ESTIMATING LIQUIDITY PREMIA IN THE SPANISH GOVERNMENT SECURITIES MARKET



Similar documents
Investing in corporate bonds?

Investing in corporate bonds?

How To Get A Loan From A Bank For Free

Quality evaluation of the model-based forecasts of implied volatility index

OpenGamma Documentation Bond Pricing

PERFORMANCE METRICS FOR THE IT SERVICES PORTFOLIO

Project Evaluation Roadmap. Capital Budgeting Process. Capital Expenditure. Major Cash Flow Components. Cash Flows... COMM2501 Financial Management

Evaluating Inventory Management Performance: a Preliminary Desk-Simulation Study Based on IOC Model

ADJUSTING FOR QUALITY CHANGE

Use of extrapolation to forecast the working capital in the mechanical engineering companies

Part C. Property and Casualty Insurance Companies

Extended-Horizon Analysis of Pressure Sensitivities for Leak Detection in Water Distribution Networks: Application to the Barcelona Network

CRM FACTORS ASSESSMENT USING ANALYTIC HIERARCHY PROCESS

Construction Economics & Finance. Module 3 Lecture-1

The United States was in the midst of a

SOME APPLICATIONS OF FORECASTING Prof. Thomas B. Fomby Department of Economics Southern Methodist University May 2008

Online Bagging and Boosting

Insurance Spirals and the Lloyd s Market

Research Article Performance Evaluation of Human Resource Outsourcing in Food Processing Enterprises

This paper studies a rental firm that offers reusable products to price- and quality-of-service sensitive

Don t Run With Your Retirement Money

Software Quality Characteristics Tested For Mobile Application Development

A WISER Guide. Financial Steps for Caregivers: What You Need to Know About Money and Retirement

Fuzzy Sets in HR Management

International Journal of Management & Information Systems First Quarter 2012 Volume 16, Number 1

The Stock Market and the Financing of Corporate Growth in Africa: The Case of Ghana

Online Appendix I: A Model of Household Bargaining with Violence. In this appendix I develop a simple model of household bargaining that

An Improved Decision-making Model of Human Resource Outsourcing Based on Internet Collaboration

Invention of NFV Technique and Its Relationship with NPV

and virtually all 4-year-olds are now enrolled in education.

No. 2004/12. Daniel Schmidt

Factor Model. Arbitrage Pricing Theory. Systematic Versus Non-Systematic Risk. Intuitive Argument

Endogenous Credit-Card Acceptance in a Model of Precautionary Demand for Money

THE INFORMATION IN THE TERM STRUCTURE OF GERMAN INTEREST RATES

The Effects of Child Care Provision in Mexico

Applying Multiple Neural Networks on Large Scale Data

COMBINING CRASH RECORDER AND PAIRED COMPARISON TECHNIQUE: INJURY RISK FUNCTIONS IN FRONTAL AND REAR IMPACTS WITH SPECIAL REFERENCE TO NECK INJURIES

An Innovate Dynamic Load Balancing Algorithm Based on Task

Is Pay-as-You-Drive Insurance a Better Way to Reduce Gasoline than Gasoline Taxes?

Study on the development of statistical data on the European security technological and industrial base

The Benefit of SMT in the Multi-Core Era: Flexibility towards Degrees of Thread-Level Parallelism

( C) CLASS 10. TEMPERATURE AND ATOMS

Privacy, Exposure and Price Discrimination

Enrolment into Higher Education and Changes in Repayment Obligations of Student Aid Microeconometric Evidence for Germany

TIME VALUE OF MONEY PROBLEMS CHAPTERS THREE TO TEN

Calculation Method for evaluating Solar Assisted Heat Pump Systems in SAP July 2013

An Approach to Combating Free-riding in Peer-to-Peer Networks

DISCUSSION PAPER. Is Pay-As-You-Drive Insurance a Better Way to Reduce Gasoline than Gasoline Taxes? Ian W.H. Parry. April 2005 RFF DP 05-15

Method of supply chain optimization in E-commerce

Pure Bending Determination of Stress-Strain Curves for an Aluminum Alloy

Image restoration for a rectangular poor-pixels detector

Standards and Protocols for the Collection and Dissemination of Graduating Student Initial Career Outcomes Information For Undergraduates

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE WELFARE EFFECTS OF PUBLIC DRUG INSURANCE. Darius Lakdawalla Neeraj Sood

Machine Learning Applications in Grid Computing

Analyzing Spatiotemporal Characteristics of Education Network Traffic with Flexible Multiscale Entropy

Dynamic Placement for Clustered Web Applications

How To Find Out What Happens When A Company Is Integrated

Adaptive Modulation and Coding for Unmanned Aerial Vehicle (UAV) Radio Channel

Note on a generalized wage rigidity result. Abstract

Dynamic Interaction among Mutual Fund Flows, Stock Market Return and Volatility

Earnings and Community College Field of Study Choice in Canada

Products vs. Advertising: Media Competition and the. Relative Source of Firm Profits

SAMPLING METHODS LEARNING OBJECTIVES

Liquidity in U.S. Treasury spot and futures markets

A Strategic Approach to Software Protection U

Markov Models and Their Use for Calculations of Important Traffic Parameters of Contact Center

A short-term, pattern-based model for water-demand forecasting

Halloween Costume Ideas for the Wii Game

Searching strategy for multi-target discovery in wireless networks

The Velocities of Gas Molecules

Managing Complex Network Operation with Predictive Analytics

Pay-As-You-Drive (PAYD): A case study into the safety and accessibility effects of PAYD strategies

The impact of demographic change on tourism and conclusions for tourism policy

HW 2. Q v. kt Step 1: Calculate N using one of two equivalent methods. Problem 4.2. a. To Find:

Physics 211: Lab Oscillations. Simple Harmonic Motion.

