The Role of Time Preferences and Exponential-Growth Bias in Retirement Savings



Similar documents
TIAA-CREF Institute. Today s Choices, Tomorrow s Opportunity: Innovations in Retirement Policy and Practice

Gopi Shah Goda. Professional Experience. Education. Fields of Interest. Research

The Effect of the Affordable Care Act on the Labor Supply, Savings, and Social Security of Older Americans

Retirement Planning Software and Post-Retirement Risks: Highlights Report

HOW DO EMOTIONS INFLUENCE SAVING BEHAVIOR?

Challenger Retirement Income Research. How much super does a retiree really need to live comfortably? A comfortable standard of living

THE RESPONSIBILITY TO SAVE AND CONTRIBUTE TO

Complexity as a Barrier to Annuitization

MetLife Retirement Income. A Survey of Pre-Retiree Knowledge of Financial Retirement Issues

By Annamaria Lusardi and Olivia S. Mitchell*

WILL THE EXPLOSION OF STUDENT DEBT WIDEN THE RETIREMENT SECURITY GAP?

Insights: American Financial Capability

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

ARE 401(K) INVESTMENT MENUS SET SOLELY FOR PLAN PARTICIPANTS?

WILL REVERSE MORTGAGES RESCUE THE BABY BOOMERS?

DO HOUSEHOLDS HAVE A GOOD SENSE OF THEIR RETIREMENT PREPAREDNESS?

4. Work and retirement

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Human Capital, Asset Allocation and Life Insurance

Making Financial Education More Effective: Lessons From Behavioral Economics

DO HOUSEHOLDS HAVE A GOOD SENSE OF THEIR RETIREMENT PREPAREDNESS?

Planning for Retirement: The Importance of Financial Literacy

RETIREMENT SAVINGS OF AMERICAN HOUSEHOLDS: ASSET LEVELS AND ADEQUACY

Unmet Need for Workplace Accommodation

AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY OF Annuity CHOICE. Until recently,

WOMEN S PERSPECTIVES ON SAVING, INVESTING, AND RETIREMENT PLANNING

Session 5b Aging Asia 5b.1) Aging Asia: Asset Rich, Income Poor? Key risks to retirement income security and investment implications

Trends in Household Wealth Dynamics,

ICI RESEARCH PERSPECTIVE

What Individuals Should Plan For Retirement Risk Management

Testimony for the ERISA Advisory Council on Ways to Help Participants Make Better Decisions in Risk-Transfer Transactions

TRENDS AND ISSUES DESIGNING AND FRAMING ANNUITIES FEBRUARY 2013 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Can Annuity Purchase Intentions Be Influenced?

Over the past 30 years, there has been a fundamental change

Using Behavioral Economics to Improve Diversification in 401(k) Plans: Solving the Company Stock Problem

Medicaid Crowd-Out of Long-Term Care Insurance With Endogenous Medicaid Enrollment

How To Calculate The Insurance Gap In South Africa

Advanced Notice of Proposed Rulemaking Regarding Pension Benefit Statements [RIN 1210-AB20]

The Perfect 401(k) Plan

Personal Retirement Accounts and Saving Emma Aguila. Web Appendix (Not for Publication)

FINANCING OUR FUTURE. Economic and Social Outlook Conference July 2014

FINANCIAL EDUCATION AND RETIREMENT SAVINGS. Robert L. Clark Professor North Carolina State University

Retirement Planning of Younger Baby-boomers: Who Wants Financial Advice? Swarn Chatterjee and Velma Zahirovic-Herbert University of Georgia

DOES MORTALITY DIFFER BETWEEN PUBLIC AND PRIVATE SECTOR WORKERS?

Inaccurate and Biased: Cost-Benefit Analyses of Transport Infrastructure Projects

Evaluating Target Date Funds Multnomah Group, Inc. All Rights Reserved.

Midterm Exam. Answers

FACULTY RETIREMENT PLANS: THE ROLE OF RETIREE HEALTH INSURANCE

Your model to successful individual retirement investment plans

How Can Financial Literacy Improve Retirement Planning?

