STANFORD CENTER FOR INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT



Similar documents
Inclusive Development in Myanmar: Learning from Neighbours. Thangavel Palanivel UNDP Regional Bureau for Asia-Pacific

Globalization and International Trade

Trade Liberalization and Its Role in Chinese Economic Growth. Nicholas R. Lardy Senior Fellow Institute for International Economics Washington, D.C.

The Problem with Structural Unemployment in the U.S.

SOCIAL BACKGROUND OF OFFICERS IN THE INDIAN ADMINISTRATIVE SERVICE SANTOSH GOYAL

Maternal & Child Mortality and Total Fertility Rates. Sample Registration System (SRS) Office of Registrar General, India 7th July 2011

S&P 500 Composite (Adjusted for Inflation)

INDIA S GDP IN PRE AND POST GLOBALISED ERA: AN APPRAISAL

Internal Migration and Regional Disparities in India

Chapter 2. Education and Human Resource Development for Science and Technology

Economic Change in India

Trends in Private and Public Investments in Agricultural Marketing Infrastructure in India

ESTIMATES OF MORTALITY INDICATORS

Press Note on Poverty Estimates,

Following decades of instability and several natural disasters,

ASIAN JOURNAL OF MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Online Open Access publishing platform for Management Research

Ghana South Korea United States. Real GDP per capita (2005 dollars) Per centage of 1960 real GDP per capita real GDP per capita

Trends in Growth and Poverty in Asia: An Economic Background Paper for ASREP

CHAPTER-VI ECONOMIC GROWTH, POVERTY AND SOCIAL SERVICES EXPENDITURE. In this chapter, the impact of social services expenditure on economic

India s Economic Reforms

INDIAN LIFE INSURANCE INDUSTRY CHANGING SCENARIO AND NEED FOR INNOVATION

India: Defining and Explaining Inclusive Growth and Poverty Reduction

Consumption Structure Evolutions in an Aging Society and Implications for the Social Security System

India's Economic Development Since 1947

REGIONAL DISPARITIES IN GROWTH AND HUMAN DEVELOPMENT IN INDIA

Global Demographic Trends and their Implications for Employment

CONCEPT OF LIBERALIZATION, PRIVATIZATION AND GLOBALIZATION

Brief 1 The State of North Carolina: Jobs, Poverty and Family. Jeannine Sato, Center for Child and Family Policy

Forecasting Chinese Economy for the Years

Chapter 6 Economic Growth

INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITIES: URBANIZATION, INFRASTRUCTURE AND GOVERNANCE IN THE NORTH AND SOUTH OF INDIA

Evolution of informal employment in the Dominican Republic

The Global Findex Database. Adults with an account at a formal financial institution (%) OTHER BRICS ECONOMIES REST OF DEVELOPING WORLD

What has happened to Indian

Qualitative analysis of a potential Free Trade Agreement between the European Union and India. Executive Summary

Recent Developments and Outlook for the Mexican Economy Credit Suisse, 2016 Macro Conference April 19, 2016

ISSUES PAKISTAN'S ECONOMY S. AKBAR ZAIDI SECOND EDITION REVISED AND EXPANDED OXTORD UNIVERSITY PRESS

Structure of an Underdeveloped Agrarian Economy

A Brief Analysis of the Impact of NAFTA on the United States and Mexico. Animesh Singh Professor P. Dasgupta Saint Peter s College November 15, 2011.

Part F. Reforms in Pensions and in the Taxation of the Capital Market. 1. The Pension Reform

EMERGING MARKET CURRENCY PAIRS CURRENCY GUIDE

Joseph E. Zveglich, Jr.