Study on the development of statistical data on the European security technological and industrial base

Leak detection in open water channels

Generating Certification Authority Authenticated Public Keys in Ad Hoc Networks

Work Travel and Decision Probling in the Network Marketing World

PREDICTION OF POSSIBLE CONGESTIONS IN SLA CREATION PROCESS

The AGA Evaluating Model of Customer Loyalty Based on E-commerce Environment

Exercise 4 INVESTIGATION OF THE ONE-DEGREE-OF-FREEDOM SYSTEM

The Research of Measuring Approach and Energy Efficiency for Hadoop Periodic Jobs

An improved TF-IDF approach for text classification *

Audio Engineering Society. Convention Paper. Presented at the 119th Convention 2005 October 7 10 New York, New York USA

Position Auctions and Non-uniform Conversion Rates

Journal of International Economics

Media Adaptation Framework in Biofeedback System for Stroke Patient Rehabilitation

A magnetic Rotor to convert vacuum-energy into mechanical energy

A Study on the Chain Restaurants Dynamic Negotiation Games of the Optimization of Joint Procurement of Food Materials

Modeling Cooperative Gene Regulation Using Fast Orthogonal Search

Energy Proportionality for Disk Storage Using Replication

Reliability Constrained Packet-sizing for Linear Multi-hop Wireless Networks

6. Time (or Space) Series Analysis

Partitioned Elias-Fano Indexes

Demand estimation and market definition. for broadband internet services 1

CLOSED-LOOP SUPPLY CHAIN NETWORK OPTIMIZATION FOR HONG KONG CARTRIDGE RECYCLING INDUSTRY

Roland Berger Strategy Consultants. content. Fresh thinking for decision makers

Endogenous Market Structure and the Cooperative Firm

Presentation Safety Legislation and Standards

Transcription:

ESTIMATING LIQUIDITY PREMIA IN THE SPANISH GOVERNMENT SECURITIES MARKET Francisco Alonso, Roberto Blanco, Ana del Río and Alicia Sanchis Banco de España Banco de España Servicio de Estudios Docuento de Trabajo n.º 0017

ESTIMATING LIQUIDITY PREMIA IN THE SPANISH GOVERNMENT SECURITIES MARKET * Francisco Alonso Roberto Blanco Ana del Río Alicia Sanchis * We wish to thank Juan Ayuso, Cleente Fernández, Víctor García-Vaquero, José Raón Martínez, Alfredo Martínez, Jorge Martínez, Soledad Núñez, Oreste Tristani, Christian Upper and participants in the BIS Workshop on Market Liquidity and in the seinar at Banco de España for helpful coents and suggestions.

Abstract This paper investigates the presence of liquidity preia in the relative pricing of assets traded on the Spanish governent securities arket. First, we propose a classification of bonds into four different categories based on their degree of liquidity. Second, we estiate liquidity preia, including liquidity paraeters in the estiation of the zero-coupon yield curve. The results suggest the existence of a liquidity preiu for post-benchark bonds (both strippable and non-strippable). The size of this preiu is relatively sall. In the case of pre-benchark bonds, the lack of liquidity does not see to be priced. We also show that these pricing discrepancies are robust to the ipact of taxes on bonds. Key words: liquidity preiu, bid-ask spread, yield curve, benchark. JEL classification: G12. BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 1

1. INTRODUCTION The liquidity of an asset is generally understood as the ease of its conversion into oney 1. In practice, the conversion of an asset into oney involves certain costs: search costs, delays, broker s coissions, etc. The higher these costs the lower the degree of liquidity of the asset. In ost financial arkets there is a class of agents known as arket akers whose function is to provide liquidity. These agents are ready to buy and sell securities up to a axiu aount and ake their profit on the difference between the bid and ask prices. The latter are the prices at which the other arket participants can execute surely and iediately sell and buy transactions, respectively. As a consequence, the bid-ask spread reflects the cost incurred by a typical investor to unwind an asset position, which is part of the cost of converting an asset into oney. This is why the bid-ask spread is one of the ost widely used easures of liquidity. According to arket icrostructure odels, the bid-ask spread ay reflect three different costs faced by arket akers: asyetric inforation costs, inventory costs, and orderprocessing costs. However, as Gravelle (BIS, 1999) points out, asyetric inforation costs should not be very significant in the case of governent securities (GS). This iplies that liquidity in GS arkets should be closely linked to the arket-akers inventory risk and order-processing costs which ultiately depend on the level of risk of the asset (duration) and the frequency with which a transaction will be executed (turnover). Soeties liquidity is easured by indicators of arket activity (turnover, turnover ratio, benchark status, age). Because investors value asset liquidity we can expect liquidity and differences in liquidity to be priced. In other words, investors ay require a liquidity preiu for holding illiquid assets in order to copensate the for bearing higher transaction costs. In the literature, there are soe papers that test for the existence of liquidity preia in securities arkets. The bulk of this literature focuses on equity arkets 2, whereas there are only a few papers that focus on debt arkets, ost of the using US arket data. Papers that test for the existence of a liquidity preiu in GS arkets have followed a nuber of approaches. For exaple, in Aihud and Mendelson (1991), Kaara (1994) and Garbade (1996) the liquidity preiu is only estiated for short-ter US Treasuries. They copare the yield of notes with that of bills with the sae ter to aturity. Since both instruents are identical, except for the fact that notes are ore actively traded, yield differences are attributed to differences in liquidity. The liquidity preia in these papers are 1 See Market liquidity: Research Findings and Selected Policy Iplications in BIS (1999) for the various diensions of liquidity. 2 See, for exaple Aihud and Mendelson (1986,1989). 2 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017

