Economics 201A - Section 6

Similar documents
6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 15: Repeated Games and Cooperation

Bayesian Nash Equilibrium

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015

Cournot s model of oligopoly

Competition and Regulation. Lecture 2: Background on imperfect competition

Games of Incomplete Information

Week 7 - Game Theory and Industrial Organisation

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 2: Strategic Form Games

Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly]

Industry profit in an oligopoly (sum of all firms profits) < monopoly profit.

Games of Incomplete Information

Backward Induction and Subgame Perfection

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

0.0.2 Pareto Efficiency (Sec. 4, Ch. 1 of text)

6.207/14.15: Networks Lectures 19-21: Incomplete Information: Bayesian Nash Equilibria, Auctions and Introduction to Social Learning

Equilibrium: Illustrations

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly. Oligopoly is a market structure in which the number of sellers is small.

Oligopoly: Cournot/Bertrand/Stackelberg

AN INTRODUCTION TO GAME THEORY

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Games Manipulators Play

Customer Service Quality and Incomplete Information in Mobile Telecommunications: A Game Theoretical Approach to Consumer Protection.

UCLA. Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

Market Structure: Duopoly and Oligopoly

Sanna-Randaccio LECTURE 22 : NON TARIFF BARRIERS

I. Noncooperative Oligopoly

ECON Game Theory Exam 1 - Answer Key. 4) All exams must be turned in by 1:45 pm. No extensions will be granted.

ECON101 STUDY GUIDE 7 CHAPTER 14

The Basics of Game Theory

Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting Ù

LATE AND MULTIPLE BIDDING IN SECOND PRICE INTERNET AUCTIONS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE CONCERNING DIFFERENT RULES FOR ENDING AN AUCTION

Mixed oligopoly and collusion

Managerial Economics

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE

Simon Fraser University Spring Econ 302 D200 Final Exam Solution Instructor: Songzi Du Tuesday April 21, 2015, 12 3 PM

Rent-Seeking and Corruption

CPC/CPA Hybrid Bidding in a Second Price Auction

Chapter 9. Auctions. 9.1 Types of Auctions

LECTURE #15: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 17

Chapter 16 Oligopoly What Is Oligopoly? 1) Describe the characteristics of an oligopoly.

Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium

Optimal Auctions Continued

8 Modeling network traffic using game theory

When other firms see these potential profits they will enter the industry, causing a downward shift in the demand for a given firm s product.

13 MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Chapter. Key Concepts

Oligopoly: Firms in Less Competitive Markets

Chapter 12 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

1 Representation of Games. Kerschbamer: Commitment and Information in Games

Equilibrium Bids in Sponsored Search. Auctions: Theory and Evidence

How to Solve Strategic Games? Dominant Strategies

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 10: Extensive Games: Critiques and Extensions

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 1: Introduction

Do not open this exam until told to do so.

Internet Advertising and the Generalized Second Price Auction:

ECO 199 B GAMES OF STRATEGY Spring Term 2004 PROBLEM SET 4 B DRAFT ANSWER KEY

9.1 Cournot and Bertrand Models with Homogeneous Products

Oligopoly markets: The price or quantity decisions by one rm has to directly in uence pro ts by other rms if rms are competing for customers.

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Game Theory Problem Set - Dynamic Games

How To Play A Static Bayesian Game

Chapter 14. Oligopoly

Game Theory: Supermodular Games 1

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

Exercises for Industrial Organization Master de Economía Industrial Matilde Pinto Machado

Economics 159: Introduction to Game Theory. Summer 2015: Session A. Online Course

Promote Cooperation. Job Market Paper

Game Mining: How to Make Money from those about to Play a Game

Sharing Online Advertising Revenue with Consumers

9 Repeated Games. Tomorrow, and tomorrow, and tomorrow, Creeps in this petty pace from day to day To the last syllable of recorded time Shakespeare

Math Quizzes Winter 2009

FINAL EXAM, Econ 171, March, 2015, with answers

Chapter 7: The Costs of Production QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW

Vickrey-Dutch Procurement Auction for Multiple Items

A Full Participation Agreement On Global Emission Reduction Through Strategic Investments in R&D

Game among Mobile Operators, Bank and the Third-party Payment Services Provider in Mobile Payment Market

Lecture V: Mixed Strategies

Optimal Auctions. Jonathan Levin 1. Winter Economics 285 Market Design. 1 These slides are based on Paul Milgrom s.

