower revenue (see Klemperer (2004)). This might be part of the reason why ebay in the U.S. recently introduced a sealed-bid format as an option for sellers; in the best offer format, bidders can make sealed-bids, and sellers can accept any bid at any time they wish. B.I.2. The timing of bids Open auctions raise the question of the optimal timing of the bid. Many researchers found that bids on ebay, where auctions run typically for a week, often arrive very near to the closing time -- a practice called sniping. For instance, in the sample of computer and antiques auctions with at least two bidders, Roth and Ockenfels (2002) found that about 50 percent of all auctions still have bids in the last five minutes, 37 percent in the last one minute, and still 12 percent in the last 10 seconds. 10 At first glance, last-minute bidding of this sort cannot easily be reconciled with economic theory, because, as explained, ebay makes available a software bidding agent, called proxy bidding, to make bidding simple for bidders without having to 4

6 be constantly vigilant or to be online at the close of the auction. A bidder can submit a proxy bid and the bidding agent then bids on behalf of the potential buyer up to the proxy bid. As a consequence, not the last bid (as in ascending-price auctions) but the highest bid wins, regardless of submission time. (And the winner pays a small increment above the second highest submitted proxy bid, which is why this is a second-price auction.) Furthermore, there is a risk involved in late bidding in online auctions. Because the time it takes to place a bid may vary considerably due to erratic internet traffic or connection times, last-minute bids have a positive probability of coming in too late, after the close of the auction. EBay explains the simple economics of second-price auctions and the risks involved in late-bidding and comes to the conclusion: ebay always recommends bidding the absolute maximum that one is willing to pay for an item early in the auction. ( ) If someone does outbid you toward the last minutes of an auction, it may feel unfair, but if you had bid your maximum amount up front and let the Proxy Bidding system work for you, the outcome would not be based on time. However, Ockenfels and Roth (2006) demonstrated within an auction theoretic model that sniping on ebay can be a best response to a variety of strategies. In particular, inexperienced, naïve bidders might make an analogy with (open) ascending-price auctions, and be prepared to continually raise their bids to maintain their status as high bidder. In an ebay style auction that closes at a predetermined deadline ( hard close ), bidding very late might be a best response to incremental bidding (or multiple bidding) of this sort. That is, bidding very near the end of the auction would not give the incremental bidder sufficient time to respond, and so a sniper competing with an incremental bidder might win the auction at the incremental bidder's initial, low bid. In contrast, bidding one's value early in the auction, when an incremental bidder is present, would win the auction only if one's value were higher than the incremental bidder's, and in that case would have to pay the incremental bidder's value. 11 The evidence in the laboratory and the field indicates that incremental bidding is common, and that sniping is likely to arise in part as a response to incremental bidding. Wilcox (2000) indicated that 1.5 to 2 bids are submitted by the average bidder. Ockenfels and Roth (2006) reported that 38 percent of the bidders bid at least twice. Furthermore, the number of bids per bidder is increasing in the number of other active bidders who bid multiple times, suggesting that incremental bidding may induce bidding wars with like-minded incremental bidders. 5

7 There are other ways to explain late and incremental bidding without positing inexperience on the part of the bidders, including implicit collusion (Roth and Ockenfels (2002)) and common-value aspects of the item being sold. 12 Some observers of ebay believe that the amount of sniping will decrease over time because it is mainly due to inexperience and unfamiliarity with ebay's proxy bidding system. This section showed, however, that there are a variety of rational, strategic reasons for sniping. In fact Wilcox (2000), Roth and Ockenfels (2002), Wintr (2004), and Ariely et al. (2005) observed both in laboratory and field studies that more experienced bidders snipe more often than less experienced bidders. Thus, it seems likely that late bidding will remain a persistent phenomenon on ebay as long as the auction rules remain unchanged. B.I.3. Rule for ending electronic auctions On ebay, auctions end at a predetermined time: a hard close. Amazon, on the other hand, emulates the Going, Going, Gone feature of traditional auction houses and employs a soft close. That is, Amazon automatically extends an auction if a bid comes in late, so that all bidders always have the opportunity to respond to the opponents' bids. Ockenfels and Roth (2006) show that, although the risks of last-minute bidding remain, the strategic advantages of last-minute bidding are eliminated or severely attenuated in Amazon-style auctions. That is, a bidder who waits to bid until the last seconds of the auction still runs the risk that his bid will not successfully be transmitted in time. However, if his bid is successfully transmitted, the auction will be extended for ten minutes, so that, no matter how late the bid was placed, other bidders will have time to respond. Thus on Amazon, an attentive incremental bidder, for example, can respond whenever a bid is placed. The differences in the strategic environment are reflected in the data: there is significantly more late bidding on ebay than on Amazon. For instance, in the sample of Roth and Ockenfels (2002), 40 percent of ebay-computers auctions and 59 percent of ebay-antiques auctions have last bids in the last 5 minutes, compared to about 3 percent of both Amazon computer and Amazon antiques auctions that have last bids in the last five minutes before the initially scheduled deadline or later. Further analyses reveal that while the impact of the bidders' feedback numbers on late bidding is significantly positive in ebay, it is negative in Amazon, suggesting that more experienced bidders on ebay bid later than less experienced bidders, but experience in Amazon has the opposite effect. 6

8 Experiments by Ariely et al. (2005) replicate these findings in a controlled laboratory privatevalue setting in which the only difference between auctions is the ending rule. The experiment thus controls for differences other than the closing rule that might affect behaviour on Amazon and ebay, such as the number of auctions being conducted at a time and the number of potential bidders. Controlled field experiments, on the other hand, seem to have more difficulties to find evidence for the impact of the ending rule. Brown and Morgan (2005) and Houser and Wooders (forthcoming) took advantage of the fact that Yahoo sellers are allowed to choose whether to end the auction with a hard or a soft close. In both studies, identical items were sold using both ending rules. None of these studies found a significant effect of the ending rule on the amount of late bidding. However, Houser and Wooders (forthcoming) observed that, ceteris paribus, hard-close auctions tend to raise somewhat less revenue than soft-close auctions (as it was found in Ariely et al. (2005)). Online market design includes the design of artificial agents, such as ebay's proxy bidder (Ockenfels and Roth (2002)). Because late-bidding involves a good deal of planning and effort, artificial agents can also help executing late-bidding strategies. In fact, there is a market for artificial sniping agents (like esnipe.com) that will allow a bidder not only to submit a proxy bid, but to do so at the last moment. Note that to the extent sniping becomes more widespread on ebay, ebay will be gradually transformed into a sealed-bid second-price auction. If a large part of the late bidding activity takes place on third party sites like esnipe.com, ebay faces a number of design and rule choices. One is to ban sniping services. In fact, ebay.de (Germany) banned third party sniping services in its general terms and conditions (which is, of course, difficult to enforce). A second choice would be just the opposite: recapturing the sniping market by offering a sniping option on ebay itself. Under this option, last minute bids submitted in advance directly to ebay could all be counted at the same time, immediately after the auction close. This would give bidders certainty both that their bids would be successfully transmitted and that there would be no time for other bidders to react. Of course, if all bidders used this option, the auction would be precisely a sealed bid auction. As we have argued above, ebay might prefer not to encourage this development towards sealed-bid bidding. Yet, ebay supports its own sniping service, which enables last-minute bidding via phone. While bidding by phone will still 7