found to be high and significant. Elton and Green (1998) use volue as a proxy for liquidity and introduce it as an explanatory variable when fitting a zero-coupon curve to the US arket. They find that the coefficient of this variable is significant for ost of the days considered, although the iplied liquidity preiu is very sall. Warga (1992) proxies liquidity by indicating whether or not an issue is on-the-run (the ost recently issued security of a particular aturity). He copares the ex-post onthly excess return over the 30-day Treasury bill rate for two series of constant duration portfolios ade up of securities traded on the US arket, one containing on-the-run bonds and the other containing the other available bonds. Warga (1992) finds that portfolios containing on-the-run bonds exhibit a lower return and interprets this as evidence of a liquidity preiu. In other papers, like Shen and Starr (1998), liquidity is proxied by the bid-ask spread. In that paper the ter preiu, proxied by the excess ex-post returns of the six-onth US T-bill over the 3-onth bill, is estiated and it is found that the bid-ask spread accounts for a substantial portion of this preiu. The estiation of liquidity preia in GS arkets is iportant because, aong other reasons, it ight iprove the inforation content of prices. For exaple, the existence of liquidity preia ay distort the inforation extracted fro the estiated ter structure or the estiates of iplied inflation expectations obtained by coparing fixed-coupon and inflation linked bonds. Against this background, the ain goal of this paper is to investigate whether there is a liquidity preiu in the relative pricing of assets traded on the Spanish GS arket. To do this, we first characterise the relative liquidity of bonds. The strippability of the asset and its benchark status appear to be two relevant deterinants of securities liquidity within each aturity zone. Given this property, we consider four categories of bonds that take into account these eleents. The categories are non-strippable bonds and pre-benchark (bonds that will have the benchark status in the future), benchark and post-benchark (bonds that had the benchark status in the past) strippable bonds. We find that there are iportant liquidity differences aong these categories of bonds according to different easures of liquidity based on activity easures and bid-ask spreads. Benchark bonds are the ost liquid, followed by strippable non-benchark bonds. And finally non-strippable bonds appear to be very illiquid. In the second part of the paper we estiate relative liquidity preia. A traditional approach is to calculate the yield spread between non-benchark and benchark bonds. However, this estiation of the liquidity preia does not control for risk and tax factors derived fro the different cash flow structures of bonds. Our ethodology follows that of Elton and Green (1998) which is based on the estiation of the ter structure of interest rates. This approach affords us better control over effects related to the cash-flow structure of bonds. Specifically, we incorporate liquidity effects in the estiation of the zero-coupon yield curve BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 3

introducing duy variables for the different categories of bonds. The results suggest the existence of a liquidity preiu for post-benchark bonds (both strippable and nonstrippable). The size of this preiu is relatively sall. In the case of pre-benchark bonds, the lack of liquidity does not see to be priced. In fact, in soe periods we even find evidence of a negative preiu over benchark issues for pre-benchark bonds. We also show that these pricing discrepancies are robust to the ipact of taxes on bonds. Thus, these results point to the existence of a liquidity preiu in the relative pricing of bonds traded on the Spanish GS arket, although its size sees relatively sall. The reainder of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 describes the structure of the Spanish GS arket. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 proposes a classification of bonds which tries to identify bonds with a different degree of liquidity. Section 5 estiates liquidity preia. And, finally, Section 6 suarises the ain conclusions. 2. STRUCTURE OF THE SPANISH GOVERNMENT SECURITIES MARKET Two types of instruent are issued by the Spanish Treasury: Letras del Tesoro (Treasury bills), which are short-ter securities issued at a discount, and Bonos y Obligaciones del Estado (governent bonds) which are ediu and long-ter securities with annual coupon payents. Both types of instruents are represented by book entries and issued via regular copetitive auctions. Bills are issued at 6-, 12- and 18-onth aturities, whereas bonds are issued at 3-, 5-, 10-, 15- and 30-year aturities. Auctions take place on a onthly basis, except for 15-year and 30-year issues, which are auctioned every two onths, and 12- and 18-onth issues, which are auctioned fortnightly. In the case of ediu and long-ter securities, issues are reopened over several consecutive auctions until the outstanding aount reaches a certain level. The securities allocated at such auctions have identical noinal coupon and interest payent and redeption dates. Since July 1997, the Spanish Treasury has been issuing strippable bonds. They enjoy a ore favourable tax treatent for payers of the corporate incoe tax, because the latter are not subject to withholding tax on coupon payents. These securities can be stripped during their life into n+1 zero-coupon assets, where n stands for the nuber of reaining coupon payents, arising fro the cash flow generated by the bond s coupons and the principal. The stripping process is conducted by a type of arket participant known as arket akers, who assue a nuber of coitents subject to annual review. They are also allowed to perfor the reverse process (reconstitution). All outstanding bonds issued before July 1997 are non-strippable and do not enjoy the favourable tax treatent of strippable bonds. 4 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017

Secondary arket trades are conducted through three systes, the first two being reserved for arket ebers, while the third is for transactions between arket ebers and their clients. In the first syste (known as the blind arket ) trading is electronically conducted without knowledge of the counterparty s identity. Only those arket ebers who coply with certain requireents and assue a nuber of coitents can participate in this arket segent. For instance, they are obliged to quote during at least 60% of the tie of each session the five issues of bonds with benchark status, subject to a axiu bid-ask spread. Blind arket trades can only be outright transactions, whether spot or forward. The second trading syste (known as the second tier ) channels all the reaining transactions between arket ebers. Trading is conducted directly between traders or through brokers. Soe brokers post indicative bid and ask prices on electronic arket inforation systes such as Reuters and Blooberg. In this arket segent, participants can trade outright (in spot or forward transactions) or enter into repos. Two types of repo transaction are allowed: ordinary repos and blocked repos, the difference being that under the second type the buyer cannot transact freely with the securities purchased, regardless of the agreed buy-back date. Clearing and settleent of GS transactions is carried out by the Central de Anotaciones en Cuenta (Book-Entry Syste). Each arket eber holds an account in this syste. Individuals or institutions who are not ebers have to channel transactions through a Managing Institution. The procedure used is one of delivery versus payent and transactions are settled three business days later. In addition to the secondary arket, there is a futures and options arket (MEFF RF) where the underlying assets are Spanish GS. At present traded contracts include only 10-year futures and options. Table 1 provides 1999 turnover figures for the different arket segents and for the different types of transaction on the Spanish GS arket. Repos are the type of transaction with the highest activity, which is ainly concentrated in the very short-ter (ainly overnight), followed by outright spot purchases. By contrast, trading activity through forward, futures, and options transactions, is ore liited. Table 2 gives a breakdown of the holders of Spanish GS at end-1999. Financial institutions own a very large proportion of the outstanding aount (61.2% for bonds and 91.3% for bills). Non-residents also have a significant share of the arket in the case of bonds (32%). By contrast, the share of non-financial corporations and households is very low. BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 5