London: capital of debt. Reducing the health consequences of personal debt

Personal Accounts and Social Security Reform

ALLIANZ LIFE INSURANCE COMPANY OF NORTH AMERICA ALLIANZ LIFE INSURANCE COMPANY OF NEW YORK DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY DEPARTMENT OF LABOR RESPONSE OF:

Health and Mortality Delta: Assessing the Welfare Cost of Household Insurance Choice

Planning For Retirement:

An Improved Measure of Risk Aversion

On the Determinants of Household Debt Maturity Choice

READING 14: LIFETIME FINANCIAL ADVICE: HUMAN CAPITAL, ASSET ALLOCATION, AND INSURANCE

EQUITY INVESTMENT IN REAL ESTATE THROUGH LISTED REITS

Deferred Compensation in a Rising Tax Environment

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE RETIREMENT

A REVIEW OF FINANCIAL ADVICE MODELS AND THE TAKE-UP OF FINANCIAL ADVICE

10 MISTAKES PEOPLE MAKE IN RETIREMENT

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Individual Retirement Accounts and Saving

Demographic Trends, Housing Equity, and the Financial Security of Future Retirees

IMPACT OF RETIREE HEALTH INSURANCE IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR

HOW MUCH SHOULD PEOPLE SAVE?

MEMO. Comparing Traditional and Roth IRAs. Connecticut Retirement Security Board. Mercer Traditional vs. Roth IRA. contributions.

Impact of a Tax Credit for College Savings. TIAA-CREF and ScholarShare. January 15, 2014 (Update) Prepared for

Choice Of Health Insurance And The Two-Worker Household by Claudia L. Schur and Amy K. Taylor

A new toolbox for retirement planning

DOES STAYING HEALTHY REDUCE YOUR LIFETIME HEALTH CARE COSTS?

09/22/ PAA Conference Application. Joint retirement expectations of dual-worker couples

Transition risk: Rethinking investing for retirement By Tim Friederich, David Karim and Dr. Wolfgang Mader

ability to accumulate retirement resources while increasing their retirement needs; and

WILL THE REBOUND IN EQUITIES AND HOUSING SAVE RETIREMENTS?

A Plan Sponsor s Fiduciary Calling to Improve the Retirement Readiness of Plan Participants

TRENDS AND ISSUES ANNUITIES: NOW, LATER, NEVER? Benjamin Goodman, Director, Actuarial Consulting Services TIAA-CREF

LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE IN

What determines annuity demand at retirement?

Evaluating Target Date Funds Multnomah Group, Inc. All Rights Reserved.

Rethinking Fixed Income

ICI RESEARCH PERSPECTIVE

5 Steps To Planning Success :

CAN RETIREES BASE WEALTH WITHDRAWALS ON THE IRS REQUIRED MINIMUM DISTRIBUTIONS?

PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2009: RETIREMENT INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES UNITED STATES

2 Voluntary retirement module specification

The more they grow, the more you SHARE.

ICI RESEARCH PERSPECTIVE

Inflation. Chapter Money Supply and Demand

One Day I will understand how my retirement plan can help me work toward my goals. One Day is Today! LEARN MORE ABOUT YOUR RETIREMENT PLAN

Trends in Corporate Climate Change Governance

dialogue IGNORANCE IS NOT BLISS: THE IMPORTANCE OF FINANCIAL EDUCATION

Saving and Investing Among Higher Income African-American and White Americans

Chapter 22 Taxes on Savings

Asset Matters: How Goals-Based Allocation Drives Portfolio Positioning

DO INCOME TAXES AFFECT THE PROGRESSIVITY OF SOCIAL SECURITY?

Vanguard research August 2015

Transcription:

The Role of Time Preferences and Exponential-Growth Bias in Retirement Savings Gopi Shah Goda Stanford University and NBER Colleen Flaherty Manchester University of Minnesota Matthew R. Levy London School of Economics Aaron J. Sojourner University of Minnesota and IZA Joshua Tasoff Claremont Graduate University 17 th Annual Joint Meeting of the Retirement Research Consortium August 6-7, 2015 Washington, D.C. The NBER Retirement Research Center, the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College (CRR), and the University of Michigan Retirement Research Center (MRRC) gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Social Security Administration (SSA) for this conference. The authors acknowledge financial support for this study provided by the TIAA-CREF Institute, the Pension Research Council/Boettner Center of the Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania, the U.S. Social Security Administration through grant number RRC08098400-07 to the National Bureau of Economic Research as part of the SSA Retirement Research Consortium, and the National Institute on Aging of the National Institutes of Health under grant number R01AG020717. The findings and conclusions are solely those of the authors and do not represent the views of SSA, any agency of the federal government, the NBER Retirement Research Center, CRR, MRRC, or any institutions with which the authors are affiliated. Copyright 2015 Goda, Levy, Manchester, Sojourner and Tasoff. All rights reserved.

