Answer Key Problem Set 5

Similar documents
Economics 181: International Trade Homework # 4 Solutions

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

A. a change in demand. B. a change in quantity demanded. C. a change in quantity supplied. D. unit elasticity. E. a change in average variable cost.

Q D = (5)(5) = 75 Q S = 50 + (5)(5) = 75.

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

Exercises Lecture 8: Trade policies

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

The Basics of Game Theory

ECON Game Theory Exam 1 - Answer Key. 4) All exams must be turned in by 1:45 pm. No extensions will be granted.

Final Exam 15 December 2006

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

Lecture 28 Economics 181 International Trade

Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models

Rutgers University Economics 102: Introductory Microeconomics Professor Altshuler Fall 2003

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly]

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

Economics 335, Spring 1999 Problem Set #7

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

I. Introduction to Taxation

CEVAPLAR. Solution: a. Given the competitive nature of the industry, Conigan should equate P to MC.

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus

tariff versus quota Equivalence and its breakdown

Demand, Supply and Elasticity

Microeconomics Topic 3: Understand how various factors shift supply or demand and understand the consequences for equilibrium price and quantity.

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

Section 1.5 Linear Models

Review Question - Chapter 7. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

ECO 445/545: International Trade. Jack Rossbach Spring 2016

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Costs of Production and Profit Maximizing Production: 3 examples.

Week 4 Tutorial Question Solutions (Ch2 & 3)

Minimax Strategies. Minimax Strategies. Zero Sum Games. Why Zero Sum Games? An Example. An Example

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table.

How To Find Out How To Balance The Two-Country Economy

Homework #5: Answers. b. How can land rents as well as total wages be shown in such a diagram?

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Economics 203: Intermediate Microeconomics I Lab Exercise #11. Buy Building Lease F1 = 500 F1 = 750 Firm 2 F2 = 500 F2 = 400

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

In following this handout, sketch appropriate graphs in the space provided.

Name: Date: 3. Variables that a model tries to explain are called: A. endogenous. B. exogenous. C. market clearing. D. fixed.

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

a) Find the equilibrium price and quantity when the economy is closed.

Econ 102 Aggregate Supply and Demand

III. INTERNATIONAL TRADE

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

The New Trade Theory. Monopoly and oligopoly in trade. Luca De Benedictis 1. Topic 3. 1 University of Macerata

ECON 443 Labor Market Analysis Final Exam (07/20/2005)

Solving Quadratic Equations

Advanced International Economics Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 758

CLASSIFICATION OF MARKETS Perfectly competitive, various types of imperfect competition

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

5 Systems of Equations

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

17. Suppose demand is given by Q d = P + I, where Q d is quantity demanded, P is. I = 100, equilibrium quantity is A) 15 B) 20 C) 25 D) 30

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

1. If the price elasticity of demand for a good is.75, the demand for the good can be described as: A) normal. B) elastic. C) inferior. D) inelastic.

4 THE MARKET FORCES OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

3.1 Solving Systems Using Tables and Graphs

ECO 199 B GAMES OF STRATEGY Spring Term 2004 PROBLEM SET 4 B DRAFT ANSWER KEY

Lesson 7 - The Aggregate Expenditure Model

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Pre-Test Chapter 11 ed17

The Cost of Production

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Refer to Figure 17-1

Cameron ECON 100: FIRST MIDTERM (A) Winter 01

Marginal cost. Average cost. Marginal revenue

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

6. Which of the following is likely to be the price elasticity of demand for food? a. 5.2 b. 2.6 c. 1.8 d. 0.3

chapter Perfect Competition and the >> Supply Curve Section 3: The Industry Supply Curve

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline

Cournot s model of oligopoly

The economics of the Export-Import Bank: a teaching note

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 14. FIRMS IN COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Web Supplement to Chapter 2

Gains From Trade Consumer Surplus Quantifying Welfare Effects Producer Surplus Welfare in Equilibrium. Consumer Surplus and Welfare Measurement

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Fall 2013) Surplus, Efficiency, and Deadweight Loss

Chapter 8 Application: The Costs of Taxation

Chapter 9 1. Use Exhibit 3 to answer the following questions.