3. DATA In this paper we use daily data on prices (quoted and traded), outstanding aounts, and trading activity (trading volue and nuber of trades) for the Spanish GS arket fro January 1999 to April 2000. This inforation is copiled for 34 bonds 3, 24 of the being outstanding throughout the saple period (see Table 3 for a description of the issues). For the short-ter, the data refer to Treasury bills and repo transactions. The price data include the following: i) Daily ean prices traded in the blind and second-tier arkets. This inforation was provided by the Central de Anotaciones of the Banco de España ii) Daily quoted bid and ask prices obtained fro two sources: a) Reuters-BDE: since August 1998 the Banco de España Research Departent has been building a database fro prices posted by Reuters at 2 p.. It includes best quoted bid and ask prices for long and short-ter issues; and bid and ask rates for repo transactions. Daily bid and ask prices are calculated using the quotations of four brokers: three 4 of the are pre-deterined and the fourth is the one who traded ost recently. Fro these quotations, the highest bid and the lowest ask prices are selected for each issue. If the bid price is higher than the ask 5, then prices are sequentially reoved until a non-negative spread is obtained. b) Blooberg: this agency provides daily quoted prices calculated as the average bid and ask quotations at the close (deterined by Blooberg to be about 5 p..). In this case, by construction, the bid-ask spread is always positive. Blooberg also provides bid and ask rates for a wide range of repo transactions. In this paper we will use quoted prices instead of traded prices to test for liquidity effects. This decision is driven by the ethodology we use, consisting of the daily estiation of a zero-coupon yield curve. The non-conteporaneity?? proble of traded prices together with the lack of prices for bonds that are not traded on a particular day would lead to soe iportant errors in the estiation. However, it has to be stressed that quoted prices are not fir but indicative, and therefore they ay not reflect actual prices. For that reason we also perfor a robust test on the accuracy of these prices by coparing the to actual traded 3 Strips are not included. The percentage of stripped bonds is very low in the Spanish arket. 4 Four in the case of short-ter instruents. 5 In the inforation provided by Reuters it is not uncoon to find negative bid-ask spreads, possibly due to the lack of conteporaneity in quotations. 6 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017

prices. Regarding the inforation on bid-ask spreads, it is worth noting that we have two indicators coputed using two different ethodologies. On one hand, the Reuters-BDE spread is the best proxy for arket spread, but it eploys non-conteporaneous quotations that ay introduce noise and ay bias downwards the size of the spread. On the other hand, the Blooberg spread cannot be interpreted as the arket spread, but its ain advantage is that it reduces non-conteporaneity probles due to the fact that quotes are averaged. Finally, trading activity (nuber of trades and trading volue) is provided by the Central de Anotaciones of the Banco de España and refers only to transactions between arket ebers, in both the blind and the second-tier arket. 4. CLASSIFYING BONDS BY THEIR RELATIVE DEGREE OF LIQUIDITY 4.1. A classification of bonds according to their life cycle and tax treatent In this section we propose a classification of bonds that tries to identify a nuber of groups of bonds with different degrees of liquidity. It is iportant to stress that the approach we follow in this paper of classifying bonds by their relative liquidity is not intended to copare liquidity across different aturity zones but within the. This decision is justified by the ethodology we use in the next section to estiate liquidity preia, which consists of fitting a zero-coupon yield curve. With this ethodology it would be very difficult to separate ter and liquidity effects if we used a classification of liquidity across different aturities. Our classification takes into account two eleents of an issue: its stage of the life cycle and its strippability (whether or not the issue is strippable). We consider the stage of life because, in general, trading activity and, consequently, liquidity is related to this. It is well known that in GS arkets trading activity tends to be concentrated in a sall group of securities known as benchark issues. The prices of these instruents are used to extract inforation for acroeconoic analysis and pricing purposes. In the Spanish GS arket there are five benchark issues corresponding to 3-, 5-, 10-, 15- and 30-year aturities. Since all issued bonds becoe benchark issues, the life cycle of bonds consists of three stages. In the first stage, the bond is initially issued and its outstanding volue is relatively sall, and hence its trading activity is very low and it does not have benchark status. Bonds in this stage will hereinafter be referred to as pre-benchark issues. New fungible auctions increase the outstanding aount, and trading activity also increases until benchark status is achieved and the issue becoes the ost liquid one for a particular aturity. Finally, in the third stage, the bond is replaced by a new benchark and its activity begins to decrease. Bonds in this stage will be referred to as post-benchark issues. BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 7

More specifically, our classification consists of four categories, naely: pre-benchark, benchark, post-benchark and non-strippable issues. The first three categories are only ade up of strippable bonds, whereas the last category includes all non-strippable bonds. We have decided to group all non-strippable bonds in one specific category for the following two reasons. First, in our saple, all non-strippable bonds are at a very advanced third stage of their life cycle, therefore they are very illiquid. And, second, they are subject to a less favourable tax treatent that could be reflected in a tax preiu. Over our saple period there was no official classification of benchark issues in Spain. As a consequence, the identification of the benchark issue ay be difficult during transition periods. The criterion we use in this paper considers that a new bond becoes the benchark issue when it has been traded ore than the old benchark for at least three consecutive days. Table 4 gives the dates on which a benchark bond changes according to this criterion, and copares the with those reported by Reuters and Blooberg. It can be observed that dates do not coincide for the different criteria, but differences between the rarely exceed one onth. Figure 1 shows the life cycle for all the strippable 10-year bonds of our saple. Over this period there are two changes of benchark, one in February 1999 when the 5.15% bond becoes the new benchark, and the other in October 1999, when the ost recently issued bond (4% with aturity at 31/1/10) acquires benchark status. This figure displays the evolution of trading activity, outstanding volue and bid-ask spread. It can be seen that the life cycle in trading activity appears also to be incorporated in the evolution of bid-ask spreads, suggesting a very different degree of liquidity of bonds depending on the stage of life they are at. Table 5 gives a descriptive analysis of previously defined bond categories over our saple period. Panel A shows the average nuber of issues for each category in the saple. The non-strippable category is the one with the highest nuber of issues (18.7 on average). At the other extree, only 2.6 bonds belong to the pre-benchark category on average. The post-benchark category includes an average of 4.4 issues. However, the nuber of bonds in this category increases throughout the saple period to reach 9 at the end. In panel C of Table 5 it can be seen that benchark issues account, on average, for alost 53% of the daily traded volue. Regarding non-strippable bonds, despite the high nuber of issues, they account for just 7% of daily traded volue (see panel C). Finally, the reaining 40% of the traded volue corresponds to strippable non-benchark bonds of which pre-benchark issues account for 15% and post-benchark issues for 25%. Looking at trading activity by aturity, a high concentration around the 10-year zone is observed, with approxiately 33% of the total arket activity. The 3- and 5-year aturities 8 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017