In aggregate, individual retirement savings are reaching unprecedented levels, totaling about $25 trillion. Yet there is considerable variation in retirement wealth across individuals even after taking into account background characteristics, such as age, income, and education. Because changes in the employer-provided pension landscape now require millions of Americans to rely more on their individual savings to finance retirement, understanding what factors contribute to differences in retirement-wealth accumulation and whether individuals are saving inadequately for retirement is a critical policy concern. If psychological biases play a strong role in driving individuals decisions, their choices may not be optimal. This study focuses on illuminating the role of two potential biases. First, individuals may have present-biased preferences, which is the tendency to exhibit patience when contemplating tradeoffs between future periods, but impatience when making tradeoffs between the present and the future. A time-consistent individual will make a plan and follow through. In contrast, a present-biased individual makes a plan but may procrastinate, continually pushing off action for a later date. Existing research shows how present bias is predicted to decrease savings, in theory, and that it is related to credit card debt, BMI, smoking, drinking, seatbelt use, and insurance purchase. However, there is a lack of empirical research relating present bias to retirement-saving behavior. Second, individuals may exhibit exponential-growth (EG) bias, the tendency to underestimate the exponential growth of an asset s value over time due to neglecting compound interest. Making informed, retirement-saving decisions requires grappling with the complex calculations required to assess whether current saving decisions are on-path to achieve one s desired standard of living in work and in retirement. A central piece of the calculation is compound interest, or the interest earned on previously earned interest that has been added to the principal. Misunderstanding this creates a cognitive barrier to optimal saving. A growing body of literature suggests that EG bias is prevalent among Americans and is correlated with lower levels of wealth accumulation and higher levels of debt. However, prior research has not uncovered whether EG bias independently drives wealth, or whether general cognitive ability or financial knowledge drive both. Theoretically, EG bias affects desired savings levels and present bias affects motivation and, thus, they may operate through separate channels. Understanding the prevalence and influence of these biases is critical for designing effective public policy in the context of retirement saving. We address this important gap in knowledge by estimating EG bias

and present bias at the individual level in a broad sample of the U.S. population. We measure the prevalence of these biases and present new evidence that connects these biases to accumulated retirement wealth. Description of Study Data Our study collected data via online surveys administered to participants in two representative U.S. samples: the American Life Panel hosted by RAND Corporation, and the Understanding America Study run by University of Southern California. Both provide computer and Internet services as needed to reach segments of the population without such access. We have a host of background information on panelists, such as age, gender, employment status, income, and education, as well as self-reported retirement wealth in individual accounts. In our study, each individual s time preference has two components: a standard discount rate that captures the stable way they discount later versus earlier consumption and a variable that captures the degree of present-bias, how much extra weight the person places on consumption in the present relative to all future periods. We measure these by asking a series of questions about how individuals value receiving various amounts of money over different time horizons. For example, Would you rather receive $100 today or $125.40 in 12 months? and Would you rather receive $120.00 in 12 months or $150.50 in 24 months? Individuals who indicate that they value payments received today relative to payments received in 12 months more than they value the same payments if received in 12 months relative to 24 months display characteristics of present bias. We measure the presence of EG bias using individuals responses to questions about the future value of an asset given various assumptions on the interest rate and time horizon. For example, individuals were asked: An asset has an initial value of $100 and grows at an interest rate of 10 percent each period. What is the value of the asset after 20 periods? EG bias is assessed based on the accuracy of the respondents answers. To increase the realism and relevance of the measures for high-stakes retirement decisions, individuals would earn more money for more-accurate answers. Calculators and other forms of help were neither explicitly forbidden nor suggested. Respondents were told they could use whatever approaches they preferred to answer the questions. Finally, we also measure individuals degree of self-awareness about these biases. We

measure people s overconfidence in their exponential estimation by allowing people to choose to get earnings based on the EG bias questions discussed above or a fixed sum of money. People did not yet know their performance on the questions. We classify people as overconfident if they preferred the performance pay to fixed pay larger even for fixed payments that were greater than their true performance payment. Finding: the biases are prevalent and independent A key contribution of this study is providing descriptive information on the prevalence of present bias and EG bias in the U.S. population. We classify individuals into one of four categories of EG bias and one of two categories of present bias, for a total of eight possible combinations of EG bias and present bias. The figure shows the distribution of our sample across these groups. We find that both biases are prevalent in the sample: 56 percent of the sample is present biased and 69 percent of the sample either underestimates ( Below ) or neglects ( Linear ) compound interest. Approximately 22 percent correctly perceive exponential growth ( Accurate ). A small portion (9%) of the sample perceives returns to be greater than exponential ( Above ). Importantly, having one bias is not related to having the other bias, as shown by the similar pattern of EG bias across those with and without present bias. Finding: each bias is associated with lower retirement wealth We relate these biases to individuals report of their accumulated retirement savings.