9 involve risks that the bid fails to be successfully submitted, it probably further increases the number of snipes. Finally, ebay could consider changing the ending rule of the auction to a soft close. Such a change, however, may also cause adverse effects. Sniping cannot only help bidders to get better prices on ebay, but sellers too can profit from sniping, because the possibility of sniping may attract more bidders. For instance, sniping can lead to more bidding from experts in auction environments with information externalities, because by bidding late, experts can avoid giving information to others through their own early bids. Sniping can also increase the excitement and entertainment value of bidding, which also can attract more bidders. B.II. Multi-unit auctions Most of the auctions on ebay and other C2C online market places are single-unit auctions, i.e., a seller sells only one item per auction. Obviously, a seller with a lot of (maybe identical) objects for sale can use such auctions and sell the items in separate auctions (either simultaneously or sequentially). But this is inconvenient as the seller needs to initiate and monitor many auctions. 13 Due to the increase of B2C sales and the associated demand for market designs that allow selling multiple units in a single auction, auction platforms started to offer multi-unit auctions. 14 The analysis of multi-unit auctions is considerably more difficult and the theoretical as well as empirical literature is less developed. Part of the reason is that, when objects are heterogeneous or bidders demand multiple items, new difficulties arise such as market power and strategic and computational complexities. In addition there are many more design-alternatives, and general insights are difficult to come by. 15 In particular, the sale of complementary objects typically poses non-trivial challenges, because efficient auctions have to allow bids on bundles of objects. For example, the celebrated Vickrey auction requires that bidders specify their preferences on any possible package of the N objects, i.e., each bidder has to submit 2 N -1 numbers. Especially for a large number of objects such an auction is infeasible. 16 Fortunately, multi-unit auction design is considerably simpler if each bidder just demands one object (or, more generally, if objects are substitutes). Under this unit-demand assumption, ebay's single-unit auction format has a natural extension: every bidder submits a (proxy) bid and the N highest bidders win one object each and pay a price that is an increment above the N+1'th highest (proxy) bid, i.e., the price is (almost) equal to the highest losing bid. In ebay's multi-unit auction 17, however, the final price is equal to the lowest winning bid. Consequently, one of the winners (the bidder with the N th highest bid) will determine the 8

10 price. If the N th highest bid is different from the N+1 th highest bid (e.g., because bidders bid valuations and not incrementally), each of the winning bidders can reduce the price by lowering his bid to an amount just above the highest losing bid. That is, the auction creates incentive for bid shading. But because the highest losing bid is usually not known before the auction is over, bidding is difficult. These kinds of arguments convinced ebay Germany to change their multi-unit format in summer 2005 to the more natural format discussed above. However, in a more general auction environment, neither ebay's old nor the new multi-unit format share the desirable properties of the second-price auction in the single-object case. The reason is that if a bidder can demand more than one unit in ebay's multi-unit format, there is a positive probability that his bid on a second or later unit will be pivotal, thus determining the price for the first and possibly other inframarginal units. With discrete goods, the bidder will thus in equilibrium bid his true value on the first unit demanded, but strictly less on all subsequent units. As a consequence, in equilibrium, bidders understate their values, or (equivalently) reduce demanded quantities, hampering revenue and efficiency. 18 Furthermore, efficiency cannot be expected in case of complementarities; that is, when the value of a bundle of objects is larger than the sum of values of each object separately. This may not only be the case on ebay but also in many applications including spectrum auctions, electricity auctions, airport landing slots auctions, supply chains, and transportation services auctions. In such cases, a bidder may end up stuck with objects that are worth little because he failed to win complementary objects (exposure problem), and may quit early because of fear of this. As a result, inefficiencies are likely to arise in all auction formats, in which bidders cannot make sure to purchase desired packages of objects. The way ebay addresses these problems is to allow bidders, who receive less objects than demanded, to withdraw the bid for all units. Allowing bid withdrawal, however, raises further design questions. For instance, what is the price to be paid by the winners when, after the auction, a bid is withdrawn? If the withdrawn bid counts (which is the case on ebay), the winner may rightly ask why he has to pay the higher price even though there is, after the withdrawal, no competition that justifies the higher price. We believe that designing a robust multi-unit auction that can account for even complex preferences of the bidders into account is an important challenge to online auctions. The changes on ebay s German platform go into the right direction. More radical changes could involve, 9

11 for instance, a declining buy-it-now price: the price decreases from a high initial price and then declines by a predetermined decrement at predetermined times so that a bidder can indicate how many items he is willing to buy at the current price. The auction ends when all objects are gone (or when the auction runs out of time). This auction format would combine ebay's successful buy-it-now format, which is often used to sell multiple units, with the merits of an auction. As bidders who demand a certain amount of objects know at any time whether they will be able to win that bundle, one may expect bids (and revenue) to be higher than in ebay's multi-unit auction, where, due to the exposure problem, bidders might be reluctant to bid. B.III. Reputation systems Moral hazard problems seriously challenge the performance of online markets. Traders are usually anonymous and geographically dispersed, exchange is done sequentially, and the quality of objects is difficult to verify. 19 In addition, the huge number of transactions, the lack of repeated interaction with the same trading partner 20 and the possibility to create new identities without cost aggravates the problem of fraud in online markets. In fact, a report by the research group GartnerG2 (2002) concludes that Internet transaction fraud is 12 times higher than in-store fraud. 21 In markets with few, well known traders reliance on legal enforcement might be sufficient (this is probably the case in energy markets, see section C.), whereas almost all online market platforms incorporate additional measures that encourage bidders to sanction fraudulent traders. In particular, ebay responds to this challenge with a mixture of policies and mechanisms. 22 In this section, we describe ebay's most visible mechanism, the reputation system, from a market design perspective. On ebay, after each encounter, buyers and sellers evaluate each other by giving the trading partner either a positive (+1), neutral (0) or negative (-1) feedback (and maybe an additional verbal commentary). These feedbacks are publicly available and easy to access such that each buyer can look at a seller s feedback history before he engages in bidding. This way, ebay's feedback mechanism can weaken the incentives for moral hazard. If ebay traders punish sellers with negative feedback information by refusing to buy from them or reducing the price they are willing to pay, then the threat of leaving negative feedback may discipline the 10

12 seller. 23 However, two points are central for the functioning of online reputation systems. First, they must generate reliable information about market participants' trading patterns. Second, they must evoke the desired reactions of traders to this information. In online reputation systems, feedback information must come from voluntary self-reporting of personal experiences. But feedback constitutes a public good; the benefit from giving feedback goes to other traders, and nobody can be excluded from using this feedback information. Furthermore, there is a kind of information externality, as observed by Bolton et al. (2004) in an experiment, and theoretically discussed in Bolton and Ockenfels (2006). As an illustration, observe that the risk of fraud is highest for trades with newbies, i.e. for trades with a seller, who has not been evaluated yet. So, buyers may only be willing to trust sellers, who have proven to be reputable, but then nobody would be willing to generate this information. However, despite these various free-riding problems, about 50 percent of the transactions on ebay receive feedback (Resnick and Zeckhauser (2002)). One of the main motives for providing the public good and giving feedback appears to be the expectation that a positive feedback is reciprocated by the trading partner. 24 It also rationalizes ebay's decision to allow bilateral evaluations (buyers can leave feedback on sellers and vice versa). But, by the same token, bilateral feedback might also discourage negative feedback if negative feedback is repaid by negative feedback. 25 Thus, reciprocal feedback may yield more feedback giving at the cost of lower information value. To avoid retaliatory feedback, some observers recommend changes in the rules of ebay's reputation system. Güth et al. (2006) recommend that buyers only evaluate sellers, and not vice versa, because there is typically no adverse selection or moral hazard issue on the buyer side. Alternatively, they as well as Klein et al. (2005) recommend a blind period, in which both trading partners can leave feedback on each other, which however is not revealed before the end of the blind period. Other more sophisticated proposed rule changes include an idea by Jurca and Faltings (2004), who propose that traders simultaneously rate the transaction. If the reports disagree, one of the traders must be lying, and both parties have to pay fines. Obviously, this simple game has a truth-telling equilibrium. Alternatively, Miller et al. (forthcoming) propose a mechanism based on scoring rules. The underlying idea is that a feedback giver is paid according to the extent the feedback predicts future seller performance. Under certain assumptions, a proper scoring rule also induces truth-telling behaviour. 11