Chapter 17. Preview. Introduction. Fixed Exchange Rates and Foreign Exchange Intervention

Long Island is rapidly losing its lead in private health care coverage. That distinctive mark of middle class success - private

Lars Osberg. Department of Economics Dalhousie University 6214 University Avenue Halifax, Nova Scotia B3H 3J5 CANADA

Regional Inequality in Healthcare in China

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS (Republic of the Marshall Islands: Public Sector Program)

The Macroeconomic Situation and Monetary Policy in Russia. Ladies and Gentlemen,

China s Economic Reforms and Growth Prospects. Nicholas Lardy. Anthony M Solomon Senior Fellow. Peterson Institute for International Economics

MACROECONOMIC AND FISCAL ASSESSMENT

EU-10 AND THE CAP CONTENTS

COMPARISON OF FIXED & VARIABLE RATES (25 YEARS) CHARTERED BANK ADMINISTERED INTEREST RATES - PRIME BUSINESS*

COMPARISON OF FIXED & VARIABLE RATES (25 YEARS) CHARTERED BANK ADMINISTERED INTEREST RATES - PRIME BUSINESS*

Convergence Clubs in Incomes across Indian States: Is There Evidence of a Neighbours Effect?

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

China s experiences in domestic agricultural support. Tian Weiming China Agricultural University

Growth and Employment in Organised Industry

Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty Reduction in China

China s 12th Five-Year Plan: Healthcare sector

Economic Planning in China by Gregory C. Chow, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 219 June 2011

The Central Role of Energy Efficiency in the Energy Outlook and EIA s Energy Data Program

Monetary Policy in Emerging Markets: Indonesia s s Case

TABLE 6.3 Exports of Selected South-East Asian Countries COUNTRY

Section 2 Evaluation of current account balance fluctuations

Chapter 3 LITERACY AND EDUCATION

Anjani Kumar*, Praduman Kumar* and Alakh N. Sharma**

The Case for a Tax Cut

What factors have contributed to globalisation in recent years? by Maziar Homayounnejad, Queen Elizabeth's School, Barnet.

GROWTH, DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY IN INDIA AND NEPAL

GOVERNMENT OF INDIA PRESS INFORMATION BUREAU *****

Chapter 11 Capital and Saving, page 1 of 9

Youth development in India: does poverty matter?

TPP#NEGOTIATION## OPPORTUNITIES#AND#CHALLENGES#FOR# VIETNAM#TEXTILE#&#APPAREL#INDUSTRY#

Adjusting to a Changing Economic World. Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. It s a pleasure to be with you here in Montréal today.

The Balance of Payments, the Exchange Rate, and Trade

Chapter 11. Development Policymaking and the Roles of Market, State, and Civil Society. Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

6. Gross Domestic Product by Country

Imperatives of Infrastructure

Project LINK Meeting New York, October Country Report: Australia

A Look at Dairy Market Price Volatility and Options for Dairy Policy Reform

AT&T Global Network Client for Windows Product Support Matrix January 29, 2015

A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF HUMAN DEVELOPMENT INDEX OF SELECTED INDIAN STATES

Economic Growth, Poverty and The Child*

THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2012 preliminary estimates)

Module 2 Illiteracy, Poverty, Unemployment and Population Growth

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF CORPORATE TAX RATE REDUCTIONS

The Puzzling Decline in Rural Women s Labor Force Participation in India: A Reexamination

Relationship of Macroeconomic Variables and Growth of Insurance in India: A Diagnostic Study

THE POTENTIAL MACROECONOMIC EFFECT OF DEBT CEILING BRINKMANSHIP

Have the Lower Income States Caught Up?

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

The Contentious Debate Over China s Economic Transition

India s Services Exports

Infrastructure Development in India's Reforms

Further Developments of Hong Kong s Offshore RMB Market: Opportunities and Challenges

Monetary Policy and Mortgage Interest rates

Figure 24 Georgia s Children a Major Focus of Human Services. $20 M Georgia Vocational Rehab Agency $1.5 M Office of Residential Child Care

II. Measuring and Analyzing GDP

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HUMAN CAPITAL, ECONOMIC GROWTH, AND INEQUALITY IN CHINA. James J. Heckman Junjian Yi

Transcription:

STANFORD CENTER FOR INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT Working Paper No. 182 China and India: Growth and Poverty, 1980-2000 by T.N. Srinivasan * September 2003 Stanford University 579 Serra Mall @ Galvez, Landau Economics Building, Room 153 Stanford, CA 94305-6015 * Department of Economics, Yale University, and Senior Fellow, Stanford Center for International Development.