account for approxiately 25% and 23% respectively. And finally, the zones of 15- and 30- year residual aturity have the lowest activity, with approxiately 5% and 3% of total arket activity respectively. Regarding outstanding volue, panel B of Table 5 shows a very different distribution. In particular, a high concentration (ore than 50%) is observed in the 0-6 years zone. 4.2. Is this classification useful to identify groups of bonds with a different degree of liquidity? We now show to what extent the four categories we propose are useful to identify groups of bonds with a different degree of liquidity. To do this we copute soe liquidity easures for the different categories of bonds. Table 6 reports various easures of liquidity, all based on trading activity, with a breakdown by bond category and aturity. These easures are the nuber of trades, trading volue and turnover ratio. All these indicators are coputed per bond and, therefore, can be interpreted as liquidity easures. A feature shared by all the liquidity easures of Table 6 is the rearkable differences in liquidity between the various categories considered. When coparing liquidity within each aturity zone, benchark issues are the bonds with the greatest liquidity, followed by strippable non-benchark bonds (both pre-benchark 6 and post-benchark). Finally, non-strippable bonds are notable for their very scarce trading activity. When coparing liquidity aong aturity zones the ost liquid bonds are those with a residual aturity between 3 and 10 years. In this regard, it is worth noting that strippable non-benchark bonds are soeties even ore liquid than 15 and 30-year benchark issues. Figure 2 displays the bid-ask spread 7 as a function of the duration for the different categories of bonds. This indicator is used as an additional easure of liquidity. A siilar pattern to that reported for trading activity also appears here when coparing the liquidity of bonds within each aturity zone (proxied by duration), although now pre-benchark issues appear to be ore siilar, in ters of liquidity, to non-strippable bonds than to postbenchark strippable issues. 6 In fact, in the case of the turnover ratio, no significant differences are observed between pre-benchark and benchark issues. 7 For this analysis we use the Reuters-BDE database because it provides a spread easure ore closely linked to the concept of arket spread (see Section 3 for a description of this database and a coparison with the Blooberg data). BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 9

However, note that trading activity and the bid-ask spread would provide a very different ranking of bonds by liquidity if we did not control for tie to aturity or duration. As Figure 2 illustrates, the bid-ask spread is positively correlated with tie to aturity. This effect clearly doinates the previously reported pattern (benchark status of the bond). This relationship between spread and tie to aturity, which has also been identified in other GS arkets 8, can be explained theoretically by the arket akers inventory risk and order processing costs, which ultiately depend on the level of risk of the asset proxied by tie to aturity. Accordingly, a ranking of bonds using the bid-ask spread would classify short-ter securities as the ost liquid and long-ter issues as relatively illiquid. Conversely, a ranking of bonds by the liquidity easures of Table 6 would classify the 10-year bonds as the ost liquid issues. It is worth noting that our classification of bonds can be justified either by the bid-ask spread or by the trading activity easures because, as was entioned before, we do not intend to copare liquidity across different aturity zones but within the. Three conclusions ay be drawn fro the previous analysis. First, the benchark status and strippability of bonds are two relevant deterinants of the liquidity differences within a aturity zone for the bonds in our saple. Second, the four categories we consider see useful to identify groups of bonds with different degrees of liquidity. And, finally there appear to be big differences in liquidity between bonds, so that it akes sense to test for the existence of a liquidity preiu. This is the ai of the next section of the paper. 5. ESTIMATING LIQUIDITY PREMIA 5.1. Preliinary analysis Our ai in this second part of the paper is to find out if differences in liquidity are priced in the Spanish GS arket. One siple approach is to approxiate the liquidity preiu by the yield spread between non-benchark and benchark bonds. Applying this easure to the 3, 5, 10 and 15-year bonds of our saple always gives a negative figure, suggesting the existence of negative liquidity preia. However, it has to be taken into account that soe factors ay bias this easure. Differences in coupons between bonds iply different risk and tax burdens that ay ake the investor deand different yields to aturity for other reasons not related to liquidity effects. The ain difficulty when identifying the liquidity preiu is the separation of the factors explaining differences in yields to aturity. With 8 BIS (1999) copares bid-ask spreads for on-the-run and off-the-run issues for Canada, Italy, Japan, UK and US. In all cases they find the sae results as ours, except for Japan, where the liquidity of on-the-run 10-year bonds akes their spread narrower than the one for on-the-run 5-year bonds. (See Table 3 of the docuent Market Liquidity: Research Findings and Selected Policy Iplications ) 10 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017

