R&D cooperation with unit-elastic demand



Similar documents
Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly]

Chapter 12 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

Microeconomics. Lecture Outline. Claudia Vogel. Winter Term 2009/2010. Part III Market Structure and Competitive Strategy

12 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

a. Retail market for water and sewerage services Answer: Monopolistic competition, many firms each selling differentiated products.

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

Why do merchants accept payment cards?

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 13 Oligopoly 1

THE NON-EQUIVALENCE OF EXPORT AND IMPORT QUOTAS

Hyun-soo JI and Ichiroh DAITOH Tohoku University. May 25, Abstract

Equilibrium: Illustrations

5. Suppose demand is perfectly elastic, and the supply of the good in question

MODULE 64: INTRODUCTION TO OLIGOPOLY Schmidty School of Economics. Wednesday, December 4, :20:15 PM Central Standard Time

Oligopoly: Cournot/Bertrand/Stackelberg

9.1 Cournot and Bertrand Models with Homogeneous Products

Economics 100 Exam 2

The Basics of Game Theory

Economics II: Micro Fall 2009 Exercise session 5. Market with a sole supplier is Monopolistic.

Gains from trade in a Hotelling model of differentiated duopoly

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Two Papers on Internet Connectivity and Quality. Abstract

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

Mikroekonomia B by Mikolaj Czajkowski. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

1 Cournot Oligopoly with n firms

AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table.

Cooleconomics.com Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly. Contents:

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

Market is a network of dealings between buyers and sellers.


Marginal cost. Average cost. Marginal revenue

Exercises for Industrial Organization Master de Economía Industrial Matilde Pinto Machado

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

Unionized Oligopoly and Outsourcing

Chapter 11. T he economy that we. The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry Production in a Nonnatural Monopoly Situation

Pre-Test Chapter 23 ed17

Two-Period Resource Duopoly with Endogenous Intertemporal Capacity Constraints

Economics 203: Intermediate Microeconomics I Lab Exercise #11. Buy Building Lease F1 = 500 F1 = 750 Firm 2 F2 = 500 F2 = 400

Aggressive Advertisement. Normal Advertisement Aggressive Advertisement. Normal Advertisement

Figure: Computing Monopoly Profit

A. a change in demand. B. a change in quantity demanded. C. a change in quantity supplied. D. unit elasticity. E. a change in average variable cost.

Forthcoming in Research Papers Series, SU- HSE, Research in Economics and Finance, May 2010

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne

Game Theory: Supermodular Games 1

Other explanations of the merger paradox. Industrial Economics (EC5020), Spring 2010, Sotiris Georganas, February 22, 2010

Chapter 8 Production Technology and Costs 8.1 Economic Costs and Economic Profit

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Variable Cost. Marginal Cost. Average Variable Cost 0 $50 $50 $ $150 A B C D E F 2 G H I $120 J K L 3 M N O P Q $120 R

Oligopoly. Models of Oligopoly Behavior No single general model of oligopoly behavior exists. Oligopoly. Interdependence.

ECON101 STUDY GUIDE 7 CHAPTER 14

OLIGOPOLY. Nature of Oligopoly. What Causes Oligopoly?

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

Figure 1, A Monopolistically Competitive Firm

Online Supplementary Material

Chapter 13 Market Structure and Competition

4. Market Structures. Learning Objectives Market Structures

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Common in European countries government runs telephone, water, electric companies.

Optimal election of qualities in the presence of externalities

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February / 32

Managerial Economics. 1 is the application of Economic theory to managerial practice.

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC

MPP 801 Monopoly Kevin Wainwright Study Questions

How To Learn Economics In India

ECO 745: Theory of International Economics. Jack Rossbach August 26, Week 1

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron.

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

Chapter 16 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

chapter: Oligopoly Krugman/Wells Economics 2009 Worth Publishers 1 of 35

QE1: Economics Notes 1

Oligopoly: Firms in Less Competitive Markets

How To Understand The Theory Of Economic Theory

The New Trade Theory. Monopoly and oligopoly in trade. Luca De Benedictis 1. Topic 3. 1 University of Macerata

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

I. Noncooperative Oligopoly

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Problem Set #6 Due: Wednesday, November 3

Technology platforms, such as Microsoft Windows, are the hubs of technology industries. We develop a

Monopoly Quantity & Price Elasticity Welfare. Monopoly Chapter 24

On the Optimal Allocation of Security Listings to Specialists

Oligopoly. Oligopoly is a market structure in which the number of sellers is small.

