The Reserve Bank s method of estimating potential output AN 2015/01

Similar documents
Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes

The use of projections and forecasts in the ECB s monetary policy

Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

Kiwi drivers the New Zealand dollar experience AN 2012/ 02

5 Comparison with the Previous Convergence Programme and Sensitivity Analysis

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

Session 12. Aggregate Supply: The Phillips curve. Credibility

Chapter 1. Introduction

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

6. Economic Outlook. The International Economy. Graph 6.2 Terms of Trade Log scale, 2012/13 average = 100

Discussion of DSGE Modeling of China s Macroeconomy and Housing Cycle

Jobs Online Background and Methodology

Strategy Document 1/03

Some Thoughts on the Design of Monetary Policy Strategy and Communications Andrew Levin Resident Scholar, IMF Research Department March 2014

A. GDP, Economic Growth, and Business Cycles

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

Jarle Bergo: Monetary policy and the outlook for the Norwegian economy

Renminbi Depreciation and the Hong Kong Economy

Quarterly Economics Briefing

Building a real-time database for GDP(E)

HOW BAD IS THE CURRENT RECESSION? LABOUR MARKET DOWNTURNS SINCE THE 1960s

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector

The dragon slain? Near-zero inflation in New Zealand

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

Macroeconomics 2301 Potential questions and study guide for exam 2. Any 6 of these questions could be on your exam!

12.1 Introduction The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

SEEK Employment Index in New Zealand: Job Vacancies and Job Seeking

Inflation expectations in the euro area, monitoring based on synthetic indicators

Monetary policy assessment of 13 September 2007 SNB aiming to calm the money market

CHAPTER 5: MEASURING GDP AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

Macroeconomics of the Labor Market

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

Measuring total factor productivity for the United Kingdom

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts.

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

As the monetary aggregates have become

Public attitudes to inflation and interest rates

Note on growth and growth accounting

An alternative interpretation of the recent U.S. inflation performance

West Bank and Gaza: Labor Market Trends, Growth and Unemployment 1

Quarterly Employment Survey: September 2011 quarter

The Japanese Saving Rate

Job Generation and Growth Decomposition Tool

LEVEL ECONOMICS. ECON2/Unit 2 The National Economy Mark scheme. June Version 1.0/Final

The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: The Romer-Romer Method on the Austrian case

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Forecasting at the Ministry of Finance

Government Budget and Fiscal Policy CHAPTER

The Aggregate Demand- Aggregate Supply (AD-AS) Model

T T Mboweni: Economic growth, inflation and monetary policy in South Africa

Preparation course MSc Business & Econonomics- Macroeconomics: Introduction & Concepts

Intuit Small Business Employment Index. White Paper

Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary. 12 April 2016

INFLATION TARGETING. Frederic S. Mishkin

Articles. Impact of the exchange rate on export. volumes. 2 Influences on export volumes: the exchange rate and other factors.

The Fiscal Policy and The Monetary Policy. Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D.

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

What Does the Taylor Rule Say About a New Zealand Australia Currency Union?*

The economic situation and monetary policy

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS

US Labour Market Monitor July report set to attract much attention as both employment and growth have slowed in 2016

A layperson s guide to monetary policy

University of Lethbridge Department of Economics ECON 1012 Introduction to Microeconomics Instructor: Michael G. Lanyi. Chapter 29 Fiscal Policy

Real estate: The impact of rising interest rates

Lars Nyberg: The Riksbank's monetary policy strategy

Introduction on monetary policy

Subject CT7 Business Economics Core Technical Syllabus

Fiscal policy and pension expenditure in Portugal

2. Issues using administrative data for statistical purposes

EUROSYSTEM STAFF MACROECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR THE EURO AREA

Inequality in G20 countries: Causes, impacts, and policy responses*

THREE KEY FACTS ABOUT ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS

Nominal GDP now-casting

Problem Set #4: Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand Econ 100B: Intermediate Macroeconomics

Financial capability and saving: Evidence from the British Household Panel Survey

Managing Consumer Credit Risk *

Part V: Fundamental Analysis

USES OF CONSUMER PRICE INDICES

MEASURING A NATION S INCOME

Briefing paper No. 3 Forecasting the economy

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Assignment #3. ECON Macroeconomic Theory Spring 2010 Instructor: Guangyi Ma. Notice:

Co-movement of State s Mortgage Default Rates: A Dynamic Factor Analysis Approach