China and India: Growth and Poverty, 1980-2000 * July 2003 T.N. Srinivasan Samuel C. Park Jr. Professor of Economics, Yale University China and India are the world's two most populous economies accounting for nearly 2-5 billion or 40% of the estimated 6.25 billion human beings of the world in 2002. Both countries enjoyed historically unprecedented average rate of growth of GDP at around 10% and 6% per year respectively during 1980-2000. (World Bank, 2002, Table I) Fewer than 10 of over 200 countries covered by the Bank exceeded India's growth rate and none exceeded China's. Without getting into the serious conceptual and data issues relating to levels of poverty and their time trends in both countries, let me cite Angus Deaton's (2001) estimates: the ratio of India's population living below the national poverty line fell from 39% in 1987-88 to 25.3% in 1999-2000 in rural areas and from 22.8% to 12.5% in urban areas. Though not quite comparable to Deaton, according to Datt (1997, 1999), in 1977-78 the poverty ratio was 50.5% and 40.5% in rural and urban areas respectively. (Table 1A) Unlike India, where household survey based estimates are available from the 1950's, such estimates for China are relatively recent - official poverty lines and poverty headcounts going back to 1978 were first announced in 1994 superceding some earlier ad hoc estimates. If these official data are to be believed, rural poverty has been virtually eliminated, falling from 30.7% in 1979 to 9.5 in 1990 and to 4.6% in 1998 (Park and Wang, 2001). A World Bank estimate quoted by the same authors, on the other hand, put rural poverty at nearly four times, at 42.8% in 1990 and it fell to 24.2% in 1997. Although the levels of poverty differ substantially between official and World Bank estimates, the trend is similar - a halving of poverty between 1990 and 2000. (Table 1B) It is clear that both in China and India, poverty has been reduced substantially in the last two decades of the twentieth century when both experienced acceleration in their growth rates. One cannot of course jump from the strong association between acceleration in growth and poverty reduction and assert a causal link between the two. One has to go behind the association and explore the exogenous determinants of growth * Revised version of a presentation made at the Seminar on WTO Accession, Policy Reform and Poverty 1

and poverty, the possible mechanisms through which the growth enhancing factors could affect incomes of individuals and households in either direction and conclude whether the net effect was to reduce poverty in the aggregate. For example, the poor, certainly in India and perhaps less so in China, are largely rural and heavily dependant on agriculture, either as landless agricultural laborers or small and marginal farmers. In such a situation, growth that is largely driven by the expansion of urban non-agricultural activities could bypass the rural poor altogether, unless such growth either expands the demand for agricultural labor (through an expansion of the demand for domestic agricultural output) or alternatively, pulls such labor out of agriculture into more productive non-agricultural activities. More generally the effects of growth on poverty reduction could differ between sectors which experience growth, so that the same aggregate rate of growth, if it arises from growth of sectors with relatively low effects of growth on poverty reduction, would reduce aggregate poverty to a lesser extent than if it arose from the growth of sectors with high effects. Going beyond these two examples, as I point out in Srinivasan (2001), the three endogenous outcomes, growth, poverty and inequality are together determined by exogenous factors including the existence and functioning of institutions including most importantly the markets for goods, services, and particularly for labor and capital, domestic and external sectors policies pursued, endogenous behavioral responses to policies and opportunities of individuals, households and enterprises as well as any constraints on the responses such as on mobility of goods and factors. The relationships between the exogenous determinants and endogenous outcomes could, and often does, vary our time and space. Above all there could be significant leads and lags in time between changes in determinants and the changes in outcomes. Needless to say, shifting forces of political economy have to be brought into the analysis. This being the case, acceleration in growth could, in theory, be associated with a decrease or an increase in poverty at particular periods of time or in some countries. But the relevant issue is whether; empirically, growth and poverty reduction went together in most places and most of the time. In fact, this is the case in the last two decades in many countries including China and India. Reduction in China, Beijing, China 28-29 June 2002, sponsored by the World Bank. 2