this in ind, our proposal is based on the estiation of the ter structure of interest rates, because this allows us to control any effect associated with differences in aturity and cash flows. This approach is siilar to that followed by Elton and Green (1998). According to the analysis developed in Section 4, we distinguish four types of bonds in relation to their life cycle and tax treatent: non-strippable bonds and pre-benchark, postbenchark and benchark strippable bonds. As a preliinary analysis of the existence of liquidity preia we estiate a zero-coupon yield curve using the Svensson odel 9,10 and analyse yield errors for bonds. We find a very interesting pattern. Figure 3 shows the estiation for a representative day of the saple, (29/3/99) and Table 7 reports average yield errors for each bond in our saple, distinguishing its classification over the saple period. The first thing we observe is that ost non-strippable bonds appear to have on average positive yield errors, i.e. they are located above the estiated yield curve. The second point to be stressed is the tendency of pre-benchark bonds to exhibit a lower yield error than benchark bonds. Finally, the yield error of post-benchark bonds lies between the yield errors of benchark and nonstrippable bonds. These results provide preliinary evidence of a positive preiu for postbenchark and non-strippable bonds over benchark issues. The next section tries to estiate the using a ore foral approach. 5.2. Estiating the yield curve incorporating liquidity effects Previous results indicate that the estiation of the yield curve for the Spanish GS arket ay be iproved if we introduce liquidity and withholding-tax effects. Our approach consists of estiating the ter structure of interest rates using the Svensson odel, and introducing duy variables to capture these effects. These variables allow us to classify securities according to their degree of liquidity and their tax treatent and to estiate liquidity preia. Elton and Green (1998) follow a siilar procedure 11 but they introduce volue as a easure of liquidity. We prefer to use qualitative instead of quantitative variables for the following reasons. First, there is no consensus on what is the best direct easure of liquidity. Second, the traditional easures of liquidity (volue and bid-ask spread) are very noisy at a daily level, i.e. they are uch ore volatile than the expected pattern of liquidity. And, finally, the relationship between liquidity easures and liquidity preia ay not be linear. 9 See Annex 1 for a description of the Svensson odel. 10 Fro now on, all the estiation results are obtained using the Blooberg dataset. When we use the Reuters-BDE dataset we obtain siilar results. 11 They use non-linear least squares to fit a cubic spline to the after-tax cash flows of bonds. BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 11

The instantaneous forward rate of ter is odelled in the following way: ϕ τ 0 1e 1 τ 1 τ 2 = β + β + β 2 e + β 3 e + γ 0 PREBENCH + γ 1POSTBENCH + γ 2 τ1 τ 2 NONSTRIP where PREBENCH, POSTBENCH and NONSTRIP are duy variables which take the value 1 for pre-benchark, post-benchark and non-strippable bonds respectively. Paraeters for duy variables ust be interpreted in relation to the reaining instruents (3, 5, 10, 15 and 30-year benchark bonds and short-ter securities). Paraeters γ 0, γ 1 and γ 2 capture the excess yield deanded on pre-benchark, postbenchark and non-strippable bonds respectively. Paraeters γ 0 and γ 1 can be directly interpreted as liquidity preia since the tax treatent is the sae for all strippable issues. Conversely, paraeter γ 2 ay incorporate a tax preiu in addition to a liquidity preiu due to the relatively less favourable tax treatent of non-strippable bonds. The interpretation of the reaining paraeters is the standard one in the Svensson odel. Once we have odelled the instantaneous forward rate including withholding-tax and liquidity effects, we estiate the paraeter vector β = β, β, β, τ, β, τ, γ, γ, ) for each day t as ( 0 1 2 1 3 2 0 1 γ 2 βˆ = arg in N i= 1 p ti 2 pti( β ) pti where pti is the actual price 12 of bond i at tie t, p ti (β ) is the theoretical price obtained fro previous specification of the instantaneous forward rate, and N is the nuber of securities considered in the estiation. We iniise price errors instead of yield errors to obtain a better fit for the aturities we are ost interested in i.e. ediu and long-ter. We estiate the odel with liquidity and withholding-tax effects (odel 2) and copare it with a odel without these effects where paraeters γ 0, γ 1, γ 2 are restricted to zero (odel 1). These odels are estiated daily fro January 1999 to April 2000. Over the period 4/1/99 to 30/9/99 the Svensson odel does not iprove on the Nelson-Siegel odel 13 and consequently, we estiate the latter odel for this period. Table 8 14 reports a descriptive 12 We use the id-point between the quoted bid and ask prices. For short-ter we use repo and bill rates. 13 This odel is a particular case of the Svensson odel, where the instantaneous forward rate is odelled with just one hup, i.e. β 3 and τ 2 are set to zero and one respectively. 14 We concentrate on the interpretation of paraeters γ 0, γ 1, γ 2, which will be reported in different tables. The reaining paraeters of the Svensson and Nelson-Siegel odel are presented in Table 12 for all the odels estiated in the paper. 12 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017

analysis of the paraeters estiated for duy variables, the root ean square error (RMSE), and the reduction in the RMSE with respect to odel 1. Model 2 reduces the RMSE by 63% on average. The paraeter of post-benchark and non-strippable bonds is positive and significant for ost days of the saple, which ay be interpreted as evidence of the existence of liquidity preia. By contrast, the paraeter of pre-benchark bonds turns out to be negative on average, suggesting the existence of a negative preiu for these bonds over benchark issues. However, soe care ust be taken in the interpretation of this paraeter. It is negatively significant for just 55% of the saple period, and in soe periods there is just one bond included in this category. The conclusion drawn fro the analysis of this paraeter is that pre-benchark bonds do not see to include any positive liquidity preiu in spite of their low liquidity in ters of trading activity and bid-ask spreads. This result ay possibly be explained by the forwardlooking behaviour of investors. It is costly to trade these securities, but investors do not deand a higher yield because, in the future, these costs will be uch lower when the bond acquires benchark status. In addition, the liited supply of these issues ay help to sustain their price. Given that pre-benchark bonds do not appear to have a positive liquidity preiu over benchark issues we proceed to group pre-benchark and benchark bonds into the sae category. Model 3 includes only two duy variables to capture liquidity differences, one for post-benchark and the other for non-strippable bonds. The reduction of RMSE with respect to odel 1 continues to be very high (50%). Non-strippable bonds appear to have a preiu of 8 basis points on average, ranging fro 5.1 to 11.7 basis points. This paraeter is statistically significant for the whole saple period. Post-benchark bonds also appear to incorporate a preiu. It takes the value of 5.2 basis points on average, but in this case there are soe periods where the paraeter of this variable is not positive and statistically significant. Figure 4 shows the evolution of estiated paraeters γ 1, γ 2. Shaded areas indicate that γ 1 is not statistically significant. These areas coincide with periods in which the benchark issues change. During these periods frontiers between strippable categories are blurred aking it difficult to interpret paraeter γ 1. The sall nuber of issues in the post-benchark category ay raise soe doubts about the accuracy of the estiation of paraeter γ 1. However, this proble does not see to be too serious if we take into account that paraeter γ 1 is significant every day in periods in which the liquidity categories of bonds are sufficiently differentiated. Suing up, the results of this section suggest the existence of a positive liquidity preiu for post-benchark issues over benchark bonds, although its size is very sall siilar to that found by Elton and Green (1998) in the US arket. Conversely, the lack of liquidity of pre-benchark issues does not see to be priced and, even a negative preiu over BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 13

