The Role of Institutional Investors in Open-Market. Share Repurchase Programs



Similar documents
Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits

Institutional Trading, Brokerage Commissions, and Information Production around Stock Splits

Institutional Investors and the Information Production Theory of Stock Splits

Why Do Firms Announce Open-Market Repurchase Programs?

Examining Share Repurchasing and the S&P Buyback Indices in the U.S. Market

How Do Institutional Investors Trade When Firms Buy Back Their Shares?

INFORMATION CONTENT OF SHARE REPURCHASE PROGRAMS

Common Stock Repurchases: Case of Stock Exchange of Thailand

Market Share. Open. Repurchases in CANADA 24 WINTER 2002 CANADIAN INVESTMENT REVIEW

Empirical Evidence on the Existence of Dividend Clienteles EDITH S. HOTCHKISS* STEPHEN LAWRENCE** Boston College. July 2007.

Share buybacks have grown

ACCOUNTING, ECONOMICS AND FINANCE. School Working Papers Series 2004 SWP 2004/16

THE REPURCHASE OF SHARES - ANOTHER FORM OF REWARDING INVESTORS - A THEORETICAL APPROACH

Some Insider Sales Are Positive Signals

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 9 Number 2 Summer 1996

FIN 423/523 Repurchase Tender Offers

Costless Versus Costly Signaling: Theory and Evidence from Share Repurchases *

Market Timing Ability of Indian Firms in Open Market Repurchases

Internet Appendix to. Why does the Option to Stock Volume Ratio Predict Stock Returns? Li Ge, Tse-Chun Lin, and Neil D. Pearson.

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Do Firms Buy Their Stock at Bargain Prices? Evidence from Actual Stock Repurchase Disclosures +

Stock Repurchases in Japan

The role of institutional investors in seasoned equity offerings

Dividends, Share Repurchases, and the Substitution Hypothesis

EXPLOITING EXCESS RETURNS FROM SHARE BUYBACK ANNOUNCEMENTS

The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence. from French firms

How To Find Out If Stock Repurchases Improve Performance

Is there Information Content in Insider Trades in the Singapore Exchange?

Costless Versus Costly Signaling: Theory and Evidence from Share Repurchases *

Institutional Trading, Information Production, and the SEO Discount: A Model of Seasoned Equity Offerings

DOES IT PAY TO HAVE FAT TAILS? EXAMINING KURTOSIS AND THE CROSS-SECTION OF STOCK RETURNS

Investor Performance in ASX shares; contrasting individual investors to foreign and domestic. institutions. 1


Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Measures of implicit trading costs and buy sell asymmetry

The Stock Market s Reaction to Accounting Information: The Case of the Latin American Integrated Market. Abstract

BASKET A collection of securities. The underlying securities within an ETF are often collectively referred to as a basket

Understanding Leverage in Closed-End Funds

The Information Content of Stock Splits *

Has the Propensity to Pay Out Declined?

Virtual Stock Market Game Glossary

Stock Market Liquidity and Firm Dividend Policy

Internet Appendix for Institutional Trade Persistence and Long-term Equity Returns

Closed-End Funds. A closed-end fund is a type of investment company. whose shares are listed on a stock exchange

Overview of Financial 1-1. Statement Analysis

SPDR S&P 400 Mid Cap Value ETF

Is Market Timing Good for Shareholders?

Accelerated Share Repurchases. Leonce Bargeron Katz Graduate School of Business University of Pittsburgh

The effect of real earnings management on the information content of earnings

How to Estimate the Effect of a Stock Repurchase on Share Price

APPLE HOSPITALITY REIT, INC. (Exact name of registrant as specified in its charter)

Glossary of Investment Terms

THE EFFECT ON RIVALS WHEN FIRMS EMERGE FROM BANKRUPTCY

Evidence and Implications of Increases in Trading Volume around Seasoned Equity Offerings

on share price performance

SOLUTIONS TO END-OF-CHAPTER PROBLEMS. Chapter % Debt; 30% Equity; Capital Budget = $3,000,000; NI = $2,000,000; PO =? = = $2.50.

On Existence of An Optimal Stock Price : Evidence from Stock Splits and Reverse Stock Splits in Hong Kong

About Our Private Investment Benchmarks

CHAPTER 17. Payout Policy. Chapter Synopsis

Equity Opportunity Trust Value Select Ten Series 2008A (A Unit Investment Trust)

The Journal of Applied Business Research Winter 2005 Volume 21, Number 1

SPDR S&P Software & Services ETF

CHAPTER 8 STOCK VALUATION

9 Questions Every ETF Investor Should Ask Before Investing

Management Quality, Venture Capital Backing, and Initial Public Offerings

Primary Market - Place where the sale of new stock first occurs. Initial Public Offering (IPO) - First offering of stock to the general public.