13 Another source of noisy and manipulative feedback information is the possibility of identity change. The costs of changing an online trader identity is often close to zero, implying that fraudulent sellers can exploit their buyers and then reappear with a clean record. Ockenfels (2003) shows in a theoretical model, however, that a feedback mechanism can work, even if sellers with a bad history can change their identity and start again as a newbie. If buyers are only willing to buy from a newbie if he offers a lower price (as compared to a seller with a good history) then starting again as a newbie can be more costly than avoiding to get a bad reputation in the beginning. The empirical evidence in Ockenfels (2003) and in the studies cited in Bajari and Hortaçsu (2004) show that indeed newbies offer goods at a price discount. But market design can also play a decisive role, because the change of online identities can be made more costly by design. One technical way would be the use of modern authentication technologies. A more economic design approach would be to implement an entrance fee ; every trader who wants to sell on the market platform has to pay a fee that needs to be sufficiently high to deter fraudulent strategies of identity changes (Friedman and Resnick (2001)). To see how market participants react to provided feedback information, Bolton et al. (2004), conducted an experiment and compare trading in a market with online feedback to a market without feedback. 26 They find that the feedback mechanism induces quite a substantial improvement in transaction efficiency and buyers respond to feedback information in a strategic way. If a seller shipped the last order, a buyer is twice as likely to trust him. 27 They also find that a trader's behaviour is influenced by own experience: a buyer who has been treated badly in the past is more likely to mistrust other sellers - regardless of their reputation. Furthermore, buyers put more weight on negative than positive feedback, and more on recent than old feedback (see also Lucking-Reiley et al. (1999), and Resnick and Zeckhauser (2002), and Keser (2002)). These findings suggest, among other things, that market performance can be increased if market participants are provided with summary statistics about overall feedback. This might mitigate the negative effect of own bad experience and hides information that affects buyers' decisions (in non-desirable way). But they also note that a problem with relying solely on cumulative feedback measures comes from the fact that the seller's actions have diminishing impact on the overall assessment. This may lead to increasing incentives to exploit one's good reputation

14 C. The design of electricity markets The liberalization of energy markets created a new interest in the design of electricity markets, though the theoretical and empirical literature is still in its infancy. One reason is the complexity of electricity markets, which involve many layers of intertwined trading institutions, and require sound knowledge of the technical constraints related to energy trading. Another reason is that electricity trading rules widely differ across the nations, as do the political, environmental and economic conditions. Because of space restrictions, we will suppress many complicating aspects here (see Müsgens and Ockenfels (2006) and the references cited therein for a more detailed description of market design issues). Our goal is to demonstrate that the microstructure of the market rules can be decisive for the market performance. Because electricity markets are organised as auctions 29 most of the design-issues discussed in this section have relevance beyond electricity markets. In particular questions concerning the timing of (interlinked) auctions and problems that arise because of the multi-object nature of electricity auctions are also relevant for online market design (and market design in general). Electricity markets are, in some sense, inherently fragile. Energy cannot be stored at reasonable costs so that the market, which suffers from stochastic supply and demand, has to be balanced in real time. As a result, equilibrium prices are extremely volatile. Furthermore, shortrun demand is inelastic, as is supply near the capacity limits, and transmission of electricity is often constrained. Therefore the market can be prone to the exercise of market power (which may be amplified by high entry costs and asymmetric information). And finally, electricity markets consists of several (strategically connected) sub-markets, which interact in various ways. 30 On forward markets, future contracts (and other derivatives) are traded (long) before the physical exchange of electricity takes place. This gives suppliers and buyers the possibility to lock in prices and reduce risks. On the day-ahead market electricity is traded for each of the 24 hours of the next day (in Germany, this is done on the Electricity Exchange, EEX, in Leipzig). Capacity and reserve markets (which typically take place immediately after and sometimes immediately before the day-ahead market) should help to improve reliability by mitigating the effects of unanticipated supply and demand shocks. Suppliers offer capacity as reserves which, if purchased and called for, are activated to balance supply and demand in real time to avoid outages. And finally, the markets for transmission (in particular interconnector) capacity needs to be cleared

15 All four markets are obviously closely intertwined and an isolated consideration can easily be misleading. Indeed, already the establishment of the markets, as well as the timing and the detailed rules of each of the markets are the result of conscious market design considerations. Regarding the establishment, observe that California decided in the nineties not to allow forward markets in order to trigger a liquid and thick day-ahead market. This design policy - as has been thought - would weaken problems of market power, because all capacity is bid in the day-ahead market, and thus eventually yield low prices. However, in fact, the opposite is true; forward markets not only reduce price risks for both demand and supply, but also tend to make the day-ahead market less vulnerable to manipulation. For instance, a utility that has sold 100 percent of the capacity over the forward market has no incentive to influence dayahead prices. Also, it is profitable for each seller to commit himself to larger quantity in forward markets (not much unlike in the common Stackelberg model, see Allaz and Vila (1993)), which however, in the aggregate, leads to larger quantities and thus smaller profits for all sellers (e.g., Bolle (1993)). Finally, if buyers cannot lock-in prices long before consumption, generators can better exploit the fact that close to real-time demand is very inelastic. Empirical work strongly supports the view that forward markets tend to reduce electricity prices. For instance, it has been forcefully argued that banning forward markets in California was essential for the energy crisis in 2000 and 2001 to emerge (e.g., Borenstein et al. (2002)). The empirical study conducted by Wolak (2000) provides strong evidence that forward markets may mitigate market power. Experiments under controlled conditions, without the complicating aspects that prevent unambiguous interpretation of the field data, come to the same conclusion (see Brandts et al. (2003), see also Rassenti et al. (2002) for a discussion about how experiments may help shaping the deregulation efforts in energy markets). Once the existence of markets is established, the timing becomes the next crucial market design issue. Because different markets may trade complements or substitutes, an inappropriate timing of the markets imposes serious strategic complexities and coordination problems for bidders. They also limit the information available to bidders, and how bidders can respond to this information, in particular in the presence of complementarities. Bidders must guess future prices, and incorrect guesses hamper revenue and efficiency. For example, Dutch-German interconnector (transmission) capacities are often auctioned off before the corresponding electricity markets clear. However, electricity and transmission capacity are obviously complements, and bidding in one market depends on the outcomes in the other market. As a result of this uncertainty, the exposure problem yields coordination problems and result in large ineffi- 14