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

Economics 101 Multiple Choice Questions for Final Examination Miller

MONEY, INTEREST, REAL GDP, AND THE PRICE LEVEL*

Revised Methodology for Unit Wage Costs and Unit Labour Costs - Explanation and Impact

THE ECONOMY AT FULL EMPLOYMENT. Objectives. Production and Jobs. Objectives. Real GDP and Employment. Real GDP and Employment CHAPTER

Topic 7: The New-Keynesian Phillips Curve

Domestic Activity. Graph 6.2 Terms of Trade Log scale, 2013/14 average = 100

Introduction to Macroeconomics. TOPIC 1: Introduction, definition, measures

Tutor2u Economics Essay Plans Summer 2002

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 17 MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES AND ISSUES March 17, 2016

Chapter 12: Aggregate Supply and Phillips Curve

Transcription:

The Reserve Bank s method of estimating potential output AN 2015/01 Ashley Lienert & David Gillmore March 2015 Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series ISSN 2230-5505 Reserve Bank of New Zealand PO Box 2498 Wellington NEW ZEALAND www.rbnz.govt.nz The Analytical Note series encompasses a range of types of background papers prepared by Reserve Bank staff. Unless otherwise stated, views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily represent the views of the Reserve Bank.

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 2 NON-TECHNICAL SUMMARY 1 Inflation is often thought of as being influenced by two main factors: the expectations of firms and households about future inflation, and fluctuations in economic activity around its sustainable or potential level. When economic activity is running ahead of this level, a positive output gap is said to exist: available resources are under pressure and inflation tends to pick up. For a central bank focused on targeting medium-term inflation, understanding the extent of these pressures is important. The first step in that process is estimating the potential level of output past, present, and future. How the Reserve Bank does that is the focus of this paper. Neither potential output nor the output gap can be directly observed. And many of the data used to produce estimates are released with a lag, and are subject to revision, often for several years after the first data release. For example, at any point we have Statistics New Zealand s latest provisional GDP estimates, but they are published almost six months after the end of the quarter to which they relate and are refined and revised over several years. The Reserve Bank s current baseline method of estimating potential output relies on estimating trends in historical data on labour supply, capital inputs, and a (residual) measure of total factor productivity (TFP). These trends are then combined, to produce an aggregate figure for potential output. The production function used to do the combining is itself a stylised representation, and reliant on other data (the shares of income going to labour and capital) that are only available with a considerable lag. And the trends tend to be quite sensitive to new data, or to data revisions. Potential output is a powerful conceptual tool, prompting analysts and policymakers to think hard about how much of any observed economic activity is sustainable (in line with the economy s capacity) and how much is above or below that level, which will tend to affect inflation. But experience suggests that any estimates for recent periods are best thought of as midpoints of a range: one might think of a true output gap as probably being within +/- one percentage point of that midpoint estimate. Estimates of potential output using the statistical techniques outlined here are one element in the Reserve Bank s forecasting and policy processes. Judgement and insights from other analytical tools are frequently used as complements in reaching the published views on the current state of resources pressures. As the data become more certain, the statistical techniques play a greater role in identifying developments in potential output in historical periods. The historical output gap estimates shapes our understanding of how inflation has typically behaved in New Zealand. 1 The authors are grateful for helpful comments and critique from Michael Reddell, Yuong Ha and Reuben Jacob.

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 3 1. INTRODUCTION The output gap (the percentage difference between actual and potential output) is a key concept in the way most central banks now think about inflation. In concept, it is a summary measure of the state of the business cycle and of pressure on resources, and thus of one key influence on inflation. Inflation is thought of as being primarily explained by expectations of future inflation and the output gap and thus both for explaining past inflation and for reaching a view of likely future inflation, decomposition of output into potential output and the output gap plays a key role. Because of the long lags between policy actions and inflation outcomes, output gap estimates are an important input for a forward-looking inflation-targeting central bank. Potential output can be thought of as the level of activity that the economy can sustain without causing inflation to rise or fall, all else equal (for example, assuming no shock, such as big changes in oil prices). By implication, the difference between actual and potential output (the output gap) indicates the extent of excess demand, and therefore the direction and magnitude of this source of inflation pressure. 2 The focus of this note is on how the Reserve Bank estimates the output gap, and some of the challenges involved in producing such estimates. 2. METHODOLOGIES There are a number of methods for estimating potential output and the output gap. Here we briefly outline three different approaches (the production function approach, time-series techniques and fully-estimated structural models of the economy) and refer the reader to more detailed descriptions in the literature. The production function approach combines factor inputs such as capital and labour in a production function to determine the level of potential output. The major challenges of this method are how to aggregate different types of labour, machinery, natural resources and intermediate inputs across diverse sectors of the economy, as well as deciding on an appropriate functional form and how to model technological progress explicitly. This approach becomes increasingly complex the more disaggregated the estimation is. The most commonly used approaches to estimating potential output involve timeseries techniques and structural models of the economy. These decompose output into trend and cycle, which are assumed to represent the supply and demand factors of the economy respectively. Time-series techniques include the univariate Hodrick- Prescott (HP) and Band Pass (BP) filters, which extract trend output from GDP data 2 For a detailed discussion of potential output and the output gap, see Claus et al. (2000).