Financial ratio analysis

SPDR Wells Fargo Preferred Stock ETF

First Quarter 2015 Earnings Conference Call. 20 February 2015

XUAN TIAN. TEACHING: Corporate Finance, Entrepreneurial Finance, Financial Institutions, Investments, and Capital Markets

Trade on the news? Information Trading"

The Hidden Costs of Changing Indices

Corporate Income Taxation

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

On the Conditioning of the Financial Market s Reaction to Seasoned Equity Offerings *

3. LITERATURE REVIEW

Managerial Entrenchment and Open-Market Share. Repurchases: The Case of Taiwan

The Master of Science in Finance (English Program) - MSF. Department of Banking and Finance. Chulalongkorn Business School. Chulalongkorn University

Third Quarter 2015 Earnings Conference Call. 21 August 2015

Examining Share Repurchasing and the S&P Buyback Indices

Delphi Management, Inc. Firm Brochure (Part 2A of Form ADV)

Advantages and disadvantages of investing in the Stock Market

Managerial Decisions and Long- Term Stock Price Performance*

Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow and Takeover Attempts

Shares Outstanding and Cross-Sectional Returns *

How To Calculate Financial Leverage Ratio

Large Cap Stock Funds

How To Know If A Buyback

How To Explain Why Share Repurchase Is More Profitable In The United Kingdom

The Real Effects of Share Repurchases

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS ABOUT RULE 10b - 18 AND STOCK REPURCHASE PROGRAMS

Off-Market Buybacks in Australia: Evidence of Abnormal Trading around Key Dates

Cash Holdings and Mutual Fund Performance. Online Appendix

The Market Reaction to Stock Split Announcements: Earnings Information After All

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 7

Analysts Recommendations and Insider Trading

Are High-Quality Firms Also High-Quality Investments?

Purpose of Selling Stocks Short JANUARY 2007 NUMBER 5

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications

Transcription:

The Role of Institutional Investors in Open-Market Share Repurchase Programs Thomas J. Chemmanur Yingzhen Li February 15, 2015 Professor of Finance, Fulton Hall 330, Carroll School of Management, Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467. Phone: 617-552-3980. Fax: 617-552-0431. E-mail: chemmanu@bc.edu. The Brattle Group. Phone: 415-217-1000. E-mail: Yingzhen.Li@Brattle.com. For helpful comments and discussions, we thank Sugata Roychowdhury. We are responsible for any remaining errors or omissions.

The Role of Institutional Investors in Open-Market Share Repurchase Programs Abstract Theoretical papers such as Brennan and Thakor (1990) argue that large investors such as institutions produce information about firms around stock repurchases. In this article, we use a large sample of transaction-level institutional trading data and the data on US firms actual repurchases made available by the 2003 revisions to the Exchange Act to test this assumption about open-market repurchase programs (OMRs) for the first time in the literature. We document several results new to the literature. First, institutional trading prior to an OMR announcement has significant predictive power for the magnitude of the abnormal return to the firm s equity around OMR announcements. Second, institutional trading immediately after an OMR announcement has significant predictive power for the firm s subsequent stock return performance: the larger the net buying by institutions, better the subsequent long-run stock returns. Third, institutions are able to realize significant abnormal profits (net of commissions and trading costs) by trading in the equity of firms undergoing open-market repurchases. Fourth, institutional trading immediately after an OMR announcement has significant predictive power for the actual repurchases by the firm: a larger amount of buying of the firm s equity by institutions is associated with a larger actual repurchase by the firm in the subsequent period. Finally, institutional trading has predictive power for the change in the firm s information asymmetry from before the OMR announcement to after: a larger amount of net buying by institutions is associated with a larger decrease in the degree of information asymmetry facing the firm in the equity market. Overall, our results are consistent with the notion that institutional investors are able to generate a significant information advantage for themselves about firms undergoing open-market repurchases. JEL Classification: G23, G35 Keywords: Open-Market Repurchases; Institutional Trading; Information Production

1 Introduction In recent years, the number of firms undertaking stock repurchases has increased dramatically, while the proportion of firms distributing value through cash dividends has declined (see, e.g., Fama and French (2001)). The popularity of share repurchases has not been mitigated even after the passage of the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Act of 2003 in the U.S. which cut the dividend tax rate to 15%, thus substantially reducing the tax disadvantage of dividend payments to investors (see, e.g., Chetty and Saez (2006)). Open-market repurchases (OMRs) constitute around 90% of the stock repurchases consummated in recent years: see, e.g., Comment and Jarrell (1991) or Grullon and Michaely (2004). An interesting question in this context is regarding the precise economic role played by repurchase programs in general and OMR programs in particular in maximizing shareholder value. The rationale for repurchase programs given by the existing literature is that they serve to signal firm insiders private information about the intrinsic value of the firm to outsiders in the equity market: see, e.g., Vermaelen (1981), Ofer and Thakor (1987), and Constantinides and Grundy (1989). 1 One interesting question in the above context is the role of institutional investors. The theoretical model of Brennan and Thakor (1990) assumes that large investors such as institutions have the ability to produce information about firms in the context of their choice of payment method between open-market repurchases, dividends, and tender o ers. 2 If institutional investors do indeed possess the ability to produce information about firms undergoing OMR programs, how does this information interact with that of firm insiders? To the best of our knowledge, there has been no paper in the literature that empirically analyzes whether institutions indeed have the ability to produce information about firms announcing OMR 1 Most of these signaling models assume that the firm commits to buy a certain number of shares, as in the case in Dutch auction or tender o er repurchase programs. See, however, Oded (2005), who develops a theoretical model demonstrating that, under suitable assumptions, open-market share repurchase programs can signal firm insiders private information even in the absence of a commitment by the firm to repurchase the entire amount of equity authorized to be repurchased by its board. 2 Brennan and Thakor (1990), however, do not assume any private information held by firm insiders about its intrinsic value. 1