16 ciencies. 32 Other European interconnectors (e.g., NordPool) solved the problem more efficiently by implementing what is sometimes called an implicit auction, where transmission capacity is managed implicitly by two or more neighbouring spot markets. Here, network users submit bids for electricity in the geographical zone where they wish to generate or consume, and the market clearing procedure determines the most efficient amount and direction of physical power exchange between the market zones. Hence, cross border capacity and energy are traded together. An even more comprehensive market would also include reserve markets, because the timing of electricity reserve auctions, which are partly cleared before and after the day-ahead market, pose similar problems. From a generator's point of view, selling electricity to the day-ahead market or the reserve market are substitutes; capacity that is sold in the day-ahead market cannot be sold anymore in the reserve market. An obvious market design solution to such timing problem is the simultaneous clearing of all these markets. A timing problem also occurred in capacity markets. 33 Take the capacity market used in New England in the nineties (Cramton (2003)). This market was intended to assure that there is sufficient capacity in the system to cover the peak load plus the reserve margin. Generators could submit bids expressing their willingness to supply capacity, and a market clearing price was calculated. Eventually, generators with bids below the price provided the capacity at the clearing price. However, the price for capacity is determined day-ahead - at a time where the cost of offering capacity is sunk (as investments in increasing capacity are long-term). So, absence of market power, the only rational bid is zero. With market power, the price is arbitrarily high. Obviously, the market design failed to promote efficient capacity investments. Given the timing of markets, the market rules need to be designed. Let us, for example, take a look at the details of the bidding formats and rules in the day-ahead market. Should bids be binding, should there be a bid cap, and what costs are bids allowed to reflect? In day-ahead markets participants submit their bids one day ahead, for every hour of that day. Such a bid describes a bidders supply or demand function, and is then used to derive a supply schedule and a clearing price for every hour of the following day. In some markets, however, bidders could change their bids without any penalty until the electricity is physically exchanged, because suppliers sometimes have to deal with unpredictable outtakes. But this can lead to gaming in a way that suppliers initially submit bids to win contracts and then exploit the market 15

17 power they have close to real time when demand becomes price-inelastic. One solution to this dilemma is to allow bid changes, but to impose costs when initial bids are changed (see Milgrom (2004) who describes a similar problem and solution in spectrum auction design). A similar problem to that of non-binding bids occurred in the day-ahead markets of California. To prevent exaggerated prices the Californian day-ahead market did not allow for prices above a certain, pre-determined level. But this rule turned out to be ineffective as bidders could avoid the day-ahead market and offer their electricity on the reserve market, which did not restrict prices by such a bid-cap. As the bid cap could not be enforced (in the sense that it could easily be bypassed), it was ineffective and eventually given up. Day-ahead markets also suffer from the exposure problem, if bidders cannot adequately express their preferences. The per-hour cost of electricity crucially depends on the total running time of the generator as suppliers face substantial start-up and no-load costs (Müsgens and Neuhoff (2005)). As in the day-ahead auction bidders submit demand and supply functions for every hour of a day but cannot express their preferences for sequences of hours, they might be reluctant to bid. Similar to a buyer who demands several units on an ebay multi-unit auction and who fears winning too few objects (making it impossible to realize synergies), a supplier in the day-ahead market is afraid of not winning subsequent hours. Therefore, electricity may not be generated at lowest costs. The exposure problem can be avoided if suppliers can express their complex cost structure in their bids. Usually this implies that they have to be able to submit supply functions for all possible combinations of hours of a day. As this is hardly feasible, Cramton (2003) suggests that in addition to a supply function suppliers submit their start-up and no-load costs, as this sufficiently describes their production costs. 34 D. The design of partnership dissolution mechanisms The market discussed in this section differs from those in previous sections. First, the number of participants is low and second, seller(s) and buyer(s) are determined endogenously by the market rules. The following discussion of partnership dissolution mechanisms does not merely show (once more) that details matter but also provides an example for how marketdesign techniques can be applied to a less conventional market. When a business partnership or joint venture comes to an end, partners have to decide what to do with their jointly owned business. 35 Under the assumption that the partnership is profitable 16

18 it is more sensible for one partner to buy out the other or to sell the entire business to a third party and realize the profits rather than to liquidate. In many instances assets may be less valuable to a third party than to either partner and thus a buy-out should be preferred to a sale. 36 In a buy-out partners essentially have to determine who should become sole owner of the partnership and how leaving partners should be compensated. To obtain an efficient allocation, 37 the shares of the partnership should be traded on a market where the partners are the market participants. A particularity of this market is that buyers and sellers are endogenously determined by market interactions, as it is possible that a certain partner will either end up selling his shares or buying-out the other partners (but does not know whether he will be buying or selling at the time the market opens). In this section, we want to demonstrate how market design matters for such a dissolution market. In particular we once more want to point out the importance of seemingly small design details and how rules affect individual behaviour. Rules that govern the division of a commonly owned object are already mentioned in the Old Testament [Genesis 13: 8-9] and Hesiod's Theogony. The rules described there are known as the cake-cutting mechanism or the divide-and-choose mechanism, and work as follows. One of two partners has to divide a commonly owned asset (e.g., a cake), and the other partner then decides which share he wants to possess. 38 The divide-and-choose mechanism is also applicable to partnership dissolution, though it needs to be modified as a partnership (usually) is an indivisible business entity. Such a modification of the divide-and-choose mechanism is the so called buy-sell clause or shoot-out mechanism. Assume that each of two partners owns 50% in a partnership. 39 The buy-sell clause states that one partner (the proposer) makes a price-offer and the other partner (the chooser) decides on whether to sell her share or buy the other partner's share at this price. This buy-sell clause is the prevalent dissolution procedure in Anglo-Saxon corporate law and is recommended by corporate lawyers and included in most partnership agreements (see Brooks and Spier (2004), Stedman and Jones (1990) and Cadman (2004)). It is important to stress that the buy-sell clause becomes effective when the partnership needs to be dissolved because of a contingency like a dispute. The performance of the clause can be measured in terms of efficiency, i.e. it should allocate the partnership to the partner who values it most (e.g., because he is most capable of running the business) at the time of the dissolution. 40 Its broad application suggests that the buy-sell clause performs well. Nevertheless, de Frutos and Kittsteiner (2004) cite cases in which the clause seems to have failed. The origin for these 17

19 failures can be found in the fact that partners prefer to be chooser rather than proposer. In fact, in most theoretical models with asymmetric information (about the value of the partnership), a partner is better off choosing than proposing in the buy-sell clause. 41 This is because a proposer does not know whether eventually he will buy or sell at the proposed price, which makes it difficult for him to exploit his private information on his valuation for the partnership. A chooser does not have this disadvantage. He can decide on whether to buy or sell at the proposed price. This shows that the determination of the proposer is an essential part of the dissolution process and the buy-sell clause has to be very specific on this matter and needs to be carefully designed to avoid disputes and inefficiencies. Examples cited in de Frutos and Kittsteiner (2004) indicate that the dissolution has been problematic in cases where it was specified that the partner who initiates the dissolution has to propose the price. 42 This is because both partners (who are in dispute) want to dissolve but no one wants to make the (initial) price offer (as this is disadvantageous). Consequently, the partners engage in a war of attrition and wait for the other to move first. This can lead to an inefficiently long dispute on who has to propose which may even end up before court. 43 De Frutos and Kittsteiner show that a different rule that governs the determination of the chooser can circumvent these problems. They show that if partners negotiate on who has to propose, the buy-sell clause can perform better than in the case where partner's just wait for the other to come up with a price. In their theoretical model they demonstrate that the buy-sell clause where the proposer is determined endogenously by negotiation is indeed the best possible dissolution rule (as it is efficient). They also provide a case that suggests that a partnership dissolution where the proposer has been determined by negotiations worked flawlessly. 44 Here again we find that a seemingly small difference in the rules (how the proposer is determined) can make all the difference with respect to the performance of an entire market (which here governs the dissolution). But also other designs for partnership dissolution have been proposed. Cramton et al. (1987) suggest a simple auction where both partners 45 simultaneously submit a bid. The entire partnership is awarded to the higher bidder who pays an amount proportional to a convexcombination of the two bids. 46 Cramton et al. show that (under their assumptions) this auction, like the buy-sell clause with negotiations, is an optimal dissolution mechanism. 47 Even though the auction might seem a more natural design for a dissolution mechanism it is hardly recommended by lawyers and therefore absent in many partnership agreements. 48 Whereas de Frutos and Kittsteiner can rationalize the use of the buy-sell clause (if used with the correct 18