It is worth recalling a bit of history. Maddison's (2002) analysis suggests that China and India had the same real per capita income in 1870 (Table 2). But by 1950, when the Communist regime took over, China's per capita income had declined by 17% while India's had increased by 16%. It took nearly two and a half decades, that is, from 1950 to 1973, for China to recover the lost ground with double India's rate of growth of per capita income. It is reasonable to presume that China and India again were roughly at the same level of per capita income in 1980, two years after Deng Xiao Ping abandoned the Maoist economic strategy that led to the death of 30 millions or more and initiated systemic reforms. India's liberalization began in the 1980s but systemic reforms came only after the macroeconomic crisis of 1991. However, although both economics experienced acceleration in growth during 1980-2000 compared to the previous three decades (Table 3), given China's slower rate of growth of population, China's average growth rate of per capita income, at nearly 9% per year, far exceeded India's 4% per year, so that China's per capita income was nearly 70% higher than India's by 2000. Official data for China suggest that rural poverty declined by 85% between 1978 and 1998, while in India it declined by somewhat less than 50% between 1997-98 and 1998-2000(Tables 1A and 1B). These differences in the rate of decline seem consistent with faster growth in China's per capita income. However, given the serious problem with income and poverty data for both countries, particularly for China, one should not over interpret these trends. China and India pursued similar state-directed and state-controlled industrialization strategies with emphasis on heavy industry until their recent reforms. However in China, state control was direct and total: agriculture was collectivized, almost all industry was state-owned and most services were supplied by the state. India had a mixed economy with agriculture, all of small scale and a significant part of large scale industries being in the private sector. Although China grew faster than India before reforms, most of the difference is attributed to China's greater savings and investment rates. In fact Maddison (1998) estimates that total factor productivity declined at a rate of 0.78% per year in the pre reform period of 1952-78. It is most likely that the differences in the reform and growth processes of the two countries also contributed to the differences in growth rates and their impact on poverty outcomes. Thus the answer to the first question of the organizers is that the Chinese growth was faster and more pro-poor. Not only China 3

continued to save and invest a far higher proportion of its GDP than India, its integration with the world economy became far deeper. Its share of foreign trade goods in GDP, albeit an imperfect proxy for global integration, rose from approximately 13% in 1980 to nearly 44% in 2000. In India, the share fluctuated around an average of 12% until the opening of the 1990's and has since risen to 20%. Another aspect of global integration, namely, influx of foreign direct investment (FDI) also showed similar differences: the ratio of FDI to GDP in China grew from virtually nothing, when the reforms began in 1978, to 4.3% in 2000. In India, even after a decade of reforms the ratio is only 0.6%. (Table 4) The sequencing of reforms was also somewhat different in the two countries. China reformed its agriculture first by abolishing collectives, introducing the household responsibility system, and reducing mandatory deliveries of output to the state by farmers and thereby enabling farmers to produce for the market. India's agriculture, while always in the private sector, was insulated from world markets, riddled with government interventions the domestic market for agricultural inputs and outputs, whose net effect was to disprotect agriculture. Indian reform process is still to be extended to agriculture. Clearly, the fact that China reformed agriculture first and achieved spectacular results for several years not only provided credibility to its reform process, but also increased incomes of the poorer segments of the Chinese economy. In India, agriculture in particular, and the rural economy in general, are yet to be reformed systemically. Until it happens not much of acceleration in the rate reduction of rural poverty can be expected. Although India and China reformed their external sector by reducing tariff and non-tariff barriers, as noted earlier, China's opening went much deeper. In part this was because, while opening the special and coastal economic zones for foreign investment, China in effect allowed foreign investors 100% ownership, freedom to hire and fire workers and provided them with an excellent infrastructure. In all these respects India lagged behind. Further, India's reservation (until very recently) of labor-intensive products such as garments, leather products and others to the small-scale industry prevented the full exploitation of opportunities from its opening. China increased its share of world exports of labor incentive products, while India struggled to maintain its share and in fact lost its share in some products. India's shallower 4