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 4 alone, and multivariate (MV) filters which use a wider range of data than GDP alone. Structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) models combine multivariate time-series techniques with some structural assumptions about the nature of economic relationships. Unobserved components models also use multivariate time-series filtering techniques, while specifying tighter restrictions on economic relationships, which may be important to the user. Finally, fully-estimated structural models of the economy are used to estimate potential output and the output gap that are consistent with all other variables in the model. Within this class, potential output from DSGE models represents the level of output the economy would attain if the nominal price and wage rigidities in the models were removed. 3 What methods have been used by the Reserve Bank? From 1997 to 2009, the Bank used a multivariate (MV) filter in its estimation of potential output, in which HP-filtered GDP was augmented with other macroeconomic data, such as inflation, inflation expectations, the unemployment rate and capacity utilisation. 4 This approach sought to use a range of sources to provide conditioning information beyond what could be drawn from the trend in GDP itself. In 2009 the Reserve Bank moved away from this MV method to a more structural approach centred on a standard production function, and which uses highly aggregated filtered data. In this method, the estimation of potential output does not use inflation data at all so that the resulting output gap can be used independently to highlight the direction of possible future inflationary pressures. 3. THE RESERVE BANK'S CURRENT METHODOLOGY 3.1. MODELLING FRAMEWORK The Reserve Bank uses a production function approach to estimate potential output. In this view, output is determined by capital inputs (capital stock and capacity utilisation), labour inputs (hours worked per person and the labour force) and total factor productivity (TFP) as a residual. s are extracted from the input series to remove the cyclical and higher frequency components, and those trends are then combined in the production function as potential output. This approach focuses on a range of factors that can be thought of as explaining potential output, thus using more data than would a filter on a single variable (e.g. real GDP itself). As stated above, inflation data are not used explicitly in the estimation of potential output. The production function is: 3 Overviews of various methods for estimating potential output and the output gap are included in St Amant & van Norden (1998), Döpke & Chagny (2001) and Mishkin (2007). 4 Conway and Hunt (1997) and Graff (2004) describe the Bank s MV filter methodology.

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 5 Y t = A t (C t K t ) (1 α) (H t L t ) α (1) where Y t is output, A t is TFP, C t is capacity utilisation, K t is capital stock, H t is hours worked per person, and L t is number of persons employed. The parameter α is labour s share in output (0 < α < 1), assumed to be 2/3. 5 The number of persons employed, L t, is: L t = E t P t N t (2) where E t is the employment rate (calculated as 1 minus the unemployment rate), P t the participation rate, and N t the working age population. The logarithmic production function is (lower case denotes logs): y t = a t + (1 α)(c t +k t ) + α(h t +l t ) (3) where l t = e t +p t +n t (4) Data are available for most variables, and then the production function itself is used to back out (log) TFP (a t ) as a residual: 6 a t = y t (1 α)(c t +k t ) α(h t +l t ) (5) s are estimated for inputs of the production function (equations 3 and 4) using an unobserved components model. This extracts trends by filtering each component, anchored by a long-run trend assumption. 7 All trends are time-varying. GDP, capital stock, working age population and TFP trends converge to constant growth rates, while capacity utilisation, hours worked per person, the employment rate and the participation rate trends converge to constant levels. Individual components and their estimated trends are illustrated in Appendix 1. 5 This assumption is supported by the latest data, which averages 0.668 for the five years to 2013, calculated from annual data for compensation of employees, indirect taxes, operating surpluses and nominal GDP. 6 Appendix 2 illustrates how this residual estimate correlates well with officially published annual data. 7 We assume the trend of capital to be identical to the capital series over history, without filtering. The quarterly capital data is already a relatively smooth series. Filtering would make it more difficult to capture the discrete fall in the level of capital at 2011Q1 associated with the Christchurch earthquakes.