Households Wages, profit, interest, rent = $750. Factor markets. Wages, profit, interest, rent = $750

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE

Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition. Ethan Kaplan

Figure 1.1 Vector A and Vector F

Transcription:

Answer Key Problem Set 5 Ricardo Cavazos and Robert Santillano Department of Agriculture and Resource Economics University of California at Berkeley December 4, 2006 1 Question 1 A small country can import a good at a world price of 10 per unit. The domestic supply curve of the good is The demand curve is S =50+5P D = 400 10P In addition, each unit of production yields a marginal social benefit of 10. a Calculate the total effect on welfare of a tariff of5perunitleviedonimports Before we are able to calculate the total effect on welfare of this policy instrument we need to compute a few things. We begin by calculating equilibrium in the domestic market, ie we set domestic demand equal to domestic supply and we solve for price. S = D 50 + 5P = 400 10P 15P = 50 P e = 50 15 = 70 With a domestic price of P e = 70 we now substitute this value into demand or supply to obtain the domestic (autarky) quantity. Therefore, we have that Please contact us at cavazos@are.berkeley.edu or rsantillano@berkeley.edu if you have any questions, find any errors, or typos in the answers. 1

µ 50 D = 400 10 15 = 400 700 1200 700 = D = 500 That the quantity, price pair that make this market clear in autarky is 500, 70. Now, at a price of 10 per unit this country would be producing less and consuming more. Therefore, to obtain these quantities we substitute the price of 10 into domestic demand and domestic supply. We have then that quantity supplied is the following: S = 50 + 5 (10) Q S = 100 and quantity demanded is then the following: D = 400 10 (10) Q D = 00 Finally, imports are defined as the difference between quantity demanded and quantity supplied. Then, it follows: M 0 = Q D Q S = 00 100 = 200 Figure 1. below presents the initial situation as well as the excess demand curve. 2

P Supply P 70/ 10 Demand 100 00 500/ Q 200 ED Figure 1. Small importing country Now we are in a position to impose the $5 per unit tariff and analyze its effects on welfare. Since it is a per unit tariff we can just add it to the international price, that is the new price domestic consumers are going to be facing is now 15 instead of 10. The new price comes about by increasing the amount of the tariff to the international price. To obtain the new quantity demanded and quantity supplied we now substitute the price of 15 into domestic demand and domestic supply. We have then the following: and S = 50 + 5 (15) Q t S = 125 D = 400 10 (15) Q t D = 250 Finally, the new amount of imports is again the difference between the quantity demanded with the tariff and the quantity supplied with the tariff, that is the new amount of imports M 1 = 125. Figure 2 below presents the outcome for a small country that imposes an import tariff of $5 per unit. Note that there are distributional changes that we still need to calculate.

P Supply P 70/ 15 10 A B C D Demand 100 125 250 00 Q 125 200 ED Figure 2. Small country and import tariff Starting with consumers we know that when prices increase consumers are going to lose. In this case, consumers are going to lose areas A+B+C+D. The magnitude of this loss of consumer surplus is (250 5) + 50 5 2 = 175. Producers on the other hand win area A. This gain is equal to (100 5) + 25 5 2 = 562.5. The government is going to win area C which is equal to (125 5) = 625. Finally, we include the Marginal Social Benefit of10perthe extra units of production which is equal to (10 25) = 250. Putting all these changes in welfare due to the imposition of the import tariff we have that this country had a positive net welfare gain of 62.5. This figure is calculated from the algebraic sum of the following terms: 175 + 562.5 + 625 + 250 = 62.5. b Calculate the total effect of a production subsidy of 5 per unit Intuitively, a production subsidy will only distort the prices producers face in the market place, ie the government has to incentive producers to increase their production. However, at the same time the government will let consumers keep facing a price of $10.when they purchase this good. Therefore, there will be no welfare changes for consumers, there will be a welfare gain for producers, a welfare loss to the government, and a social welfare gain due to the increase in production. Lets look at these effects. The first thing we need to remember is a production subsidy will create an imaginary shift of the supply curve towards the right. This is so because at every price now producers are willing to supply a larger quantity, precisely because of the subsidy. The subsidy in this case is of the same amount as the import tariff. Therefore, the rightward shift of the supply curve will cross the $10 price line at a quantity of 125. Therefore, producers will gain area A which is equal to (100 5) + 25 5 2 = 562.5. The government will lose the amount of the subsidy multiplied by the amount produced which is equal to (125 5) = 625. Social benefit will then be (10 25) = 250. Remember, consumer do not 4