Because one s level of retirement savings also depends on factors other than biases, such as age, gender, ethnicity, and income, we control for these when isolating how retirement savings differs for those with EG bias and/or present bias. We also control for financial literacy (measured by three questions about risk diversification, inflation, and interest rates), general cognitive ability (measured by five questions from an IQ exam), risk preferences (measured using respondent s choice of coin-flip lotteries) and one s general preference for making tradeoffs in future dates. 1 We then use our model to predict retirement wealth based on differences in EG bias and present bias to determine the role of these biases in retirement saving decisions. 2 Being present bias leads to $24,934 less in predicted retirement wealth relative to someone who makes consistent tradeoffs, approximately 19% of average retirement savings. 3 For EG bias, those with accurate understanding have $27,375 more in predicted retirement wealth relative to those who neglect compounding (Linear), equivalent to 20% of average savings. By way of comparison, the predicted effect of each bias is larger than the effect of cognitive ability as captured by our IQ measure. In predicting retirement savings, our findings do not reveal evidence of an interaction between present bias and EG bias. Instead, each bias appears to separately relate to retirement savings. For whom are these biases more important for explaining retirement wealth? We find that the relationship between EG bias and retirement savings is stronger for individuals who earn higher income, who have a college degree, and who are the financial decision maker in the household. We also find that present bias has a stronger relationship with retirement wealth for those who do not have access to, or are not enrolled, in an employer-provided plan. If individuals are aware of their biases, they may be able to deal with them by seeking advice or tools that help them commit to saving. Indeed, we find that among individuals with the same level of EG bias, those who are more overconfident in their ability to understand exponential growth have significantly lower retirement-savings levels. Finally, we also administer a hypothetical retirement-saving scenario to evaluate how the 1 The full set of control variables includes one s general time preference, age, gender, number of children, marital status, race/ethnicity, educational attainment, income, interactions between age and income, employment status, state of residence, risk aversion, cognitive ability, and a standard measure of financial literacy. 2 These results implicitly assume that our measures of these biases are not correlated with other factors that affect retirement savings that are not included in our analysis. 3 Average retirement savings for the sample is $132,926.

saving behavior of individuals in our sample would respond depending on whether they receive an intervention meant to undo each bias. To do this, we construct a hypothetical scenario based on an employer introducing a match component to its employer-provided retirement plan, and we randomize receipt of two sets of interventions in our sample: retirement-income projections to address EG bias and incentives to plan to address present bias. We find evidence consistent with the treatments having larger effects among individuals with higher levels of bias than among individuals with lower levels of bias, further supporting the idea that these biases drive behavior. Conclusions This study provides important findings on the prevalence and influence of cognitive and motivational barriers to retirement savings. In particular, we measure the presence of EG bias and present bias, relate them to retirement savings, and use interventions designed to mitigate these biases to provide further evidence for the relationship. These biases are pervasive: 90 percent of the sample demonstrated one or both biases. Our evidence reveals that these biases are distinct in that having one does not increase one s likelihood of having the other. In addition, each bias has an important, and independent, relationship to retirement savings. Interpreted causally, our estimates imply that individuals would have 8 percent higher savings if both biases were eliminated. When we correct for the possibility that our measures of individuals biases contain random noise, the estimated relationships are much stronger, implying that eliminating both sources of bias would lead individuals to have 53 percent higher savings. We find that efforts to target those with EG bias through timely information are moderately effective. The recently proposed Lifetime Income Disclosure Act (113 th Congress, H.R. 2171), which would require plan administers to distribute income disclosures that project the annual income supported by an individual s current savings and contribution rate, may mitigate EG bias to some extent. While this study addresses important previously unresolved questions, a key limitation is its use of hypothetical choices when attempting to mitigate these biases. Future research would benefit from coupling direct measurement of the biases with a rich set of interventions to using actual retirement contribution and saving decisions.