integration and failure due to lack of domestic policy reform to avail of the opportunities in the world market limited not only the growth enhancing impact of trade reform, but also more importantly, its poverty reducing effect. In at least two other respects, Chinese and Indian reforms differed significantly, the differences favoring China both with respect to growth and with respect to poverty alleviation. The first is in their approach to the reform of state owned enterprises (SOEs). The share of investment in SOEs continues to be high (about 30% in India and two-thirds in China in 2000) in both economies and employment in SOEs has not fallen significantly in spite of the fall in their share of total output. These similarities notwithstanding, there is no Indian counterpart to China's dynamic township and village enterprises, which by all accounts were laborintensive and provided employment opportunities to the poor. The second area in which India lagged and continues to lag behind China is in the availability of reliable and affordable infrastructure, particularly power. While China has succeeded in attracting foreign investment into this vital sector, India has failed to do so. Clearly infrastructural restraints inhibit growth directly and the growth effects of poverty indirectly. There is some evidence that in the post-reform era, regional disparities have widened in both countries. To a certain extent this is natural: those regions (and individuals) which are better placed initially to take advantage of the opportunities opened up by reforms or for that matter by any other factor such as, for example, the information-technology revolution, are likely to grow faster (and richer). For example, India's phenomenal success in software is still confined to a few cities in the south and west. The real issue is not one of increasing regional disparities, but of whether the socio-economic system would enable the initially disadvantaged regions and individuals to catch up. If it does not, the social and political consequences could be serious and could lead to secessionist threats. Trends in growth of GDP and poverty are depicted in Figures 1-4. It is seen from Figure 1 that there was a perceptible acceleration in growth of GDP after 1980 or so. There is evidence of possibly rising regional disparities in the trends in poverty in India between rural and urban areas and differences between two groups of states (Figures 2-4). From Figure 2 it is seen that, first of all, from 1951-52 until 1977-78 rural 5

and urban poverty rates in India fluctuated with no discernible trend and this period largely overlaps the three decades 1950-80 of the infamous "Hindu" rate of growth of 3.5% per year on the average. There is acceleration in the rate of growth and the start of a downward trend in poverty ratio, in the period after 1977-78. From Figure 3, it is evident that the trends in rural and urban poverty were very similar until 1990 and then they diverge, with urban poverty continuing to fall while rural poverty almost stagnates. Finally, Figure 4 shows that until 1990-91 the trends in rural poverty were similar between group 1 (Andhra Pradesh, Gujarat, Karnataka, Kerala, Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu and West Bengal) and group 2 (Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa, Rajasthan and Uttar Pradesh) states, but after the crisis and reform year of 1991-92, poverty declines in group 1 states and stagnates in group 2 states. These figures support the following conclusions: (i) until growth rate accelerated after 1980 there was no discernible decline in poverty (ii) in the post-reform period after 1991, the slower decline, if not stagnation altogether, of rural poverty is consistent with the fact that the reform process is yet to be extended to rural areas (iii) the faster decline in rural poverty in group 1 states after the crisis and reform year of1991-92 is consistent with the fact that these states were better endowed with better infrastructure and above all in human capital as measured by higher literacy (particularly of females) rates, lower total fertility rates, and lower infant mortality rates. Whether widening disparities are temporary and would be reversed or permanent and entrenched is an interesting issue. At the aggregate level, one approach to this issue is to ask: do regions with initially different levels of income nonetheless converge over time to the same level and rate of growth per capita income in the long run? This is the so-called "absolute" convergence hypothesis. It is to be contrasted with the "conditional" convergence hypothesis, which suggests each region converges to its own long run level and growth of per capita income. There is a growing literature on testing the hypotheses of absolute and conditional convergence in both countries. Demurger et al. (2001) and Dayal-Gulati and Husain (2000) find support only for conditional convergence in China. In India, Cashin and Sahay (1996, 1997) found evidence of absolute convergence. Rao and Sen (1997) suggest that in fact findings of Cashin and Sahay should be interpreted as supporting conditional convergence. Clearly, finding of conditional convergence, since it is consistent with regions growing at different rates in the long run, could mean growing disparities 6