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Lecture 28 Economics 181 International Trade

The Ascending Auction Paradox

12 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly

Extreme cases. In between cases

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

The Impact of Group Purchasing Organizations on. Healthcare-Product Supply Chains

Economics 203: Intermediate Microeconomics I Lab Exercise #11. Buy Building Lease F1 = 500 F1 = 750 Firm 2 F2 = 500 F2 = 400

Christmas Gift Exchange Games

A Theory of Auction and Competitive Bidding

Chapter 13: Strategic Decision Making in Oligopoly Markets

chapter: Oligopoly Krugman/Wells Economics 2009 Worth Publishers 1 of 35

Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models

Oligopoly and Game Theory

Microeconomic Theory Jamison / Kohlberg / Avery Problem Set 4 Solutions Spring (a) LEFT CENTER RIGHT TOP 8, 5 0, 0 6, 3 BOTTOM 0, 0 7, 6 6, 3

How To Understand The Theory Of Economic Theory

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Summary of Doctoral Dissertation: Voluntary Participation Games in Public Good Mechanisms: Coalitional Deviations and Efficiency

4. Market Structures. Learning Objectives Market Structures

Analytical Model for Analyzing Construction Claims and Opportunistic Bidding

MobLab Game Catalog For Business Schools Fall, 2015

Transcription:

UC Berkeley Fall 007 Economics 01A - Section 6 1 What we learnt this week Marina Halac Basics: trigger strategy Classes of games: infinitely repeated games, static Bayesian games Solution concepts: subgame perfect Nash euilibrium, Bayesian Nash euilibrium Applications: auction model Problems Problem 1: Infinitely repeated asymmetric prisoners dilemma Consider an infinitely repeated game with discount factor δ and the following stage-game C D C 3, -1, 3 D 5, -1 0, 0 (i) What are the payoffs in the worst possible SPNE? (ii) What is the lowest discount factor δ for which the players achieve cooperation in a SPNE? (iii) Is it possible to achieve payoffs better than (0, 0) in a SPNE for discount factors lower than δ? Hint: Think about a SPNE in which the players alternate between (C, D) and (D, C) on the euilibrium path. Problem : Euilibria with payoffs worse than Nash Consider an infinitely repeated game with discount factor δ and the following stage-game D E D 0,0-1,-1 E -1,-1 -,- Assume δ 1/. Can (E,E) be played in a SPNE? Note that (E,E) gives payoffs (-,-) which are lower than the payoffs achieved in the stage-game Nash euilibrium, (0,0). If your answer is yes, propose strategies that sustain (E,E) in some period in a SPNE. If your answer is no, prove it. Problem 3: Cournot oligopoly Let Y k be player k s payoff in his worst Nash euilibrium of the stage game. Let D k (a 1,..., a N ) max a Ak U k (a 1,..., a k 1, a, a k+1,..., a N ). In problem 11 of Problem Set Nagano, you are asked to prove the following theorem: Consider a stage-game G and an action profile of G, (a 1,..., a N ), with D payoffs (X 1, X,..., X N ) such that X k > Y k. Then for all δ > max k X k k D k Y k, there exists a SPNE of G(T=,δ) where players play (a 1,..., a N ) each period. 1

Now consider n firms in a Cournot oligopoly. Inverse demand is given by P (Q) = a Q, where Q = 1 +... + n. Total costs for firm i are c i ( i ) = c i. Consider the infinitely repeated game based on this stage game. Using the theorem above, find the lowest value of δ such that the firms can sustain the monopoly output level in a SPNE. How does you answer vary with n? Problem 4: Bayesian game C D A x,y 4,5 B,y x,3 Let x {3, 5} and y {4, 6}, independently drawn. Both values of x and both values of y are eually likely. Suppose that each player knows his own payoff: player 1 observes x and player observes y. Player 1 does not observe y and player does not observe x. Find the BNE. Problem 5: Cournot with asymmetric information (Gibbons 3.) Consider a Cournot duopoly operating in a market with inverse demand P (Q) = a Q, where Q = 1 + is the aggregate uantity on the market. Both firms have total costs c i ( i ) = c i, but demand is uncertain: it is high (a = a H ) with probability θ and low (a = a L ) with probability 1 θ. Furthermore, information is asymmetric: firm 1 knows whether demand is high or low, but firm does not. All of this is common knowledge. The two firms simultaneously choose uantities. What are the strategy spaces for the two firms? Make assumptions concerning a H, a L, θ, and c such that all euilibrium uantities are positive. What is the BNE of this game? Problem 6: Second-price auction (MWG 8B3) Consider the following action (known as second-price or Vickrey auction). An object is auctioned off to I bidders. Bidder i s valuation of the object is v i. Each bidder observes only his own valuation. The auction rules are that each player submit a bid (a nonnegative number) in a sealed envelope. The envelopes are then opened, and the bidder who has submitted the highest bid gets the object but pays the auctioneer the amount of the second highest bid. If more than one bidder submits the highest bid, each gets the object with eual probability. Show that submitting a bid of v i with certainty is a weakly dominant strategy for bidder i. Also argue that this is bidder i s uniue weakly dominant strategy. Problem 7: First-price auction Consider a first-price sealed-bid auction of an object with two bidders. Each bidder i s valuation of the object is v i. Each bidder observes only his own valuation. The valuation is distributed uniformly and independently on [0, 1] for each bidder. The auction rules are that each player submit a bid in a sealed envelope. The envelopes are then opened, and the bidder who has submitted the highest bid gets the object and pays the auctioneer the amount of his bid. If the bidders submit the same bid, each gets the object with probability 1/. Derive the BNE of this auction. Hint: Look for an euilibrium in which bidder i s strategy is b i (v i ) = c i v i for some constant c i.