programs, and how their information interacts with the private information held by firm insiders (which they may attempt to convey to the equity market through a repurchase program). The objective of this paper is to fill this gap in the literature. The economic setting we consider to develop our empirical analysis can be described as follows. Consider a situation where the insiders of a firm, having private information about its intrinsic value, are considering whether or not to undertake an open-market repurchase program. Let there be two types of outside investors in the equity market. The first type of investors are institutional investors, who have the ability to produce noisy information about the firm (at a cost). The precision of information produced by institutions is lower than that of the private information held by firm insiders, so that, while information production helps institutions reduce their information disadvantage with respect to firm insiders, it does not eliminate it. The second type of investors are retail investors, who do not have any ability to produce information about the intrinsic value of the firm, and are therefore at a disadvantage with respect to both institutions and insiders. Retail investors are essentially liquidity traders in the equity market in the economic setting we study here, similar to their role in market microstructure models such as Kyle (1985). The price of the firm s stock in the equity market is set by a market maker who is uninformed to begin with, but who sets the stock price to break even (after observing the aggregate order flow of trades in the firm s equity), again similar to the price-setting rule in market microstructure models. While the market maker cannot fully separate informed and uninformed trades, the price of the firm s equity will reflect, to some degree, the information held by institutional investors. 3 We address the following research questions in the above economic setting. First, do institutions have the ability to produce information about a firm prior to its announcing an OMR program? We address this question by analyzing whether institutional trading prior 3 The above economic environment that we postulate here is very similar to that of the theoretical model of Chemmanur and Jiao (2011), who, however, focus on the theoretically analyzing on the implications of institutional trading around seasoned equity o erings. Given the absence of any formal theoretical analysis of open-market stock repurchases in an economic environment similar to the above, we choose to adapt the analysis of Chemmanur and Jiao (2011) to the case of open-market repurchases in order to develop testable hypotheses for our empirical analysis. 2

to an OMR program announcement has predictive power for the announcement e ect of such a program. Second, do institutions have the ability to produce information about a firm immediately after its announcing an OMR program, and are they able to profit from this information? We address this question by studying the predictive power of institutional trading immediately after an OMR program for the subsequent long-run performance of the firm s equity and also the profitability of such trading. We also address this research question by analyzing the predictive power of institutional trading immediately after an OMR program announcement for the actual repurchases made by the firm in the subsequent period. Finally, we analyze how institutional trading immediately after an OMR program announcement a ects the change in the information asymmetry faced by the firm from before the announcement of the OMR program to after. As we discuss in detail in Section 3, the last analysis allows us to address the question of how the information produced by institutions interacts with the private information of insiders that is conveyed through the OMR program. We make use of a detailed transaction-level institutional trading database provided by Abel Noser Solutions (formerly Ancerno Ltd., or Abel/Noser Corporation) to address the above research questions. Our data includes transactional-level trading data spanning twelve years from January 2003 to September 2011 originated from 868 di erent institutions, with an aggregate annualized trading principal of around $9 trillion on all U.S. domestic equity. For an average open-market repurchase event, our sample institutions collectively account for about 12% of the CRSP-reported trading volume within the two-year period surrounding the open-market repurchase announcement. With this dataset, we are able to track institutional trading both before and after an open-market repurchase announcement. We are also able to compute realized institutional trading profitability net of explicit trading costs (i.e., brokerage commissions) and implicit trading costs (i.e., market impact). Throughout this paper, we use a variable we call Net Buy to measure institutional trading. We define Net Buy as the number of shares purchased by institutions minus the number of shares sold by 3