BPE_MIC1 Microeconomics 1 Fall Semester 2011

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol.I - Economics of Scale and Imperfect Competition - Bharati Basu

Profit maximization in different market structures

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Adverse Selection and the Market for Health Insurance in the U.S. James Marton

Mergers and Acquisitions in Mixed-Oligopoly Markets

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 16 Oligopoly What Is Oligopoly? 1) Describe the characteristics of an oligopoly.

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

Final Exam (Version 1) Answers

Lecture 28 Economics 181 International Trade

Transcription:

R&D cooperation with unit-elastic demand Georg Götz This draft: September 005. Abstract: This paper shows that R&D cooperation leads to the monopoly outcome in terms of price and quantity if demand is unit-elastic. If the demand function exhibits an upper bound for the willingness to pay, R&D cooperation is inferior to a scenario in which firms cooperate both in their R&D and their output decision. Keywords: R&D cooperation, spillovers, cartelization JEL-Classification No.: L13, O31 Department of Economics, University of Vienna, BWZ - Bruenner Str. 7, A-110 Vienna, Austria, phone/fax: +43 1 477-374 66/-374 98, email: georg.goetz@univie.ac.at, http://homepage.univie.ac.at/georg.goetz/

1. Introduction The question of whether R&D cooperation might have adverse consequences for product market competition is a rather disputed issue. There are concerns that firms which cooperate in one field might well cooperate in another one as well (see Martin 00). Rather than entering this discussion, I show that under certain conditions R&D cooperation directly leads to the monopoly outcome in terms of price and quantity. If demand is unit-elastic, a Cournot duopoly, in which firms cooperate in R&D, leads to a price that approaches infinity and R&D expenditures that go to zero. The duopoly differs from the monopoly case only in terms of profits, which are lower in the duopoly case. If R&D spillovers are perfect, the cooperative and the non-cooperative choice of R&D expenditures coincide. If the demand function exhibits an upper bound for the willingness to pay, duopoly prices and quantities under R&D cooperation are exactly that of the monopoly. However, R&D expenditures are inefficiently low. I show that a scenario, in which firms cooperate in R&D and compete in the quantity setting stage of the game, is inferior to full cartelization. A related paper is Kline (000). He shows that R&D cooperation might lead to lower R&D expenditures than non-cooperation if certain conditions on demand and costs are satisfied. The case of a unit-elastic demand analyzed in this paper is a special case of the conditions stated by Kline. My analysis complements Kline's results in that it calculates actual levels of R&D expenditures whereas Kline makes only comparisons at the margin.

3. The model I consider a homogeneous good duopoly, in which firms set quantities. In order to make the points clearly, I employ the functional forms introduced by Dasgupta and Stiglitz (1980). Inverse demand reads 1 p =σ q + q ε (1) 1 Here, q 1 and q denote the outputs of the two firms, p denotes the product price. σ is a positive parameter that measures market size. ε denotes the constant price elasticity of demand. Firm i's constant, marginal costs c i depend on x i, the firm's R&D expenditures in the following way: ( i) ( i j) c x =β x +θ x i, j = 1,; i j. () I assume a two-stage game in which firms simultaneously choose R&D expenditures in the first stage. In the second stage firms simultaneously choose outputs. In the case of R&D cooperation firms choose R&D expenditures of both firms cooperatively in order to maximize joint profits. The setup follows Kamien, Mueller, and Zang (199) by assuming input spillovers and in the definition of R&D cooperation. Second stage quantities for given levels of R&D expenditures derive from the profit function ( ) 1 ε 1 π = σ q + q β x +θx q x i, j = 1,; i j. (3) i i j i i The first order conditions with respect to quantities can be written as πi q i σ! 1+ε ε = q1+ q (( ε 1) qi +εqj) β ( xi +θ xj) = 0, i,j = 1,; i j. (4) ε

4 Closed-form solutions do not exist for arbitrary values of the demand elasticity ε. However, they are straightforward to calculate for the special case ε = 1. Equilibrium quantities read in this case q i ( xi xj) ( xi xj) ( xi xj) ( xi xj) σ +θ θ + = β +θ + θ +, i, j = 1,; i j. (5) Note that the quantities are well defined for a demand elasticity of 1. A symmetric equilibrium of the quantity setting stage exists even for inelastic demand as long as ε is greater than 1/. The equilibrium price is also a function of R&D expenditures and reads (( i j) ( i j) ) p =β x +θ x + θ x + x, i, j = 1,; i j. (6) The reduced profit functions as a function of R&D expenditures are ( x x ) σ ( xi +θxj) ( xi +θ xj) + ( θ xi + xj) * i i j x i π, =, i, j = 1,; i j. (7).1 Non-cooperative R&D Differentiating the reduced profit function with respect to x i and solving for an equilibrium with symmetric R&D expenditures x N yields N x ( 1 θ) σ = 41+ θ. (8) Effective R&D expenditures x i + θ x j are equal to σ( 1 θ ) /4. Note that individual and effective R&D expenditures are strictly decreasing in the spillover parameter θ. Even more, as θ approaches one, x N approaches 0. With unit elastic demand, a perfect spillover would lead firms to invest as little as possible in R&D.