3 Answers Problem 1 (i) The payoffs in the worst SPNE are (0, 0). They are achieved by the repetition of the stagegame Nash euilibrium (D,D). It is not possible to achieve payoffs worse than 0 since either player can always guarantee himself a payoff of at least 0 by playing D in every period. (ii) According to part (a) the worst available punishment has a payoff of 0 for both players. So for neither player to want to deviate from (C, C), both of the following conditions must hold 5 3/(1 δ) δ /5 (deviation of player 1) 3 /(1 δ) δ 1/3 (deviation of player ) We find that δ = /5. (iii) Yes. Define the following regimes: regime 1: play (C, D); regime : play (D, C). Then consider the following strategies (for each player): Start in regime 1. If the outcome in regime 1 is (C,D), go to regime ; otherwise, play (D,D) forever. If the outcome in regime is (D,C), go to regime 1; otherwise, play (D,D) forever. We now prove that there exists δ < δ for which these strategies constitute a SPNE with payoffs better than (0,0). In this SPNE, the players alternate between (C,D) and (D,C) as long as neither player deviates, and deviations are punished by the stage-game Nash euilibrium forever. For no player to want to deviate in any regime, the following conditions must hold 3 5 δ + 5δ δ 3... = (5 δ)/(1 δ ) always holds (player 1 in regime (D,C)) 0 1 + 3δ δ + 3δ 3... = ( 1 + 3δ)/(1 δ ) holds if δ 1/3 (player in regime (D,C)) 0 1 + 5δ δ + 5δ 3... = ( 1 + 5δ)/(1 δ ) holds if δ 1/5 (player 1 in regime (C,D)) 3 δ + 3δ δ 3... = (3 δ)/(1 δ ) always holds (player in regime (C,D)) Note also that no player deviates from (D,D) (in the subgame following deviation) as (D,D) is a Nash euilibrium of the stage game. Hence, a SPNE in which the players alternate between (C, D) and (D, C) exists if δ 1/3 (note that 1/3 < δ ). If players start in regime (C, D), they get strictly positive payoffs of ( 1 + 5δ)/(1 δ ) and (3 δ)/(1 δ ). Problem The answer is yes. For δ 1/, a SPNE that implements (E,E) in some period exists. Define the following regimes: regime 1: play (E,E); regime : play (D,D). Consider the following strategies (for each player): Start in regime 1. If outcome is (E,E) in regime 1, go to regime. Otherwise, stay in regime 1. Regime is absorbing. We check that neither player wants to deviate in regimes 1 and. Regime is a repetition of a stage-game Nash euilibrium, so no player has incentives to deviate. In regime 1, if a player does not deviate, his payoff is. If a player deviates once, his payoff is 1 δ + 0δ +... = 1 δ Hence, a SPNE in which the players play (E,E) in the first period exists if δ 1/. (Note that I used the One-Stage Deviation Principle: In a repeated game, a combination of players strategies s is a SPNE iff no player can gain by deviating in a single stage, and confirming to s thereafter.) 3

Problem 3 The monopoly output is Q M = (a c)/. Thus, if the n firms share the monopoly output eually, each produces M = (a c)/(n), with profit π M = (a c) 4n A firm s optimal stage-game deviation, D, when the n 1 other firms choose M is D = arg max (a (n 1) a c n c) = n + 1 (a c) 4n This gives the deviator a profit level of π D = (n + 1) 16n (a c) The uniue stage-game NE is for each firm to choose i = arg max i (a i j c) = a j i j c i j i Solving the system of euations, the n-firm Cournot NE outcome involves each firm producing C = (a c)/(n + 1), with profit π C = (a c) (n + 1) Consider the proposed trigger-strategy for each player: Play M in period 1. In period t, play M if all firms have played M in all previous periods; play C otherwise. Using the theorem above, these trigger strategies constitute a SPNE if 1 16n 4n 1 16n δ πd π M (n+1) π D π C = (n+1) (n+1) δ Note that δ 1 as n. Hence, collusion is harder to sustain when there are more firms. Problem 4 Each player has two types: T 1 = {t 1L, t 1H }, where t 1L knows that x = 3 and t 1H knows that x = 5, and T = {t L, t H }, where t L knows that y = 4 and t H knows that y = 6. To find the BNE, note that for type t 1L, playing A strictly dominates playing B (regardless of his belief about player s action, A is t 1L s best response), and for type t H, playing C strictly dominates playing D. Hence, in any BNE, t 1L plays A and t H plays C. Consider next type t 1H. His expected payoff from playing A is 5p 1 (s = C t 1H ) + 4(1 p 1 (s = C t 1H )) = 4 + p 1 (s = C t 1H ) 4