observe any welfare changes since they are unaffected by the production subsidy. However, imports do change because there is more domestic production. Since consumption is constant at 00, but production has increased to 125 units then imports are reduced to 175. The balance for this policy instrument is a positive one of 187.5.This figure is calculated by the algebraic sum of the following quantities 250 + 562.5 625 = 187.5. Figure. below presents this case. P Supply P 70/ 15 10 A B C D Demand 100 125 250 00 Q 125 200 ED Figure. Small country, import tariff, and production subsidy Remember, consumers stay at their consumption point of 00 units. Producers increase production to 125 units, the government has to pay $5 for each of the 125 units produced, and society is also better because each of the 25 extra units produced is worth $10. c Why does the production subsidy produce a greater gain in welfare than the tariff? The answer to this question lies in the fact that the production subsidy only distorts the production side. It is only producers that see their statusquo situation modified. Consumers remain at their original consumption point and observe no distortion in the final good market. On the other hand, the import tariff modifies both the behavior of consumers, they consume less, and of producers, they produce more. d What would the optimal production subsidy be? To calculate the optimal production subsidy we first need to identify what is it exactly we want to maximize. From the previous questions we noticed that welfare is enhanced given the combination of economic policies and the externality. Therefore, our goal would be to make that change in welfare as big as possible. To that effect we have to realize that welfare for this country is going to be the summation of consumer surplus, producer surplus, government expenditures, and social benefit. Therefore, we define Welfare as the following: 5

Welfare = CS + PS + GV T + SB However, we do not want to maximize welfare per se, but the change in welfare. Therefore, our objective function is going to be the change in welfare which we define in the following manner: MAX Welfare = CS + PS + GV T + SB As already explained in question 1c the production subsidy will not affect consumers. They will remain at their original consumption point of 00 units. Therefore, we know that CS =0. Our objective function then reduces to the change in producer surplus, change in government expenditures, and change in social benefit. To construct our objective we proceed in the following way: Note that the new price producers will get will be the sum of the old price and the subsidy. Therefore, define the P new =10+subsidy. Take this new price and substitute into the supply equation to obtain the new quantity as a function of the subsidy. Therefore, we have the following: S =50+5P Substitute for the price to obtain the following: S = 50+5(10+subsidy) = 100 + 5 subsidy To calculate the PS we have the following: PS = µ subsidy (100 + 5 subsidy 100) (100 subsidy)+ 2 = 100 subsidy + 5 2 subsidy2 To calculate GV T we have the following: GV T = subsidy (100 + 5 subsidy) = 100 subsidy +5 subsidy 2 To calculate SB we have the following: SB = 10 (100 + 5 subsidy 100) = 50 subsidy Wesubstitutetheseexpressionintoourobjectivefunctiontoobtainanexpression that is only a function of the subsidy. In this way we can take a 6