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 6 The trends are combined according to the production function to obtain the estimate of (log) potential output (y t ). y t = a t + (1 α) c t+k t + α(h t +l t) (8) where l t = e t+p t+n t (9) The data used, and the sources of those data, are summarised in Table 1. All data are quarterly and seasonally adjusted, except capital which is annual data transformed to quarterly. These techniques work well for historical periods (for example, estimates of potential output and the output gap in the years prior to the 2008/09 recession). However, data issues come to the fore the more recent the period one is estimating. Table 1: Variables, data sources, and data availabiltiy Variable Description Data source Data available in mid-november 2014 Y t Output: real production GDP Statistics NZ, National Accounts 2014Q2 (release date: 18Sep2014) C t Capacity utilisation (economy-wide) NZIER, QSBO 2014Q3 (release date: 07Oct2014) K t Capital: productive capital stock Statistics NZ, National Accounts, Year ended March 2013 (release date: 28Nov2013) H t Hours worked per person Total weekly hours Total official employed & RBNZ calculation Statistics NZ, HLFS 2014Q3 (release date: 05Nov2014) N t Working age population Statistics NZ, HLFS & RBNZ calculation 8 2014Q3 (release date: 05Nov2014) P t Participation rate Statistics NZ, HLFS 2014Q3 (release date: 05Nov2014) E t Employment rate = 1 unemployment rate Statistics NZ, HLFS 2014Q3 (release date: 05Nov2014) The data used in the model are all published with a lag (in some cases a considerable lag). To illustrate this, Table 1 shows the latest data that were available in mid- November 2014 and used for the calculation of the potential output estimate that appeared the December 2014 Monetary Policy Statement (MPS). Only for periods up to March 2013 did we have published data for all series. Many of these data (notably GDP, capital stock, and population) are subject to revisions for several years after they are first published. 8 The Statistics NZ Working Age Population (WAP) data include estimates between each population census; so recent years data may be revised in the following census. Before filtering the data, we add a long-term forecast of population to the Statistics NZ WAP series in order to capture the expected boost to potential output from strong migration flows.

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 7 Discussion of the output gap often focuses on the estimate for the quarter in which an MPS is being published. Those estimates draw on the production function model, but (because much of the data for the current quarter are not yet available), we have to extend each series with a forecast to the current quarter, using indicator models, information from business information visits, and analysts judgement. 9 3.2 HISTORY AND FORECAST The Reserve Bank s estimation of potential output (and of the output gap) is undertaken in two distinct stages: (i) estimation of potential output over history based on past data, and (ii) separate forecasts of the future paths of the output gap and potential output. The model outlined in the previous section is used to estimate potential output over history to the current quarter. Because the data for the model components are published with a lag, we forecast each series to the current period before putting them into the model to produce the estimate of potential output over history. The output gap (x t ) over history to the current quarter is then calculated as the difference between the log of actual output and potential output: x t = y t y t (10) Initial forecasts of the forward path of the output gap are made using the Bank s forecasting model, NZSIM, so that it is consistent with the forecasts of all other variables in the model. 10 The forecast output gap may be judgementally adjusted (based on data that are not in the model). The future path of potential output is forecast (independently of NZSIM), using assumptions about each component of potential output and our forecasts for particular variables. The forecasts of the output gap and potential output are combined to produce the forecast of GDP: y t = y t + x t (11) While it is possible to model both trend (potential output) and cycle (the output gap) within one framework, we choose to model these separately. Why? The key focus for monetary policy is the business cycle, with the aim of stabilising inflation. Therefore, constructing separate models for potential output and the output gap allows us to concentrate our forecasting effort on the cyclical component. Separately estimating 9 By current quarter, we mean the same quarter as the date of the MPS. For example, in preparing the December 2014 MPS, we extend the component data series with forecasts to 2014Q4. 10 NZSIM is a DSGE gaps model, that is all variables/data in the model are in the form of deviations from trend, thus reflecting the economic cycle. See forthcoming Reserve Bank of New Zealand Discussion Paper on NZSIM.