institutions, normalized by the number of shares outstanding. Our paper provides a number of new results on the role of institutional investors around open-market repurchases. We organize our empirical tests and results into five parts, corresponding to the five sets of research questions outlined above. First, we study, for the first time in the literature, the informativeness of institutional trading before the announcement of an open-market repurchase program. We find that institutional trading before an openmarket repurchase announcement has considerable predictive power for announcement e ect of programs. Greater selling by institutional investors is significantly associated with a more favorable announcement e ect. This result is robust to controlling for various variables that have been found in the prior literature to be able to predict announcement e ects of openmarket repurchase programs, including prior firm performance and insider trading. This suggests that institutional investors possess private information about the intrinsic value of the firms announcing open-market repurchase programs. Second, we study the predictive power of institutional trading immediately after openmarket repurchase announcements (two quarters) for the firm s subsequent long-run (one year) performance, again for the first time in the literature. We find that institutional trading immediately after an open-market repurchase announcement has considerable predictive power for the firm s subsequent long-run stock performance: a 1% increase in institutional net buying is associated with about 0.4% increase in the firm s abnormal stock return over the subsequent one-year period. This result is robust to controlling for various variables capturing publicly available information, as well as the extent of trading in the firm s equity by insiders. The above result indicates that institutions have a residual information advantage over retail investors, even after the announcement of an open-market repurchase program. Third, we study the realized profitability of institutional trading around open-market repurchase programs, using actual transaction prices and net of brokerage commissions, for the first time in the literature. We find that institutions make positive abnormal profits after the announcement of an open-market program, even after taking commissions and other 4

trading costs into account. This is especially the case when the information conveyed by the announcement of an open-market program is noisier (i.e., when the size of the repurchase program is smaller or when the firm actually repurchases less subsequent to the announcement). For example, over the one-year horizon after an open-market repurchase program announcement, our sample institutions on average realize a risk-adjusted return of 1% when the size of the repurchase program is smaller (i.e., below the sample median), and they realize a risk-adjusted return of 0.8% when the firm actually repurchases less subsequent to the announcement (i.e., below the sample median). These results suggest that the information advantage possessed by institutional investors after an open-market repurchase announcement that we documented earlier translates into real trading profits, especially when the information conveyed by the open-market repurchase announcement made by the firm is noisier (i.e., when the size of the repurchase program is smaller or when the firm actually repurchases less subsequent to the announcement). In summary, we are able to show not only that institutions possess an information advantage after open-market repurchase announcements, but are also able to translate this advantage into real trading profits even after accounting for both explicit (brokerage commissions) and implicit (market impact) trading costs. Fourth, we study the predictive power of institutional trading immediately after openmarket repurchase announcements for the actual repurchases made by the firm in the subsequent period, again for the first time in the literature. We find that institutional trading immediately after an open-market repurchase announcement has considerable predictive power for the subsequent actual repurchases made by the firm: a 1% increase in institutional net buying is associated with about 3% increase in the firm s actual repurchase over the subsequent two-quarter period. This result is robust to controlling for various variables capturing publicly available information, as well as the extent of trading in the firm s equity by insiders. The above result again indicates that institutions have a residual information advantage over retail investors, even after the announcement of an open-market repurchase 5

program. Finally, we examine how institutional trading around open-market repurchase programs a ects the information asymmetry faced by the firm in the equity market. We find that institutional trading over the two-quarter period immediately after an open-market repurchase program announcement has considerable predictive power for the reduction in information asymmetry faced by the firm around the repurchase program announcement (i.e., from before the announcement to after). Greater net buying by institutional investors is associated with more analyst coverage (i.e., more analysts covering the firm) and lower analyst forecasts dispersion (i.e., more precise analyst forecasts), two of the proxies for information asymmetry widely used in the literature. These results indicate that the information conveyed by institutional trading subsequent to open-market repurchase program announcements plays an additional role in reducing the information asymmetry faced by the firm, over and above that of the repurchase announcement itself in reducing this information asymmetry. What do we learn from the above empirical results about the role of institutional investors as information producers around open-market repurchase programs? First, the fact that institutional trading has predictive power for the announcement e ects of open-market repurchase programs, for the long-run stock return performance of the firm subsequent to the announcement of such programs, and for the actual repurchases made by the firm indicates that they have information advantage over retail investors both before and after the announcement of an open-market repurchase program. It should be noted that institutional investors continue to possess this information advantage over retail investors even after an open-market repurchase program announcement, which may convey firm insiders private information as well. Second, our results indicate that institutions are able to use their information advantage to realize abnormal profits by trading in the equity of firms undergoing open-market repurchase programs, especially when the size of the open-market repurchase program is smaller or when the firm makes less actual repurchase subsequent to the announcement of the repurchase program. It is worth noting that we are able to generate the 6

above results mainly because we utilize transaction-level institutional trading data, which also enable us to account for both explicit (brokerage commissions) and implicit (market impact) trading costs of institutional investors. Finally, our results of the e ect of institutional trading on the reduction in the information asymmetry facing the firm in the equity market around open-market repurchase programs indicate that not only do institutional investors have information advantage relative to retail investors around such programs, they are also able to reduce this information asymmetry facing the firms by trading in the equity of firms undergoing such repurchase programs. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 relates this paper to the existing literature. Section 3 develops testable hypotheses about institutional trading around openmarket repurchases. Section 4 describes the data and various variables used in this study. Section 5 presents empirical tests and results on institutional trading around open-market repurchases. Section 6 concludes. 2 Relation to the Existing Literature Our paper lies in the intersection of two literatures. The first is the literature on openmarket repurchases. 4 Under an asymmetric information framework, Ofer and Thakor (1987) develop a model in which firms could signal their value through two mechanisms, paying dividends or repurchasing their shares. In their model, the signaling costs through repurchases are higher and thus repurchases are a stronger signal perceived by the equity market. Oded (2005) o ers some theoretical insights on why a price increase accompanies the announcement of an open-market stock repurchase program, even though the announcement of an OMR program is not a commitment to buy back all the shares authorized. In his model, firms face a trade-o between the long-run gains from the informed trading that the option to repurchase shares creates and the short-run costs from the market s accounting for this 4 To the extent that an open-market repurchase program is a form of cash distribution, our paper is also related to the broader literature on payout policy: see Allen and Michaely (2003) for an extensive review on the payout policy literature. 7