20 rule for selecting the proposer), an explanation of its pre-dominance with respect to auctions still requires further theoretical and empirical/experimental research (see Kittsteiner et al. (2006)). It should be noted that both mechanisms, the buy-sell clause and the auction, can fail to deliver an efficient dissolution if partners do not know the exact value of the partnership, as this depends on information only available to the other partner, and in addition partners only want to dissolve if the gains from trade that are associated with dissolution are large. Kittsteiner (2003) shows that the auction might result in an outcome where partners stay together even though a dissolution is desirable (i.e., it generates higher total profits). Fieseler et al. (2003) show that any market design for environments where the firms value depends on all partner's private information, exhibits this problem that partners stay together even though they should not. This implies that the buy-sell clause cannot be efficient in such environments either. The optimal market design for such a situation is still unknown. 49 We believe that the design of negotiation procedures, such as in partnership dissolution but also in online bargaining etc., is one of the most promising research areas in economic design. However, for significant progress to be made, more experimental and empirical work is needed. E. Conclusion Institutions matter. All our examples demonstrate that the design of rules and procedures significantly affects market outcomes. Even small design changes can have substantial consequences. But behaviour matters too. Experimental and field research shows that decision makers and traders respond to incentives. They do not always do so in a rational way, as predicted by standard theory, but they typically do so in a systematic and predictable way. This opens the door for market design as an engineering science (Roth (2002)), in which various theoretical and empirical tools interact to improve the performance of markets and negotiations. We think that the recent examples of market design, some of which are discussed and cited in this article, are only the beginning of a fruitful and exciting engineering literature in business and economics. 19

Economic Insight from Internet Auctions. Patrick Bajari Ali Hortacsu

Economic Insight from Internet Auctions. Patrick Bajari Ali Hortacsu Economic Insight from Internet Auctions Patrick Bajari Ali Hortacsu E-Commerce and Internet Auctions Background $45 billion in e-commerce in 2002 632 million items listed for auction on ebay alone generating

More information

8 Multi-contract tendering procedures and

8 Multi-contract tendering procedures and 8 Multi-contract tendering procedures and package bidding in procurement Nicola Dimitri, Riccardo Pacini, Marco Pagnozzi and Giancarlo Spagnolo 8.1. Introduction 193 In practical procurement, the most

More information

LATE AND MULTIPLE BIDDING IN SECOND PRICE INTERNET AUCTIONS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE CONCERNING DIFFERENT RULES FOR ENDING AN AUCTION

LATE AND MULTIPLE BIDDING IN SECOND PRICE INTERNET AUCTIONS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE CONCERNING DIFFERENT RULES FOR ENDING AN AUCTION LATE AND MULTIPLE BIDDING IN SECOND PRICE INTERNET AUCTIONS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE CONCERNING DIFFERENT RULES FOR ENDING AN AUCTION AXEL OCKENFELS ALVIN E. ROTH CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 992 CATEGORY 9: INDUSTRIAL

More information

The Timing of Bids in Internet Auctions: Market Design, Bidder Behavior, and Artificial Agents *

The Timing of Bids in Internet Auctions: Market Design, Bidder Behavior, and Artificial Agents * The Timing of Bids in Internet Auctions: Market Design, Bidder Behavior, and Artificial Agents * Axel Ockenfels University of Magdeburg, Germany Alvin E. Roth Harvard University AI Magazine, Fall 2002,

More information

Managerial Economics

Managerial Economics Managerial Economics Unit 8: Auctions Rudolf Winter-Ebmer Johannes Kepler University Linz Winter Term 2012 Managerial Economics: Unit 8 - Auctions 1 / 40 Objectives Explain how managers can apply game

More information

Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case

Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case Andrea Amelio and Dimitrios Magos ( 1 ) Introduction ( 1 ) This paper offers an economic background for the analysis conducted by the Commission during

More information

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions Chapter 7 Sealed-bid Auctions An auction is a procedure used for selling and buying items by offering them up for bid. Auctions are often used to sell objects that have a variable price (for example oil)

More information

Reputation management: Building trust among virtual strangers

Reputation management: Building trust among virtual strangers Reputation management: Building trust among virtual strangers September 2006 Executive summary Trust is essential to efficient business activities, but it doesn t come naturally in an online environment.

More information

8 Modeling network traffic using game theory

8 Modeling network traffic using game theory 8 Modeling network traffic using game theory Network represented as a weighted graph; each edge has a designated travel time that may depend on the amount of traffic it contains (some edges sensitive to

More information

Cournot s model of oligopoly

Cournot s model of oligopoly Cournot s model of oligopoly Single good produced by n firms Cost to firm i of producing q i units: C i (q i ), where C i is nonnegative and increasing If firms total output is Q then market price is P(Q),

More information

Stock market simulation with ambient variables and multiple agents

Stock market simulation with ambient variables and multiple agents Stock market simulation with ambient variables and multiple agents Paolo Giani Cei 0. General purposes The aim is representing a realistic scenario as a background of a complete and consistent stock market.

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation The Cournot and Bertrand models are the two basic templates for models of oligopoly; industry structures with a small number of firms. There are a number

More information

Measuring Unilateral Market Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets: The California Market, 1998 2000

Measuring Unilateral Market Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets: The California Market, 1998 2000 Measuring Unilateral Market Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets: The California Market, 1998 2000 By FRANK A. WOLAK* * Department of Economics, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305-6072, and NBER

More information

MAREK MAURIZIO DOCENTE A CONTRATTO ASSEGNISTA DI RICERCA UNIVERSITÀ CA FOSCARI, VENEZIA

MAREK MAURIZIO DOCENTE A CONTRATTO ASSEGNISTA DI RICERCA UNIVERSITÀ CA FOSCARI, VENEZIA ONLINE AUCTIONS MAREK MAURIZIO DOCENTE A CONTRATTO ASSEGNISTA DI RICERCA UNIVERSITÀ CA FOSCARI, VENEZIA AUCTIONS AN AUCTION IS A MARKET MECHANISM THAT USES A COMPETITIVE PROCESS BY WHICH: A SELLER SOLICITS

More information

Using clients rejection to build trust

Using clients rejection to build trust Using clients rejection to build trust Yuk-fai Fong Department of Economics HKUST Ting Liu Department of Economics SUNY at Stony Brook University March, 2015 Preliminary draft. Please do not circulate.

More information

Hybrid Auctions Revisited

Hybrid Auctions Revisited Hybrid Auctions Revisited Dan Levin and Lixin Ye, Abstract We examine hybrid auctions with affiliated private values and risk-averse bidders, and show that the optimal hybrid auction trades off the benefit

More information

Price Dispersion. Ed Hopkins Economics University of Edinburgh Edinburgh EH8 9JY, UK. November, 2006. Abstract

Price Dispersion. Ed Hopkins Economics University of Edinburgh Edinburgh EH8 9JY, UK. November, 2006. Abstract Price Dispersion Ed Hopkins Economics University of Edinburgh Edinburgh EH8 9JY, UK November, 2006 Abstract A brief survey of the economics of price dispersion, written for the New Palgrave Dictionary

More information

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings Emilia Matei 1005056 EC372 Term Paper. Topic 3 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes and Merton method of modelling derivatives prices was first introduced

More information

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION Abraham L. Wickelgren Professor Louis Kaplow s article, Multistage Adjudication, presents an extremely useful framework for thinking about how

More information

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management Most active managers are skilled. Jonathan B. Berk 1 This research was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation. 1 Jonathan B. Berk Haas School