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 8 the output gap, our view of the cycle remains independent of any major revision in the level of GDP or other factors that may change our view of the level of potential output. It is important to note that our estimated path of potential output includes fluctuations with the business cycle. This can be seen in figure 1, with the slowing of the growth of potential output (flattening of the red line) associated with the downturn in real GDP during the 2008/09 recession. Given this, the output gap (figure 2) represents unsustainable fluctuations in output. Figure 1: Real GDP and potential output Figure 2: The output gap The future is, of course, unknown and can only be estimated with considerable margin of error shocks happen and behaviours change. There is a significant amount of uncertainty surrounding the estimates of potential output and the output gap, even for the historical period. Some of this is inevitable because it is an unobservable variable outside a model there is no true output gap we can benchmark estimates against. In addition, because the model relies on the filtering of

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 9 component series, many of which are themselves subject to revisions, the technique is sensitive to the end-point problem. That is, as more data become available, the estimate of potential output (and of the output gap) for a particular quarter changes. That makes sense: any judgement about the extent of excess demand will inevitably be conditioned to some extent by new information about what happened subsequently. Figure 3 helps illustrate the scale of the issue, by reference to our published estimates of the output gap for the March quarter of 2012, approximately three years ago. The estimate made in 2012Q1 was based on GDP data to 2011Q3 and forecasts to 2012Q1. Figure 3 shows that the 2012Q1 output gap as calculated in 2012Q1 was -1.46. Since then, estimates have changed considerably as data for subsequent quarters have become available and as the GDP data have been revised. Figure 3: Changing estimates of the 2012Q1 output gap % of potential output 0.4 0.2 0-0.2-0.4-0.6-0.8-1 -1.2-1.4-1.6 2012:1 2012:3 2013:1 2013:3 2014:1 2014:3 Date of forecasting round 0.4 0.2 0-0.2-0.4-0.6-0.8-1 -1.2-1.4-1.6 4. CONCLUSION The estimation of potential output and the output gap are important to an inflationtargeting central bank, such as the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, because they provide an estimate of the degree of pressure on resources and therefore a way of understanding inflation past, present and future. The statistical method that the Reserve Bank uses to generate estimates of potential output has changed over the years. The current method, used since 2009, combines a production function approach with time-series filtering of data. However, this method is used only as a tool to help the Monetary Policy Committee formulate its view of the current state of the business cycle. Published estimates represent a considered view, informed by the statistical model and specific judgements. Estimates for current and recent quarters in particular are inevitably subject to a material margin of uncertainty.

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 10 REFERENCES Claus I, P Conway and A Scott (2000). The output gap: measurement, comparisons and assessment, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Research Paper No 44. Conway P and B Hunt (1997). Estimating potential output: a semi-structural approach, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Discussion Paper G97/9. Döpke J and O Chagny (2001). Measures of the output gap in the Euro-zone: An empirical assessment of selected methods. Kiel Institute for World Economics Working Paper No 1053. Graff M (2004). Estimates of the output gap in real time: how well have we been doing? Reserve Bank of New Zealand Discussion Paper DP2004/04. Mishkin FS (2007). Estimating potential output, Speech given at the Conference on Price Measurement for Monetary Policy (May 24, 2007); available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/mishkin20070524a.htm St Amant P and S van Norden (1998). Measurement of the output gap: A discussion of recent research at the Bank of Canada, Bank of Canada Technical Report No 79.

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 11 APPENDIX 1: MODEL COMPONENTS AND THEIR TRENDS 5 4 Capital Capital: annual percent change Figure 4: Components and trends 0.94 0.93 0.92 Capacity utilisation Capacity utilisation 3 2 1 0 0.91 0.9 0.89 0.88 0.87 0.86 Labour TFP 6 Labour: annual percent change 6 TFP: annual percent change 4 4 2 2 0-2 0-2 -4 36.5 36 35.5 Hours per person Hours worked per person 3 2.5 Working age population WAP: annual percent change 35 2 34.5 34 1.5 33.5 33 1 32.5 0.5 70 69 68 Participation rate Participation rate 98 96 Employment rate Employment rate 67 94 66 65 92 64 63 90 62 88

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note series 12 APPENDIX 2: HOW ACCURATE ARE OUR TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY ESTIMATES? In the model, TFP is estimated as a residual. How well does the resulting quarterly series correlate with the official annual TFP series, published by Statistics New Zealand? In figure 5 we can see that the model-generated quarterly data (scaled, red line) fits fairly closely with the officially published annual series (blue line). An annual series created from the quarterly model-generated data (grey line) is also fairly highly correlated with the official TFP measure. 1150 1100 Figure 5: Total factor productivity as model residual vs. official data Official annual data (SNZ) Model-generated annual data (scaled) Model-generated quarterly data (scaled) 1150 1100 1050 1050 1000 1000 950 950 900 900 850 850 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015