across regions. In India there is evidence of growing disparities between southern and Western coastal states on the one hand, and the interior and northern states on the other growth rates, with the former growing faster than the latter in the post reform era. Coupled with the fact that the incidence of poverty is higher, and the share of country's population larger, in the latter states, there has been legitimate concern that if sustained in the future, these growth disparities will threaten the stability of India's federal democracy. Let me conclude with a brief comment about areas for further research. First of all, as I argued earlier, the interaction between growth and poverty is complex involving exogenous determinants relating to institutions, public policies and private responses. Far too little is known at a disaggregated level of the mechanisms that are involved. Part of the problem is the lack of reliable data at appropriate levels of disaggregation. For example, India has recently enacted amendments to its constitution devolving power, if not resources, to local levels of government. Other than some tantalizing bits of data and analysis, not enough is known about, first whether or not such devolution will enhance the voice of the poor in making decisions that affect their welfare and thus enhance the potential for poverty reduction and second, whether, because of possible differences in the resources and capability of local level institutions, regional disparities would widen. To take another example, in India in the post reform era the service sector has grown faster than other sectors did and its share in GDP has grown. This sector is diverse, consisting of the poor and unskilled involved in household services at one end of the spectrum, to the high skilled doctors, lawyers and software technicians at the other end. It would be very illuminating to know whether the growth of the service sector has largely come from its poorer end and hence contributed to poverty reduction. Alas, the data are poor and there is virtually no analysis of the available poor data from this perspective. At least in India there have always been, and still are, an enormous number of schemes ostensibly aimed at poverty alleviation. While they absorbed significant amount of resources, their aggregate effect in reducing poverty was negligible until the 1980s when growth began to accelerate. Interestingly, although India received only a modest external assistance relative to its population and GDP, it received more from multilateral and bilateral resources, much of it on concessional terms, during 1950-80 when there was slow growth and virtually no reduction in poverty. This raises an interesting and important question: are myriad national 7

policy interventions aimed at the poor and clever mechanisms for allocation of lending by international financial institutions based on the so called Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers process likely to make much of a difference to trends in poverty compared to the alternative of creating an economic and political framework that provides an enabling and stable environment in which individuals, households and enterprises decide what is in their best interests, while facing increasing opportunities from rapid and sustained growth to better themselves. I suspect not - but to make a convincing case whether this is so would require lots more research than is available. REFERENCES Cashin, P. and R. Saha (1996), "Internal Migration, Centre-State Grants and Economic Growth in States of India," IMF Staff Paper, 43, 123-71. ---. (1997), A Reply to Rao and Sen, IMF Staff Papers, 44: 289-91. Datt, G. (1997), "Poverty In India: An Update", International Food Policy Research Institute (Processed) Datt, G. (1999), "Has Poverty In India Declined Since The Economic Reforms", World Bank (Processed) Dayal-Gulati and A. Hussain (2000). Centripetal Forces in China s Economic Take-Off, Working Paper WP/00/86 (revised), Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Deaton, A. (2001). Computing Prices and Poverty Rates in India, 1999-2000, Research Program in Development Studies, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University, processed. Demurger, S., J. Sachs, W. Woo, S. Bao, G. Change and A. Mellinger (2001). Economic Geography and Regional Growth in China, paper presented at the Asian Economic Panel, Cambridge, MA, 26-27 April 2001, processed. Ministry of Finance (2002), Economic Survey 2001-2002, New Delhi, Government of India Press. Maddison, A. (1998). Chinese Economic Performance in the Long-Run, Paris: OECD Development Center. Maddison, A. (2002), Growth and Interaction in the World Economy: The West and the Rest over the Past Millennium, (forthcoming) Ministry of Finance (2002), Economic Survey, 2001-2002, New Delhi: Government of India Park, A and S. Wang (2001), "China's Poverty Statistics" China Economic Review, 12, 384-395 Rao, M. G. and K. Sen (1997), "Internal Migration, Centre-State Grants, and Economic Growth in States of India," IMF Staff Papers, 44, 283-89. 8