More information

Competing Trading Platforms: Nash bargainers against Walrasian auctioneers

Competing Trading Platforms: Nash bargainers against Walrasian auctioneers Competing Trading Platforms: Nash bargainers against Walrasian auctioneers Rene Saran and Markus Walzl September 30, 2009 Extended Abstract Recent years have told many stories of the raise (and fall) of

More information

Electricity Market Design: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly

Electricity Market Design: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly Published in the Proceedings of the Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences, January, 2003. Electricity Market Design: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly Peter Cramton University of Maryland cramton@umd.edu

More information

English translation of the report: Strommarktdesign. Preisbildungsmechanismus im Auktionsverfahren für Stromstundenkontrakte an der EEX

English translation of the report: Strommarktdesign. Preisbildungsmechanismus im Auktionsverfahren für Stromstundenkontrakte an der EEX English translation of the report: Strommarktdesign Preisbildungsmechanismus im Auktionsverfahren für Stromstundenkontrakte an der EEX Prof. Dr. Axel Ockenfels* Dr. Veronika Grimm Dipl.-Vw. Gregor Zoettl

More information

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements How credit analysts view and use the financial statements Introduction Traditionally it is viewed that equity investment is high risk and bond investment low risk. Bondholders look at companies for creditworthiness,

More information

Successful International B2B Pricing for Manufacturers of Consumer Goods

Successful International B2B Pricing for Manufacturers of Consumer Goods Successful International B2B Pricing for Manufacturers of Consumer Goods Figure 1: Definition of action areas Cluster criteria: Geographical proximity Legal barriers/free trade agreements Similarity in

More information

E procurement: Multiattribute Auctions and Negotiations

E procurement: Multiattribute Auctions and Negotiations InterNeg Teaching Notes 1/11 E procurement: Multiattribute Auctions and Negotiations Gregory E. Kersten InterNeg Research Center and J. Molson School of Business, Concordia University, Montreal 1. Introduction

More information

The battle to contain fraud is as old as

The battle to contain fraud is as old as 22 SPONSORED FEATURE COMBATTING DIGITAL FRAUD Combatting digital fraud Combatting digital fraud has become a strategic business issue for today s CIOs. The battle to contain fraud is as old as business

More information

Convergence Bidding Tutorial & Panel Discussion

Convergence Bidding Tutorial & Panel Discussion Convergence Bidding Tutorial & Panel Discussion CAISO June 13, 2006 Joe Bowring PJM Market Monitor www.pjm.com Convergence Basics Day-Ahead Market basics Day-Ahead and Real-Time Market interactions Increment

More information

Financial Market Microstructure Theory

Financial Market Microstructure Theory The Microstructure of Financial Markets, de Jong and Rindi (2009) Financial Market Microstructure Theory Based on de Jong and Rindi, Chapters 2 5 Frank de Jong Tilburg University 1 Determinants of the

More information

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs.

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs. OPTIONS THEORY Introduction The Financial Manager must be knowledgeable about derivatives in order to manage the price risk inherent in financial transactions. Price risk refers to the possibility of loss

More information

As you move your cart down the grocery isle, stop in front of the canned soups. You see before maybe four or five different brands of soup.

As you move your cart down the grocery isle, stop in front of the canned soups. You see before maybe four or five different brands of soup. 1Oligopoly 19 As you move your cart down the grocery isle, stop in front of the canned soups. You see before maybe four or five different brands of soup. If you stop in front of the frozen pizzas you might

More information

The Evolution of Cooperation in Anonymous Online Markets

The Evolution of Cooperation in Anonymous Online Markets The Evolution of Cooperation in Anonymous Online Markets An Empirical Investigation of the Process of Reputation Formation Andreas Diekmann, Ben Jann Wojtek Przepiorka, Stefan Wehrli ETH Zürich www.socio.ethz.ch

More information

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

1 Uncertainty and Preferences In this chapter, we present the theory of consumer preferences on risky outcomes. The theory is then applied to study the demand for insurance. Consider the following story. John wants to mail a package

More information

The real value of corporate governance

The real value of corporate governance Volume 9 No. 1 The real value of corporate governance (c) Copyright 2007, The University of Auckland. Permission to make digital or hard copies of all or part of this work for personal or classroom use

More information

Heightened pricing complexity at each level

Heightened pricing complexity at each level TM How to Go from Good to Great with Pricing Software By Craig C. Zawada, Senior Vice President, Pricing Excellence, PROS INTRODUCTION GROWING COMPLEXITY DEMANDS SOFTWARE SOLUTIONS Over decades of experience

More information

ESRI Research Note. The Irish Electricity Market: New Regulation to Preserve Competition Valeria di Cosmo and Muireann Á. Lynch

ESRI Research Note. The Irish Electricity Market: New Regulation to Preserve Competition Valeria di Cosmo and Muireann Á. Lynch ESRI Research Note The Irish Electricity Market: New Regulation to Preserve Competition Valeria di Cosmo and Muireann Á. Lynch Research Notes are short papers on focused research issues. They are subject

More information

Understanding results of pilot implementation 1 2

Understanding results of pilot implementation 1 2 Research Reports Articles Managing a Fashion Supply Chain An Alternative to the Crystal Ball by Satyashri Mohanty Implementing pull based supply chain solutions of Theory of Constraints involves significant

More information

Comments on ISO s Third Revised Straw Proposal for Settlement of Interties in Real-Time

Comments on ISO s Third Revised Straw Proposal for Settlement of Interties in Real-Time Comments on ISO s Third Revised Straw Proposal for Settlement of Interties in Real-Time Department of Market Monitoring July 26, 2012 Summary The Department of Market Monitoring (DMM) appreciates the opportunity

More information

Stop Reacting to Buyers Price Expectations; Manage Them

Stop Reacting to Buyers Price Expectations; Manage Them Stop Reacting to Buyers Price Expectations; Manage Them BY THOMAS T. NAGLE AND JOSEPH ZALE Executive Takeways Pricing policies empower companies to manage customers price expectations, and avoid the cycle

More information

Forward Risk-Hedging Products PC_2012_E_13

Forward Risk-Hedging Products PC_2012_E_13 Answer to public consultation Petteri Haveri 26.10.2012 1(5) Agency for the cooperation of energy regulators consultation2012r08@acer.europa.eu Forward Risk-Hedging Products PC_2012_E_13 The Finnish Energy

More information

Keyword Auctions as Weighted Unit-Price Auctions

Keyword Auctions as Weighted Unit-Price Auctions Keyword Auctions as Weighted Unit-Price Auctions De Liu Univ. of Kentucky Jianqing Chen Univ. of Texas at Austin September 7, 2006 Andrew B. Whinston Univ. of Texas at Austin In recent years, unit-price

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

Chapter 5 Pricing Foundations and Implications on Web Service Pricing

Chapter 5 Pricing Foundations and Implications on Web Service Pricing Chapter 5 Pricing Foundations and Implications on Web Service Pricing 5.1 Pricing Principles in General One of the key building parts of a market is its market mechanism. This mechanism encloses the rules

More information

Reputation Rating Mode and Aggregating Method of Online Reputation Management System *

Reputation Rating Mode and Aggregating Method of Online Reputation Management System * Reputation Rating Mode and Aggregating Method of Online Reputation Management System * Yang Deli ** Song Guangxing *** (School of Management, Dalian University of Technology, P.R.China 116024) Abstract

More information

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 422 March 2009 Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Monika Piazzesi Stanford University and National

More information

Chapter 7: Capital Structure: An Overview of the Financing Decision

Chapter 7: Capital Structure: An Overview of the Financing Decision Chapter 7: Capital Structure: An Overview of the Financing Decision 1. Income bonds are similar to preferred stock in several ways. Payment of interest on income bonds depends on the availability of sufficient

More information

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015 ECON 459 Game Theory Lecture Notes Auctions Luca Anderlini Spring 2015 These notes have been used before. If you can still spot any errors or have any suggestions for improvement, please let me know. 1

More information

Industry profit in an oligopoly (sum of all firms profits) < monopoly profit.