adverse selection. Under this trade-o, only good firms announce open-market repurchase programs, so that the announcement of an OMR program acts as a credible signal. On the empirical side, Dann (1981) notes that the announcement of open market share repurchase programs tends to be preceded by a recent decline in the announcing firms stock price. Comment and Jarrell (1991) study the relative signaling power of Dutch-auction, selftender o ers and open-market repurchases. Ikenberry, Lakonishok, and Vermaelen (1995) study long-run stock returns following OMR announcements. Nevertheless, there has been no study in the literature analyzing the role of institutional investors as information producers around open market share repurchase programs. 5 The second literature our paper is related to is the theoretical and empirical literature on institutional trading and information production by institutional investors around corporate events. Chemmanur and Jiao (2011) develop a model of institutional trading and information production around SEOs. Gibson, Safieddine, and Sonti (2004) and Chemmanur, He, and Hu (2009) empirically analyze institutional trading around SEOs. Ours is, however, the only paper to study institutional trading around open-market repurchases, and the only one to make use of transaction-level institutional trading data. While this is not the primary focus, our paper also contributes to the broader literature on the determinants of the extent of information production by outsiders about a firm. Anumberofauthorshavedevelopedtheoreticalanalysesabouttheincentivesofoutsiders to acquire information about a firm (see, e.g., Grossman (1976), Grossman and Stiglitz (1980), Diamond and Verrecchia (1981), Verrecchia (1982), Admati and Pfleiderer (1986), and Bhushan (1989a)). There have also been a number of empirical analyses regarding the extent of information production by analysts about a firm (see, e.g., Bhushan (1989b), O Brien and Bhushan (1990), Lang and Lundholm (1996)) and the informativeness or accu- 5 Two other contemporaneous papers also study trading by institutional investors around stock repurchases. DeLisle, Morscheck, and Nofsinger (2014) document that institutional investors are net sellers during share repurchases. In a similar spirit, Huang and Zhang (2013) show that institutions sell after share repurchase announcements. Neither of these papers analyze and test hypotheses regarding the information production role of institutional investors that is our focus here. 8

racy of the information produced (see, e.g., Frankel, Kothari, and Weber (2006)). Much of the above empirical literature has focused on the cross-sectional variation in firm characteristics that lead to di erences in information production by analysts and others across firms. In contrast to the above information production literature, our paper focuses on information production by institutional investors around a specific corporate event, namely, open-market repurchases. 3 Theory and Development of Hypotheses In this section we will briefly discuss the underlying theoretical motivation and develop the hypotheses we test in our empirical analysis. An important theoretical model where institutional investors produce information around payout (dividends or repurchases) is that of Brennan and Thakor (1990). The authors build on the notion that the share price is not a perfect aggregator of the private information of investors about the prospects of the firm and that the collection of information by investors is costly. Under this assumption, it follows that share repurchases oblige shareholders either to incur information collection costs, or to run the risk of partial expropriation by trade with better informed investors. As a result, uninformed shareholders (retail investors) prefer dividends to repurchases, while informed investors (large investors such as institutional investors) will prefer repurchases because this allows them to profit at the expense of the uninformed. Thus, the focus of Brennan and Thakor (1990) is on a firm s choice between cash dividends, open-market repurchases, and tender o er repurchases. Unlike the above theoretical analysis, the focus of our empirical analysis is not on alternative methods of cash distribution. However, we empirically test whether institutions indeed have the ability to produce valuable information about firms undergoing open-market repurchase programs. The economic setting we consider to develop testable hypotheses for our empirical tests can be described as follows. Consider a situation where the insiders of a firm, having private 9