Srinivasan, T. N. (1989), Growth and Poverty Alleviation: Lessons from Development Experience, published in French with the title Croissance et allégement de la pauvreté: les leçons tirées de l expérience du développement in Revue d économic du développement, 1-2/2001, 115-168 World Bank (2002), World Development Indicators, Washington D. C., World Bank ---. (2000), India-Policies to Reduce Poverty and Accelerate sustainable Development, Report 19271, Washington D.C., World Bank WTO (2001). International Trade Statistics, 2001, Geneva: World Trade Organization. 9

TABLE 1A A: INDIA RURAL URBAN OFFICIAL* DEATON OFFICIAL* DEATON AUG 51 - NOV 52 47.37 35.46 SEP 61 - JUL 62 47.20 43.55 JUL 70 - JUN 71 54.84 44.98 JUL 77 - JUN 78 50.50 40.50 JUL 87 - JUN 88 39.0 39.0 39.1 22.8 JUL 93 - JUN 94 37.1 32.9 30.2 18.1 JUL 99 - JUN 2000 27.0 25.3 23.5 9.5 * DATA FOR YEAR PRIOR TO 1987-88 ARE FROM DATT (1997,1999) AND FOR OTHER YEARS ARE FROM DEATON (2001). SOURCES: DATT, G. (1997, 1999). DEATON, A. (2001). 10

TABLE 1B B: CHINA RURAL CHINA 1978 1990 1997 1998 (1) OFFICIAL 30.7 9.5 5.4 4.6 (2) WORLD BANK -- 42.8 24.2 -- SOURCE: PARK, A. AND S. WANG (2001). 11

TABLE 2 GDP PER CAPITA (1990 INTERNATIONAL DOLLARS): 1700-1998 1700 1820 1870 1913 1950 1973 1998 CHINA 600 600 530 552 439 839 3117 INDIA 550 533 533 673 619 853 1746 SOURCE; MADDISON (2002) 12

TABLE 3 GDP GROWTH 1950-1980 1980-1990 1990-2000 CHINA 4.40* 10.1 10.3 INDIA 3.75** 5.8 6.0 SOURCE: WORLD BANK (2002), FOR 1980-1990 AND 1990-2000 * MADDISON (1998), TABLE 3.10 ** AUTHOR'S ESTIMATE 13

TABLE 4 A. TRADE IN GOODS (AS % OF GDP) FDI (AS % OF GDP) 1990 2000 1990 2000 CHINA 32.9 43.9 1.2 4.3 INDIA 13.1 20.3 0.0 0.6 SOURCE: WORLD BANK (2002), TABLE 6.1 B. SHARE IN WORLD EXPORTS 1948 1953 1983 2000 CHINA 0.9 1.2 1.2 4.0 INDIA 2.2 1.3 1.3 0.7 SOURCE: WTO(2001),TABLE II.2 14

Figure 1: Rate of Growth of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) at factor cost 12.0 10.0 GDP at factor cost (percent) 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 0.0-2.0-4.0-6.0 1951-52 1953-54 1955-56 1957-58 1959-60 1961-62 1963-64 1965-66 1967-68 1969-70 1971-72 1973-74 1975-76 1977-78 Year 1979-80 1981-82 1983-84 1985-86 1987-88 1989-90 1991-92 1993-94 1995-96 1997-98 1999-00 2001-2002A Source: Ministry of Finance (2002), Appendix Table 1.3 15

Figure 2: Indian Poverty from 1951-2000 Headcount Index 70 60 50 40 30 20 Rural Urban 10 0 Aug 51-Nov 52 May 53 - Sep 53 May 55 - Nov 55 Mar 57 - Aug 57 Jul 59 - Jun 60 Feb 63 - Jan 64 Jul 66 - Jun 67 Jul 69 - Jun 70 Oct 73 - Jun 74 Survey Period Jul 86 - Jun 87 Jul 89 - Jun 90 Jan 92 - Dec 92 Jul 95 - Jun 96 Source: World Bank (2000) 16

17

18