Industry profit in an oligopoly (sum of all firms profits) < monopoly profit. Collusion. Industry profit in an oligopoly (sum of all firms profits) < monopoly profit. Price lower and industry output higher than in a monopoly. Firms lose because of non-cooperative behavior : Each

More information

Consultation on Forward Risk-Hedging Products and Harmonisation of Long-Term Capacity Allocation Rules

Consultation on Forward Risk-Hedging Products and Harmonisation of Long-Term Capacity Allocation Rules Deres referanse Vår referanse Dato PC_2012_E_13 N 26.10.2012 ACER Trg Republike 3 1000 Ljubljana, Slovenia Consultation on Forward Risk-Hedging Products and Harmonisation of Long-Term Capacity Allocation

More information

AN ANTITRUST PRIMER FOR PROCUREMENT PROFESSIONALS

AN ANTITRUST PRIMER FOR PROCUREMENT PROFESSIONALS PRICE FIXING & BID RIGGING - THEY HAPPEN: What They Are and What to Look For AN ANTITRUST PRIMER FOR PROCUREMENT PROFESSIONALS I. INTRODUCTION American consumers have the right to expect the benefits of

More information

Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders

Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders Peter Norman Sørensen Økonomi, KU GetFIT, February 2012 Peter Norman Sørensen (Økonomi, KU) Prediction Markets GetFIT,

More information

ANCILLARY SERVICES. A Paper for PPC. Establishment Organisation and Pilot Operation of the HTSO. 21 September 2000

ANCILLARY SERVICES. A Paper for PPC. Establishment Organisation and Pilot Operation of the HTSO. 21 September 2000 ANCILLARY SERVICES A Paper for PPC Establishment Organisation and Pilot Operation of the HTSO 21 September 2000 TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. INTRODUCTION 1 2. SYSTEM TRADING ARRANGEMENTS 2 3. OPTIONS FOR PROCUREMENT

More information

Game Theory and Poker

Game Theory and Poker Game Theory and Poker Jason Swanson April, 2005 Abstract An extremely simplified version of poker is completely solved from a game theoretic standpoint. The actual properties of the optimal solution are

More information

CALIFORNIA ISO. Pre-dispatch and Scheduling of RMR Energy in the Day Ahead Market

CALIFORNIA ISO. Pre-dispatch and Scheduling of RMR Energy in the Day Ahead Market CALIFORNIA ISO Pre-dispatch and Scheduling of RMR Energy in the Day Ahead Market Prepared by the Department of Market Analysis California Independent System Operator September 1999 Table of Contents Executive

More information

Oligopoly. Oligopoly is a market structure in which the number of sellers is small.

Oligopoly. Oligopoly is a market structure in which the number of sellers is small. Oligopoly Oligopoly is a market structure in which the number of sellers is small. Oligopoly requires strategic thinking, unlike perfect competition, monopoly, and monopolistic competition. Under perfect

More information

A. Introduction. 1. Motivation

A. Introduction. 1. Motivation A. Introduction 1. Motivation One issue for currency areas such as the European Monetary Union (EMU) is that not necessarily one size fits all, i.e. the interest rate setting of the central bank cannot

More information

Mercedes Hospital Online Bidding - A Review

Mercedes Hospital Online Bidding - A Review A Comment on Mercy Hospital s Online Bidding for RN Overtime Staffing Chris Stevens, Ohio University Dan Friesner, Gonzaga University ABSTRACT A central tenet of economics is that firms with lower costs

More information

by Maria Heiden, Berenberg Bank

by Maria Heiden, Berenberg Bank Dynamic hedging of equity price risk with an equity protect overlay: reduce losses and exploit opportunities by Maria Heiden, Berenberg Bank As part of the distortions on the international stock markets

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Quasi-Equity. Case study in using Revenue Participation Agreements. Venturesome

Quasi-Equity. Case study in using Revenue Participation Agreements. Venturesome Quasi-Equity Case study in using Revenue Participation Agreements Venturesome 2 Venturesome is a social investment fund, an initiative of the Charities Aid Foundation (CAF). Venturesome provides capital

More information

Internet Advertising and the Generalized Second Price Auction:

Internet Advertising and the Generalized Second Price Auction: Internet Advertising and the Generalized Second Price Auction: Selling Billions of Dollars Worth of Keywords Ben Edelman, Harvard Michael Ostrovsky, Stanford GSB Michael Schwarz, Yahoo! Research A Few

More information

Global Forum on Competition

Global Forum on Competition Unclassified DAF/COMP/GF/WD(2006)14 DAF/COMP/GF/WD(2006)14 Unclassified Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 16-Dec-2005 English

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

ebay economics: Factors that Determine Online Auction Prices

ebay economics: Factors that Determine Online Auction Prices ebay economics: Factors that Determine Online Auction Prices Günter Schamel Dept of Ag Economics and Social Sciences Humboldt University at Berlin Berlin, GERMANY 10099 g.schamel@rz.hu-berlin.de Selected

More information

Dissolving a partnership (un)fairly

Dissolving a partnership (un)fairly Dissolving a partnership (un)fairly John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley Berkeley, CA 947-19, USA (e-mail: morgan@haas.berkeley.edu) Received:

More information

Testimony on H.R. 1053: The Common Cents Stock Pricing Act of 1997

Testimony on H.R. 1053: The Common Cents Stock Pricing Act of 1997 Testimony on H.R. 1053: The Common Cents Stock Pricing Act of 1997 Lawrence Harris Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Presented to U.S. House of Representatives Committee on

More information

Demand for Health Insurance

Demand for Health Insurance Demand for Health Insurance Demand for Health Insurance is principally derived from the uncertainty or randomness with which illnesses befall individuals. Consequently, the derived demand for health insurance

More information

Understanding Financial Management: A Practical Guide Guideline Answers to the Concept Check Questions

Understanding Financial Management: A Practical Guide Guideline Answers to the Concept Check Questions Understanding Financial Management: A Practical Guide Guideline Answers to the Concept Check Questions Chapter 8 Capital Budgeting Concept Check 8.1 1. What is the difference between independent and mutually

More information

The Golden Nugget That Makes Traders Wealthy Trading. AAPL, RIMM And Gold Stocks. The Four Stages of Stocks

The Golden Nugget That Makes Traders Wealthy Trading. AAPL, RIMM And Gold Stocks. The Four Stages of Stocks The Golden Nugget That Makes Traders Wealthy Trading AAPL, RIMM And Gold Stocks I know most Apple enthusiasts will be rolling their eyes with my analysis and that s fine because the rest of us need people

More information

Imperfect information Up to now, consider only firms and consumers who are perfectly informed about market conditions: 1. prices, range of products

Imperfect information Up to now, consider only firms and consumers who are perfectly informed about market conditions: 1. prices, range of products Imperfect information Up to now, consider only firms and consumers who are perfectly informed about market conditions: 1. prices, range of products available 2. characteristics or relative qualities of

More information

Monetary Policy does not work in Russia's Barter Economy German Banking as a Solution?