and his expected payoff from playing B is p 1 (s = C t 1H ) + 5(1 p 1 (s = C t 1H )) = 5 3p 1 (s = C t 1H ) Thus, for t 1H, playing A is a best response iff the probability that player plays C is at least 1/4. Now note that in euilibrium, the probability that player plays C is always greater than 1/4, since for any [0, 1], p 1 (s = C t 1H ) = p 1 (t H t 1H ).1 + p 1 (t L t 1H ) = 1/ + / 1/ Hence, in any BNE, t 1H plays A. Finally, consider type t L. Regardless of what player 1 does, the payoff from playing C is always y = 4 for this type. His expected payoff from playing D is U (s 1L, D; t 1L, t L )p (t 1L t L ) + U (s 1H, D; t 1H, t L )p (t 1H t L ) = U (A, D; t 1L, t L )p (t 1L t L ) + U (A, D; t 1H, t L )p (t 1H t L ) = 5 > 4 Hence, in any BNE, t L plays D. We have found that there exists a uniue BNE with (s 1L, s 1H, s L, s H ) = (A, A, D, C). Problem 5 Firm 1 s strategy space is [0, ) [0, ), and firm s strategy space is [0, ). The strategies (1L, 1H, ) constitute a BNE iff 1L = arg max 1H = arg max = arg max (a L c), (a H c), and θ(a H 1H c) + (1 θ)(a L 1L c) The three first-order conditions are: 1L = a L c, 1H = a H c, and = θa H + (1 θ)a L c (θ1h + (1 θ) 1L ) Therefore, the uniue BNE is: ( (1L, 1H, ) θah + ( + θ)a L c =, (3 θ)a H (1 θ)a L c, θa ) H + (1 θ)a L c 6 6 3 Problem 6 We prove that bidding v i is at least as good as any other bid no matter what other bids are. Consider an alternative bid b i > v i. Case 1: There is another bid higher than b i. Then neither of the bids wins the auction and so both give a payoff of 0. Case : The second highest bid is less than v i. Then bidder i wins the auction and pays the same second highest bid in both cases. Both bids give the same payoff. Case 3: The highest bid of other players is between v i and b i. Then bid v i would lose the auction and give a payoff of 0. Bid b i would win the auction but the bidder would 5

have to pay more than his valuation, obtaining a negative payoff. Hence, bidding b i > v i is weakly dominated by bidding v i. Consider next an alternative bid b i < v i. Case 1: There is another bid higher than v i. Then neither of the bids wins the auction and so both give a payoff of 0. Case : The second highest bid is less than b i. Then bidder i wins the auction and pays the same second highest bid in both cases. Both bids give the same payoff. Case 3: The highest bid of other players is between b i and v i. Then bid b i would lose the auction and give a payoff of 0. Bid v i would win the auction and the bidder would have to pay less than his valuation, obtaining a positive payoff. Hence, bidding b i < v i is weakly dominated by bidding v i. This argument implies that bidding v i is the uniue weakly dominant strategy for player i. Problem 7 Following the hint, suppose player j s strategy is b j (v j ) = c j v j. For a given value of v i, player i s best response solves max b i (v i b i )Pr(b i > b j ) = (v i b i )Pr(b i > c j v j ) (Note that we can ignore a tie since Pr(b i = b j ) = 0 because b j (v j ) = c j v j and v j is uniformly distributed, so b j is uniformly distributed.) Now note that Pr(b i > c j v j ) = Pr(v j < b i /c j ) = b i /c j where the last euality uses b i /c j [0, 1], which follows from the fact that player i would not bid below 0 nor above c j. Hence, player i s best response is b i (v i ) = v i / The same analysis for player j yields b j (v j ) = v j / So each player submits a bid eual to half his valuation. This reflects the trade-off that a player faces in an auction: the higher the bid, the more likely to win; the lower the bid, the larger the gain if the player wins. 6