derivative with respect to the subsidy, set it equal to zero, and solve for the optimal subsidy. We have the following: MAX Welfare = 100 subsidy + 5 2 subsidy2 100 subsidy +5 subsidy 2 +50 subsidy = 5 2 subsidy2 +50 subsidy Take the derivative of the objective function and set equal to zero, i.e =0.Wehavethat Welfare subsidy Welfare subsidy = 5 subsidy + 50 = 0 subsidy = 50 5 = 10 Since this a strictly concave function we know that is has a unique maximum and it opens downward. Therefore, there is no need to check the second order conditions. Finally, the increase in welfare that a subsidy of 10 would provide is of the amount of 250. 2 Question 2 Suppose that ABC is a Taiwanese firm, and XYZ is a Korean firm. The following payoffs result, depending on the firm s decisions. What equilibrium, and what payoffs will result if there is no government intervention? XY Z ABC Produce Not Produce Produce 40, 25 60, 0 Not Produce 0, 150 0, 0 If there is no government intervention then the equilibrium we would observe would be that of the XYZ firm producing and the ABC firm not producing. The payoffs wouldbe(0, 150) where ABC would receive 0 and XY Z would receive 150. The process by which we arrive at this outcome is the following: We are looking for the equilibrium where the players have no unilateral incentives to deviate from it. This equilibrium is called a Nash equilibrium. To find the Nash equilibrium we first check to see if the players have dominant strategies. If they do this would simplify the process because this would imply there is a set of strategies that a player will never use. In this case, we can see that firm XY Z has a dominant strategy of Produce because the payoffs of producing are always greater than the payoffs of Not Producing. Firm XY Z is comparing 25 to 0; and 150 to 0. Producing will always yield a greater payoff than Not producing. Conclusion, firm XY Z will always produce. On the other 7

hand, firm ABC does not have a dominant strategy. However, since firm ABC knows that firm XY Z will always produce then the best response from firm ABC is to Not produce. This way firm ABC will obtain a payoff of 0 instead of one of -40. Question Strategic trade. The cost for production is,000 per car in the US and 2,000 per car in Japan. Suppose automobile prices are described by the following inverse demand function: P =60, 000 20 (X US + X J ) a Derive the reaction function for US producers, ie X US (X J ),expressthenumber of US cars produced as a function of Japanese production. To derive reaction functions we first need to maximize profits taking the other country s production as given. So, if we want to obtain the US reaction function then we maximize US profits taking Japanese production as given: Max π = P X US, 000X US = (60, 000 20 (X US + X J )) X US, 000X US Now take the derivative of profits with respect to the quantity produced in the United States. We have the following: Set π X US π X US = 60, 000 40X US 20X J, 000 = 57, 000 40X US 20X J =0and solve for X US.Wehavethefollowing: 57, 000 40X US 20X J = 0 40X US = 57, 000 20X J X US = 57, 000 20X J 40 If we wanted to obtain the Japanese reaction function we would proceed in the same manner as we just did. Note that these two reaction function are almost symmetric except for marginal cost which is lower in Japan. Taking this difference into account we obtain the Japanese reaction function: Max π = P X J 2, 000X J = (60, 000 20 (X US + X J )) X J 2, 000X J 8

Now take the derivative of profits with respect to the quantity produced in Japan. We have the following: Set π X J π X J = 60, 000 40X J 20X US 2, 000 = 58, 000 40X J 20X US =0and solve for X J.Wehavethefollowing: 58, 000 40X J 20X US = 0 40X J = 58, 000 20X US X J = 58, 000 20X US 40 Now consider the reaction functions graphed below and use them to answer the questions b and c X US X J Figure 4. Reaction Functions b Which reaction function does the arrow point to? X US (X J ) or X J (X US )? The arrow points towards the United States reaction function, that is X US (X J ). c What factors may cause any US strategic trade policy attempts to fail? List 2 The reasons that might make US strategic trade policy fail are many, but among them are the following: The US is facing another large country and there is a possibility of retaliation; The US makes a non-credible threat and the other country calls the "bluff" of the United States; Rent-seeking 9