information about its intrinsic value, are considering whether or not to undertake an openmarket repurchase program. Outsiders in the equity market consist of two types of investors. The first type of investors are institutional investors, who have the ability to produce noisy information about the firm (at a cost). The precision of information produced by institutions is lower than that of the private information held by firm insiders, so that, while information production helps institutions reduce their information disadvantage with respect to firm insiders, it does not eliminate it. The second type of investors are retail investors, who do not have any ability to produce information about the intrinsic value of the firm, and are therefore at a disadvantage with respect to both institutions and insiders. Retail investors are essentially liquidity traders in the equity market in the economic setting we study here, similar to their role in market microstructure models such as Kyle (1985). The price of the firm s stock in the equity market is set by a market maker who is uninformed to begin with, but who sets the stock price to break even (after observing the aggregate order flow of trades in the firm s equity), again similar to the price-setting rule in market microstructure models. While the market maker cannot fully separate the informed and uninformed trades, the price of the firm s equity will reflect, to some degree, the information held by institutional investors. The above economic environment that we postulate here is very similar to that of the theoretical model of Chemmanur and Jiao (2011), who, however, focus on the theoretically analyzing on the implications of institutional trading around seasoned equity o erings. Given the absence of any formal theoretical analysis of open-market stock repurchases in an economic environment similar to the above, we choose to adapt the analysis of Chemmanur and Jiao (2011) to the case of open-market repurchases in order to develop testable hypotheses for our empirical analysis. 6 In the following, we develop testable hypotheses for analyzing the 6 Apart from Brennan and Thakor (1990), we are not aware of any theoretical model of stock repurchases which incorporates the role of institutional investors and their ability to produce information about the firm. In the interest of conserving space, we choose not to develop a formal theoretical model here to analyze institutional trading around stock repurchases, but instead adapt the theoretical analysis of Chemmanur and Jiao (2011) to the stock repurchase setting. 10

e ect of institutional trading around open-market repurchases for the announcement e ect of a stock repurchases; actual shares repurchased (as against the authorized repurchase); the long-run return performance of the firm s equity subsequent to the announcement of an open-market repurchase; and finally, the abnormal profits realized by institutional investors (net of all transaction costs) by trading in the equity of firms subsequent to their announcement of an open-market repurchase program. We also develop testable hypotheses for the relationship between institutional trading immediately after an OMR program announcement and the change in the information asymmetry faced by the firm from before the announcement of the OMR program to after. Our first hypothesis deals with the relationship between institutional trading and the announcement e ects of open-market repurchase programs. Before the announcement of the repurchase program, ordinary (uninformed) investors in the equity market will have a prior valuation of the firm, which will be reflected in the pricing of the firm s equity before the repurchase announcement. Consider now the scenario where institutional investors trade in the firm s equity prior to the repurchase announcement, and the extent (number of shares) and direction (buy or sell) is publicly disclosed subsequent to their trading. In this case, assuming that all investors are aware that institutions have more precise information compared to other outsiders, the stock market will reflect the additional information contained in the trading by institutions, with the price of the firm s equity falling lower if the net buy by institutions (number of shares bought minus number of shares sold) is negative, while it will rise higher if their net buy is positive. At this point, if the firm announces an open-market repurchase program, stock market investors will further positively update the value of the firm s equity, knowing that the decision to repurchase or not is made by firm insiders who have information that is even more precise than that of institutional investors about the intrinsic value of the firm. 7 This means that the announcement e ect, which will reflect the 7 Here we are assuming that an open-market repurchase program credibly conveys information about the firm from firm insiders to outside investors in the equity market. Some readers may wonder how an open-market repurchase program can convey such information, given that the firm does not commit to repurchase the entire number of shares authorized by the board. It should be noted in answer to this 11

di erence in the firm s stock price from before the repurchase to immediately after, will be decreasing in the net buy of institutional investors. This will be the first hypothesis that we test here (H1). We now turn to trading by institutions subsequent to the announcement of an openmarket repurchase program. If the announcement of an open-market repurchase conveys firm insiders private information to the equity market, the price of the firm s stock immediately after the repurchase announcement will reflect this information. However, given that, in an open-market repurchase program, the firm does not make a commitment to repurchase all the shares authorized by the board, the repurchase announcement may only be a noisy signal of firm insiders private information. If this is indeed the case, institutions may have aresidualinformationadvantageoverretailinvestorsevenaftertheannouncementofan open-market repurchase program. If such an information advantage persists, then trading by institutions after an open-market repurchase announcement will have predictive power for future firm performance. This is the second hypothesis we test here (H2). Further, in this scenario, institutions will be able to make abnormal profits using their information advantage by trading in the equity of firms announcing repurchase programs (subsequent to the repurchase). This is therefore the third hypothesis we test here (H3). 8 If indeed, the repurchase announcement is only a noisy signal of firm insiders private information, then firm insiders themselves may have residual private information relative to outsiders about their firm s intrinsic value as well. Further, the more favorable this residual private information held by insiders (i.e., the more undervalued insiders believe their firm s question that an open-market repurchase program can indeed credibly convey such information as long as there is a monotonic relationship between firm insiders private information and the size (number of shares) of the repurchase program authorized (which, in turn, can be shown to be the case if firm insiders will incur a cost of falsely announcing a larger program than that warranted by insiders private information). See Oded (2005) for such a theoretical model of firms credibly signaling insiders private information through an open-market repurchase program, even in the absence of a commitment by the firm to repurchase all the shares authorized. 8 The residual information advantage of institutional investors over retail investors is likely to be greater as the information conveyed by the repurchase announcement itself becomes more noisy: e.g., for repurchase programs that are smaller (as a fraction of total shares outstanding). This, in turn, implies that the abnormal profits made by institutions from trading in the firm s equity after an open-market repurchase program announcement will also be greater for smaller repurchase programs. 12