5. Cooperative R&D Under R&D cooperation firms choose R&D activities cooperatively in order to maximize joint profits. In the quantity setting stage, firms play a non-cooperative game. The objective function is x1, x (( x x ) ( x x ) ) 1 1 (( x1 +θ x) + ( θ x1 + x) ) σ +θ + +θ max π, +π, = * * 1 x1 x x x1 x1 x The derivative of this expression with respect to x 1 reads * * σ( 1 θ ) x 1 ( x1 + θx) ( x + θx1) π +π x 1 1 1 ( x +θx ) ( θ x + x ) ( x +θ x ) + ( θ x + x ) 1 1 1 1 3. (9) = 1. (10) Again I solve for an equilibrium with symmetric R&D expenditures. If one assumes that x 1 = x = x C, the first expression on the r.h.s of (10) becomes 0, and the value of the derivative is equal to 1. I obtain the result that the R&D-cooperators invest in R&D as a monopolist would: i.e. as little as possible. The joint profit of the duopolists is, however, smaller than that of the monopolists. Due to competition in the second stage of the game, profit for each duopolist approaches σ/4 as R&D expenditures go to 0. Therefore, joint profits are just half of the monopoly profit. Note here that in the case with symmetric R&D expenditures x C joint profits can be simplified to * * σ C π 1 +π = x. (11) 3. Extension: Demand with finite maximum willingness to pay While the above section clearly makes the relevant point R&D cooperation might lead to the monopoly outcome in terms of final output I now present an example that does not rely

6 on limit arguments. To do that, I assume that consumers have a maximum finite willingness to pay that is equal to the parameter σ. The demand curve now exhibits a flat part at a price of σ and a kink at an aggregate output of one. This extension leaves the equilibrium of the game with R&D competition unchanged as long as σ> 1 1 1+ 1+ β ( ) ( 1+ 1 θ ). (1) I assume this condition to hold. This assumption ensures that price and quantity in the equilibrium without R&D cooperation are different from the monopoly price and quantity. Both monopoly and R&D cooperation would lead to a price of σ and an aggregate output of one. This is a consequence of the fact that price elasticity is infinite along the flat part of the demand curve, whereas the arguments from the above section extend to the unit-elastic part of the demand curve. One obtains the result that R&D cooperation is sufficient for a duopoly, which competes in the final stage of the game, to implement the monopoly solution in terms of output and price. The joint profit, however, is smaller. To see this, I derive equilibrium R&D expenditures under R&D cooperation. Again looking for a symmetric equilibrium, I solve for x, the maximum value of R&D expenditures, which is compatible with both firms producing an output of 1/ each. Setting the quantity in (5) equal to 1/ and imposing symmetry yields x = β 1 1 ( 1 ) 1 + θσ. (13) For higher values of x, the firms would produce a total output of more than one in the second stage of the game due to lower marginal costs. Note that x is smaller than the cost minimizing value of R&D expenditures. This can be seen by differentiating π 1 + π as defined in equation (3) with respect to x 1 and x, taking into account that individual outputs are 1/. The resulting value is

7 greater than x for the values of σ that satisfy (1). This yields another surprising result: R&D cooperation with non-cooperation in the quantity setting stage is inferior to full cartelization! While output and prices are identical, sole R&D cooperation leads to higher average costs. 4. Policy conclusions There is a clear policy conclusion from the above analysis. Do not allow R&D cooperation for the development of products with inelastic demand. However, if the authority does not prevent such a cooperation, then it should even suggest a full cartelization of the participants of a cooperative agreement. 5. References Dasgupta, P., Stiglitz, J.E. (1980). Industrial Structure and the Nature of Innovative Activity. Economic Journal 90, 66-93. Kamien, M.I., Muller, E., and Zang, I. (199). Research Joint Ventures and R&D Cartels. American Economic Review 8, 193-1306. Kline, J.J (000). Research joint ventures and the cost paradox. International Journal of Industrial Organization 18, 1049-1065. Martin, S. (00). Advanced Industrial Organization. nd edition. Blackwell, Oxford.