Monetary Policy does not work in Russia's Barter Economy German Banking as a Solution? Monetary Policy does not work in Russia's Barter Economy German Banking as a Solution? Dalia Marin University of Munich, CEPR, and RECEP October 1999 The Non-Cash Economy in Ukraine/CIS - in Quest of Policy

More information

Reverse Auctions and the Government

Reverse Auctions and the Government A Troubled Asset Reverse Auction Lawrence M. Ausubel and Peter Cramton * 5 October 2008 1 Summary The US Treasury has proposed purchasing $700 billion of troubled assets to restore liquidity and solve

More information

Discussion Paper by CERC Staff

Discussion Paper by CERC Staff Improvement of Market Efficiency by information dissemination through display of Aggregate Demand and Supply Day Ahead curves by Power Exchange on their website Discussion Paper by CERC Staff Table of

More information

Written evidence for the Department of Business, Innovation and Skills: a small business commissioner

Written evidence for the Department of Business, Innovation and Skills: a small business commissioner Written evidence for the Department of Business, Innovation and Skills: a small business commissioner About ACCA ACCA is the global body for professional accountants. We aim to offer business-relevant,

More information

MobLab Game Catalog For Business Schools Fall, 2015

MobLab Game Catalog For Business Schools Fall, 2015 MobLab Game Catalog For Business Schools Fall, 2015 CORE COURSE COVERAGE Economics For Business Principles of Business Microeconomic Analysis Decisions Game Theory Negotiation Strategy Managerial Economics

More information

A Report to the Minister for Health and Children. Competition in the Irish Private Health Insurance Market Executive Summary

A Report to the Minister for Health and Children. Competition in the Irish Private Health Insurance Market Executive Summary A Report to the Competition in the Irish Private Health Insurance Market Executive Summary January 2007 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY AND RECOMMENDATIONS E 1. E 2. The Irish private health insurance market is community

More information

Statement of Guidance

Statement of Guidance Statement of Guidance Foreign Exchange Risk Management 1. Statement of Objectives To provide a standard of best practice to banks for the implementation of an effective and sound Foreign Exchange Risk

More information

CEJA Position. Improving the Functioning of the Food Supply Chain

CEJA Position. Improving the Functioning of the Food Supply Chain CEJA Position Improving the Functioning of the Food Supply Chain Introduction Following the European Commission s Communication on Tackling unfair trading practices (UTPs) in the business-to-business food

More information

Asymmetric Information

Asymmetric Information Chapter 12 Asymmetric Information CHAPTER SUMMARY In situations of asymmetric information, the allocation of resources will not be economically efficient. The asymmetry can be resolved directly through

More information

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011.

Two-State Options. John Norstad. j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011. Two-State Options John Norstad j-norstad@northwestern.edu http://www.norstad.org January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011 Abstract How options are priced when the underlying asset has only two possible

More information

Managing Cash Flow, Currency and Payment Risk

Managing Cash Flow, Currency and Payment Risk Managing Cash Flow, Currency and Payment Risk Managing Cash Flow, Currency and Payment Risk As US companies look to expand or start new operations overseas, new risks emerge that must be managed, with

More information

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB-107-002 ISSN 1866 4024

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB-107-002 ISSN 1866 4024 Business Brief Consolidation Index: Critical Success Factors for Industry Consolidation 1 ESMT No. BB-107-002 ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT ISSN 1866 4024 2 Business Brief Consolidation

More information

1. Care manager: rhetoric or reality Tad Kubisa Director of Social Services, Cambridgeshire

1. Care manager: rhetoric or reality Tad Kubisa Director of Social Services, Cambridgeshire 1. Care manager: rhetoric or reality Tad Kubisa Director of Social Services, Cambridgeshire When Griffiths presented his report Community Care - Agenda for Action to the Secretary of State, directors of

More information

Before you accept the Terms and Conditions and engage in our Services, it is important that you read these Risk Warnings.

Before you accept the Terms and Conditions and engage in our Services, it is important that you read these Risk Warnings. Important information Investment Risk Warnings Before you accept the Terms and Conditions and engage in our Services, it is important that you read these Risk Warnings. Definitions used in these Risk Warnings

More information

Summary Ph.D. thesis Fredo Schotanus Horizontal cooperative purchasing

Summary Ph.D. thesis Fredo Schotanus Horizontal cooperative purchasing Summary Ph.D. thesis Fredo Schotanus Horizontal cooperative purchasing Purchasing in groups is a concept that is becoming increasingly popular in both the private and public sector. Often, the advantages

More information

Eni Gas &Power s response to ERGEG s consultation - ERGEG principles: Capacity allocation and congestion management in natural gas transmission

Eni Gas &Power s response to ERGEG s consultation - ERGEG principles: Capacity allocation and congestion management in natural gas transmission Eni Gas &Power s response to ERGEG s consultation - ERGEG principles: Capacity allocation and congestion management in natural gas transmission networks. San Donato Milanese, 27.3.2009 Introduction Eni

More information

How To Mitigate Market Power

How To Mitigate Market Power ENERGY ADVISORY COMMITTEE Electricity Market Review: Market Power The Issue To review the range of practices in assessing and mitigating market power in the electricity supply industry, and to consider

More information

How To Make A Simultaneous Auction

How To Make A Simultaneous Auction Auctioning Airport Slots March 2001 DotEcon Ltd 105-106 New Bond Street London W1S 1DN www.dotecon.com Terms of reference Study commissioned jointly by DETR and HM Treasury Reviews the options for using

More information

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Luís M. B. Cabral New York University and CEPR November 2005 1 Introduction Beginning with their seminal 2002 paper,

More information

Wong 1. accessed 29 Nov 2010. 1 Malcolm Tatum, What is an Online Auction?, http://www.wisegeek.com/what-is-an-online-auction.htm,

Wong 1. accessed 29 Nov 2010. 1 Malcolm Tatum, What is an Online Auction?, http://www.wisegeek.com/what-is-an-online-auction.htm, Wong 1 Angel Hoi Ling Wong (UID: 303577059) Econ 106T Professor Board 2 December 2010 Priceline: Name Your Own Price Introduction Priceline.com ( Priceline ) is an e-commerce company that primarily provides

More information

Response by NIE Energy (PPB)

Response by NIE Energy (PPB) NIE Energy Limited Power Procurement Business (PPB) Review of K factors & Supply Margins and Tariff Structure Review Consultation Paper CER-09-093 Response by NIE Energy (PPB) 11 September 2009. Introduction

More information

How To Know Market Risk

How To Know Market Risk Chapter 6 Market Risk for Single Trading Positions Market risk is the risk that the market value of trading positions will be adversely influenced by changes in prices and/or interest rates. For banks,

More information

Development Methodologies Compared

Development Methodologies Compared N CYCLES software solutions Development Methodologies Compared Why different projects require different development methodologies. December 2002 Dan Marks 65 Germantown Court 1616 West Gate Circle Suite

More information

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk A. Research on Information Acquisition in Markets and Agency Issues Between Investors and Financial Intermediaries An important dimension of the workings of financial markets

More information

Credit Lectures 26 and 27

Credit Lectures 26 and 27 Lectures 26 and 27 24 and 29 April 2014 Operation of the Market may not function smoothly 1. Costly/impossible to monitor exactly what s done with loan. Consumption? Production? Risky investment? Involuntary

More information

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM) 1 CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM) This model is the main tool in the suite of models employed by the staff and the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) in the construction

More information

The Power Market: E-Commerce for All Electricity Products By Edward G. Cazalet, Ph.D., and Ralph D. Samuelson, Ph.D.

The Power Market: E-Commerce for All Electricity Products By Edward G. Cazalet, Ph.D., and Ralph D. Samuelson, Ph.D. The Power Market: E-Commerce for All Electricity Products By Edward G. Cazalet, Ph.D., and Ralph D. Samuelson, Ph.D. Why not use the Web to buy and sell transmission rights at prices derived from bids

More information