equity is even after the repurchase announcement), the larger the amount of shares the firm is likely to actually repurchase (normalized by the total number of shares outstanding in the firm), in an attempt to eliminate this residual undervaluation. At the same time, as discussed above, the noisier the signal conveyed by the announcement of the repurchase program by the firm, the greater the information advantage held by institutional investors relative to retail investors. This means that trading by institutions after an open-market repurchase announcement will be positively associated with the amount of shares actually repurchased by the firm (normalized by the total number of shares outstanding). Thus, a greater net buy of the firm s equity by institutions after an open-market repurchase announcement will be positively related to the actual repurchases made by the firm in the subsequent period (H4). Finally, it is interesting to examine how institutional trading around open-market repurchase programs a ects the information asymmetry faced by the firm. Clearly, if open-market repurchase announcements serve as noisy signals of firm insiders private information to outsiders in the equity market, then the information asymmetry faced by the firm will be reduced: i.e, the extent of information asymmetry faced by the firm in the equity market subsequent to an open-market repurchase announcement will be lower than that before the repurchase announcement. The question we examine here, however, is the e ect of the interaction between the signal conveyed by the repurchase program announcement and the information conveyed by institutional trading immediately after the announcement of the repurchase on the information asymmetry facing the firm. In particular, the reduction in the information asymmetry facing the firm will be greater when the noisy signal conveyed by the repurchase announcement and the information conveyed to the equity market by institutional trading reinforce each other (which will be the case when the institutional net buy immediately after the repurchase announcement is positive). On the other hand, the reduction in information asymmetry facing the firm will be smaller when the noisy signal conveyed by the repurchase announcement and the information conveyed to the equity market by in- 13

stitutional trading oppose each other (which will be the case when the institutional net buy immediately after the repurchase announcement is negative). In summary, the reduction in information asymmetry facing the firm following the announcement of an open-market repurchase program will be positively associated with the institutional net buy immediately after the repurchase announcement (H5). 4 Data and Summary Statistics 4.1 Open-Market Repurchases Data The data on open-market repurchase programs (OMRs) in this study come from several sources. Our initial sample of open-market repurchase announcements from January 2004 to December 2010 comes from the SDC Platinum Database of Mergers and Acquisitions. We then exclude announcements such that the repurchase may be executed through tender o er, private negotiation, or Dutch auction. 9 If a firm makes multiple repurchase announcements in the same calendar year, we only keep the first announcement. We also require that accounting information from Compustat and stock return information from CRSP are available for the firms in our OMR data. Our data on U.S. firms actual share repurchases come from Quarterly Compustat, which are made availably by the regulatory changes to Rule 10b-18 of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 in 2003. 10 Beginning from 2004, U.S. firms are required to make quarterly disclosures of actual share repurchases and average prices paid. We then match this actual repurchase data from Quarterly Compustat with the data on OMR announcements we obtained from SDC. 9 The purpose is to eliminate repurchase programs that may be executed through a combination of methods (e.g., open-market and private negotiation). 10 Earlier studies (e.g., Stephens and Weisbach (1998), Fama and French (2001), and Grullon and Michaely (2002)) have used a variety of other CRSP- and Compustat-based measures to estimate actual share repurchases by U.S. firms. These estimations invariably su er from di erent measurement biases. For a detailed discussion of these measures, see Banyi, Dyl, and Kahle (2008). 14

Table 1 reports summary statistics of our OMR data. We have about 3,000 open-market repurchase programs announced from January 2004 to December 2010. The average OMR program size, defined as the dollar amount value of the OMR program normalized by the market capitalization of the firm, is 7.94%, consistent with prior studies in the literature (e.g., Peyer and Vermaelen (2009)). We find a significant 1.74% average abnormal return in the 5-day window around an OMR announcement, which is also consistent with the empirical findings in the literature (e.g., Babenko, Tserlukevich, and Vedrashko (2012)). Over the 4 fiscal quarters following an OMR announcement, our sample firms actual repurchases on average account for about 86% of the OMR program size announced. This is largely consistent with prior findings that firms complete a significant portion of the repurchase programs within the one-year period after the announcement (e.g., Stephens and Weisbach (1998)). 4.2 Institutional Trading Data We obtain transaction-level institutional trading data from Abel Noser Solutions, a leading execution quality measurement service provider for institutional investors. The data are similar to those used by several microstructure studies on institutional trading costs, for example, Keim and Madhavan (1995), Conrad, Johnson, and Wahal (2001), and Jones and Lipson (2001). To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to use institutional trading data to study institutional investors trading behavior around open-market repurchase programs. The data cover equity trading transactions by a large sample of institutions from January 2003 to September 2011. For each transaction, the data include the date of the transaction, the stock traded, the number of shares traded, the dollar principal traded, commissions paid by the institution, and whether it is a buy or sell by the institution. The data are provided to us under the condition that the names of all institutions are removed from the data. However, identification codes are provided enabling us to separately identify all institutions. 15