benchark issues is found in soe periods. Finally, there is clear evidence of a positive preiu for non-strippable bonds over the whole saple period. However, as noted before, this preiu cannot be interpreted directly as a liquidity preiu since the excess yield deanded on non-strippable bonds ay also include a withholding-tax preiu. In the next section we try to separate these two coponents. 5.3. Separation of withholding-tax and liquidity effects for non-strippable bonds. Previous results show strong evidence of a preiu for non-strippable bonds that, initially, ay be due to liquidity or withholding-tax effects. In order to isolate the liquidity effects we re-estiate Model 3 odifying the cash flows of non-strippable bonds (Model 4) by introducing withholding-tax effects. To do this, we consider three different tax scenarios. The ain results are suarised in Table 9. We start with the extree case in which withholding tax is fully set off against the annual payent of corporate incoe tax. We include the cost of withholding tax, which reduces the aount of coupon payents by 18% (the withholding tax rate during the saple period) and a new cash flow strea, corresponding to the copensation for the withholding tax, at the date of the annual tax payent. Under this tax scenario, the estiation results show no evidence of a liquidity preiu for non-strippable bonds. On average, we obtain a negative preiu very close to zero. However in only 34% of the saple period is this negative preiu statistically significant, while in 17% of the saple period the liquidity preiu takes a positive value. These results would iply that the excess return found for nonstrippable bonds is ainly explained by their tax cost. However, this tax scenario is difficult to uphold for various reasons. First, ost investent institutions set off withholding tax against quarterly payents of corporate incoe tax rather than annual payents. Second, withholding-tax costs ay be reduced through coupon-washing transactions 15. This leads us to consider two alternative and ore realistic tax scenarios. Spanish corporate incoe tax requires quarterly payents to be ade based on estiated profits during each quarter. These quarterly payents are then reconsidered in the annual tax return. In practice, ost investent institutions are subject to these quarterly payents and therefore the withholding tax is set off against the next quarterly payent instead of in the annual tax return. This leads us to consider a ore realistic second tax scenario in which the withholding tax is set off against the next quarterly payent. This tax scenario is still an extree case in the sense that the cost of withholding tax ight be reduced through coupon-washing transactions. The results of the estiations show an average liquidity 15 These transactions consist of selling non-strippable bonds to non-resident investors, who are not subject to withholding tax, before the date of the coupon, and buying the back again after that date. 14 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017

preiu for non-strippable bonds of 6.8 basis points that proves to be statistically significant for the whole saple period. Therefore, in this case, the cost of withholding tax is sall, around 1.2 basis points considering the results of Model 3. The liquidity preiu for post-benchark bonds does not change significantly, and its size is still saller than the one for non-strippable bonds. This fact could be explained by the lower degree of liquidity of the latter bonds. Finally, we consider a third tax scenario in which the withholding-tax cost of the first tax scenario is reduced through coupon-washing transactions. We suppose that resident and non-resident investors share the profit on this transaction equally. This profit is the cost saved by avoiding the withholding tax. Under this scenario we again find evidence of a positive liquidity preiu for non-strippable bonds. It takes the value of 3.6 basis points on average. Therefore under this scenario the cost of withholding tax is 4.2 basis points with respect to Model 3. This liquidity preiu is statistically significant in 75% of the saple period. The liquidity preiu for post-benchark bonds does not change significantly, and it is now larger in size than the one for non-strippable bonds. To su up, the separation of withholding tax and liquidity effects for non-strippable bonds requires assuptions to be ade. Excluding the ost extree and unrealistic case, we have found that the previously reported preia for non-strippable bonds ostly reflect a liquidity preiu, whose size ranges between 6.8 and 3.6 basis points. The liquidity preiu for post-benchark bonds does not change significantly and, on average, takes the value of 5.2 basis points. Here, it is worth noting that differences in liquidity between post-benchark and non-strippable bonds do not see to iply significant differences in their liquidity preiu. This result ight suggest that there is no linear relationship between the liquidity preiu and trading activity. 5.4. Robustness to tax effects The above results ay be sensitive to the inclusion of general tax effects in the estiation of the zero-coupon yield curve. That is, they ay be affected by the estiation of a pre-tax instead of a post-tax yield curve. It is very difficult to estiate a post-tax yield curve, because tax treatent is very different across investors. In this section we estiate a posttax yield curve considering the tax treatent for Spanish corporations, which hold two thirds of the outstanding volue of bonds (see Table 2). The theoretical price is expressed as the present value of after-tax cash flows, with a tax rate of 35% iposed on both interest payents and capital gains. Capital gains or losses at the redeption date are distributed over the life of the bond using a constant yield ethod, and assuing that the bond is held until aturity. BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 15