Sample institutions are either investment managers or plan sponsors. Investment managers are mutual fund families such as Fidelity Investments, Putnam Investments, and Lazard Asset Management. Examples of pension plan sponsors include United Airlines pension plan and the Commonwealth of Virginia. Table 2 reports summary statistics of our institutional data. We have 868 institutions in our sample, with 372 of them being investment managers and 496 of them being plan sponsors. In aggregate, these institutions have an annualized trading volume of around 304 billion shares and an annualized trading principal of around $9 trillion. In association with these trading activities, our sample institutions in aggregate incur an annualized commission expense of about $7.5 billion. If we consider a two-year trading horizon surrounding the OMR announcement dates in our OMR data, on average (for each OMR event), our sample institutions in aggregate execute about 24,510 transactions, with a trading principal of about $3.5 billion, and account for about 12% of the trading volume reported by CRSP. 5 Empirical Tests and Results 5.1 Pattern of Institutional Trading before OMR Announcements As the first step of our empirical analysis, we examine the pattern of institutional trading before open-market repurchase announcements. To the best of our knowledge, this has not been investigated in the literature before. We focus on institutional trading during the oneyear period before OMR announcements. Table 3 present the results of our analysis. We aggregate trading from institutional investors over di erent trading horizons before OMR announcements. For ease of disposition, Net Buy, our main variable to measure institutional trading, is expressed in basis points in Table 3. The general pattern is that Net Buy is significantly positive from minus quarter 2 to minus quarter 4. For example, during the 4th quarter before an OMR announcement, institutional investors in our sample on average net buy 20.85 basis points of the firm s shares outstanding. Nevertheless, during the quarter 16

immediately before OMR announcements, Net Buy is significantly negative, indicating that institutional investors on average net sell over this period. This sell-o is consistent with the large decline in stock price during the one-quarter period before OMR announcements. Further, the trading pattern over the one-year period before OMR announcements and over di erent sub-periods is largely similar for both investment managers and plan sponsors. 5.2 Institutional Trading and OMR Announcement E ects Hypothesis H1 predicts that Net Buy from institutions is inversely related with OMR announcement e ects. In this subsection, we make use of institutional trading data and examine the relationship between institutional trading and the announcement e ects of openmarket repurchase programs. Table 4 presents the results of our OLS analysis. The dependent variable is the cumulative abnormal return over a 5-day period around OMR announcements (i.e., the announcement return described in Table 1). Following the literature in open-market repurchases, we calculate the announcement e ects based on a market model, where the market beta is estimated with daily returns over the 250-day period ending 31 trading days before OMR announcements. The variable-of-interest is Net Buy from institutions. For ease of interpretation, from this subsection onwards, Net Buy is expressed in percentage rather than basis points. In Models (1) - (3), Net Buy is aggregated over the 6-month period before OMR announcements, whereas in Models (4) - (6), Net Buy is aggregated over the 12-month period before OMR announcements. From Model (1) we can see that the coe cient on Net Buy is negative and statistically significant. This is consistent with H1, suggestingthatinstitutionaltradingpriortoannouncements of open-market repurchase programs indeed conveys private information held by institutions about the intrinsic value of the firms. We control for usual suspects that have been found to be able to explain OMR announcement e ects in the literature, such as the size of the OMR programs and the past return of the firm. In a recent paper, Babenko, 17

Tserlukevich, and Vedrashko (2012) find that insider trading and insider holdings provide additional explanatory power regarding OMR announcement returns. In Models (2) and (3), we incrementally control for these variables and the coe cient on Net Buy remains negative and statistically significant. In Models (4) - (6), we aggregate institutional net buying over the 12-month period before OMR announcements and perform similar multivariate analysis as in Models (1) - (3). Our results remain qualitatively the same in the sense that the coe cients on Net Buy are all negative and statistically significant. To summarize this subsection, we find evidence that is consistent with hypothesis H1. Institutional trading before OMR announcements has predictive power for the announcement e ects, in the sense that smaller Net Buy is associated with more favorable OMR announcement e ects. This results holds even after we control for publicly available information such as size of the OMR program, prior firm performance, and insider trading. This evidence suggests that institutional trading prior to an open-market repurchase program announcement indeed reflects the private information held by institutional investors about the intrinsic value of the firm. 5.3 Institutional Trading and Subsequent Stock Return Performance In the previous subsection, we examine the relationship of institutional trading before OMR announcements and the OMR announcement e ects. From this subsection onwards, we focus on institutional trading immediately after OMR announcements and examine the informativeness of such trading. We first investigate whether institutional trading immediately after OMR announcements predicts subsequent stock return performance of the firm (H2). Table 5 reports the results of our multivariate analysis. The variable-of-interest is institutional trading, measured in Net Buy, after OMR announcements and we focus on institutional 18