Table 10 shows the ain results of the re-estiation of Model 3 using after-tax flows (Model 5). It can be seen that in this new odel the sign and significance of estiated preia reain unchanged, but their absolute size is reduced by around 35%. The paraeters that capture the asyptotic value of the instantaneous forward rate ( β 0 = ϕ ) and the instantaneous forward rate for an infinitely sall ter to aturity ( β 0 + β1 = ϕ 0) are also reduced by around 35%. Consequently, the liquidity preia expressed as a percentage of these interest rates reain alost unchanged (see Table 11). These results indicate that previously estiated relative liquidity preia are robust to tax effects. Finally, it is interesting to see that the odel with taxes further reduces the RMSE. On average the reduction over the basic odel is 76%, which copares with the 50% reduction of the odel with two duies but without taxes (odel 3). This result suggests the relevance of introducing tax effects when fitting zero-coupon yield curves. 5.5. Ipact of liquidity preia on the estiated yield curve In this subsection we study the ipact of the introduction of liquidity effects on the estiated zero-coupon yield curve. To do this we copare the estiated paraeters for the different odels we have considered in subsections 5.2 to 5.4. Table 12 reports the ean and the standard deviation of the basic paraeters of the ter structure 16. The ean of the paraeters estiates for the odels that introduce liquidity effects without taxes (Models 2 to 4) are very close to those of the basic odel (Model 1). This is not a surprising result given the relatively sall liquidity preia we have found. Conversely, when taxes are introduced (Model 5) soe paraeters change significantly. β 0 and β 1 are now around 35% (the tax rate) below the estiated level for Model 3, whereas the changes in the other paraeters are less draatic. These changes iply that after-tax zero-coupon rates are around 35% below before-tax rates. Figure 5 depicts the zero-coupon yield curve at 29/3/99 for two of the odels we have estiated, using the Nelson-Siegel approach. The odels we consider in this figure are the basic odel (Model 1) and the odel that introduces duy variables for both postbenchark and non-strippable bonds (Model 3). The yield curve of the odel that accounts for liquidity (Model 3) stands slightly above (with a axiu difference of 9 basis points) that of the basic odel for short-ter aturities and slightly below it (with a axiu difference of 12 basis points) for ediu-ter horizons. For long-ter aturities both odels display very siilar rates. 16 Fro 4/01/99 to 30/9/99 we estiate the Nelson-Siegel odel, and fro 1/10/99 to 14/4/00 the Svensson odel. 16 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017

Figure 6 shows the estiated 1-year forward curves iplied by the yield curves depicted in Figure 5. Estiated forward rates for horizons shorter than 6 years are slightly lower for the odel that accounts for liquidity effects, whereas the opposite is the case for longer horizons. Figures 7 and 8 are the sae as Figures 5 and 6, except for the fact that they are estiated at 31/3/00 using the Svensson odel. In this case, the zero-coupon rates are lower for the odel that introduces liquidity effects in coparison with the basic odel, for all horizons. It is worth noting that for the ediu and long-ter horizons the difference between the two curves is saller than that found with Figure 5. This is not surprising given the reduction in the estiated liquidity preia in the second half of the saple period. The introduction of liquidity effects has allowed us to identify liquidity preia and to reduce the error in the estiation of the zero-coupon yield curve. However, the iplications for the inforation content of the estiated yield curve are not very iportant. This is an expected result given the sall size of the estiated liquidity preiu. 5.6. Biases in quoted prices The results of the previous analysis have been derived fro the quoted prices posted by brokers in Blooberg. We know that these prices are not fir, but erely inforative and, consequently, we do not know how accurate they are. The existence of a bias in quoted prices ay have an ipact on the liquidity preia we have estiated. In this subsection we study the existence of biases in quoted prices in coparison with traded prices and derive conclusions on their ipact on the estiated liquidity preia. To do this, for each day and security we copute the difference in yield between the ean traded price and the idquoted price. Table 13 shows the average of these yield differences for each security, distinguishing its classification over the saple period in the four categories we have considered in this paper (pre-benchark, benchark, post-benchark and non-strippable). Three iportant features eerge fro Table 13. First, average yield differences are very sall for alost all securities 17 (between 0 and 2.3 basis points), ost of the being not significantly different fro zero. Second, yield differences tend to be positive for ost bonds (those figures statistically different fro zero are all positive). Third, yield differences tend to be higher for pre-benchark and non-strippable bonds. These results suggest the existence of a sall negative bias in quoted prices in coparison with traded prices, which sees to be ore iportant for pre-benchark and non-strippable 17 The only exception being those bonds that ature within the saple period. The low duration of these bonds iplies that sall differences in quoted and traded prices translate into significant discrepancies in ters of yield to aturity. BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017 17

issues. This would ean that there is a negative bias in the liquidity preia estiated for non-strippable and pre-benchark bonds, i.e. the actual liquidity preiu for non-strippable bonds is higher than the estiated, whereas the absolute value of the liquidity preiu for pre-benchark issues is lower. However, these biases in the liquidity preia should be relatively sall given the very sall size of the bias in quoted prices. Consequently, the reported results of sections 5.1 to 5.5 see to be robust to the data set we have used. 6. CONCLUSIONS The analysis developed in the first part of the paper has shown that there are iportant liquidity differences aong securities traded in the Spanish GS arket. The strippability of the asset strippable bonds are the ost liquid- and the benchark status benchark bonds are ore liquid- appear to be two relevant deterinants of the securities liquidity within each aturity zone. The second part of the paper analyses the presence of liquidity preia in the relative pricing of assets traded in the Spanish GS arket. The estiation is carried out introducing liquidity paraeters in the Svensson odel of the zero-coupon yield curve. These liquidity paraeters allow us to estiate the excess yield of pre-benchark, post-benchark and non-strippable bonds over benchark issues. This ethodology iproves on the traditional approach to the estiation of liquidity preia which involves coputing the yield spread between non-benchark and benchark bonds - because it allows an appropriate control of effects associated with differences in aturity and cash flows. The ain conclusions that can be drawn fro the estiations ade are the following. First, results suggest the existence of positive liquidity preia for post-benchark bonds (both strippable and non-strippable). However, these preia are very sall and siilar to those found by Elton and Green (1998) in the US arket. Second, the lack of liquidity of prebenchark bonds does not see to be priced in the arket. In fact, in soe periods, there is even a negative preiu over benchark issues for these bonds. This is a soewhat surprising result that can possibly be explained by the forward-looking behaviour of arket participants. Third, estiated liquidity preia see robust to tax effects and to the data set we have used (quoted prices instead of actual traded prices). Finally, regarding the iplications for the estiated zero-coupon yield curve, the introduction of liquidity effects does not have a significant ipact due to the sall size of the estiated liquidity preia. In this paper we have focused on testing for the existence of liquidity preia in the Spanish GS arket. The results obtained pose interesting questions for future research. One of the is the analysis of the deterinants of the estiated liquidity preia and their 18 BANCO DE ESPAÑA / DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N. 0017