THE MEANING AND UTILITY OF DRUG PRICES

Similar documents
The War on Drugs: Methamphetamine, Public Health and Crime. Carlos Dobkin, Nancy Nicosia

The Effects of Price on Alcohol Use, Abuse and Consequences

Chapter 4 STRATEGIC GOALS AND OBJECTIVES

Substance Abuse Prevention Dollars and Cents in Arkansas: A Cost-Benefit Analysis

1. Youth Drug Use More than 40% of Maryland high school seniors used an illicit drug in the past year.

Comment on the Proposed Changes to MDMA ( Ecstasy ) Penalties

THE ECONOMICS OF DRUG SELLING: A REVIEW OF THE RESEARCH

Fact Sheet: Drug-Related Crime

Colorado Substance Use and Recommendations Regarding Marijuana Tax Revenue

European status report on alcohol and health Reducing the negative consequences of drinking and alcohol intoxication

DRUG POLICY AND THE CRIMINAL JUSTICE SYSTEM (2001)

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. The Report

Key Strategies for Violence and Substance Abuse Prevention III: Working in the Community

This report provides the executive summary for Indicators of School Crime and Safety: 2014.

Math 120 Winter Recitation Handout 11: Can We Win the War on Drugs?

ESTIMATING SUBSTANCE ABUSE TREATMENT NEED FROM THE NHSDA

Economic Fact Sheet Facts and Figures Relating To Illegal Drugs

Drug abuse in the Republic of Ireland: an overview

The Demand for Marijuana, Cocaine, and Heroin

ONDCP. Drug Policy Information Clearinghouse FACT SHEET John P. Walters, Director Drug-Related Crime

POSITION STATEMENT ON MEDICAL MARIJUANA AND MARIJUANA LEGALIZATION

Tobacco and Alcohol Taxation

Marijuana in Massachusetts. Arrests, Usage, and Related Data

Marijuana in New Jersey. Arrests, Usage, and Related Data

Responses to Misleading and Inaccurate Beer Industry Propaganda on Excise Taxes

UTAH DRUG CONTROL UPDATE. Substance Abuse Treatment Admissions Data

Elasticity. Demand is inelastic if it does not respond much to price changes, and elastic if demand changes a lot when the price changes.

THE ECONOMIC COSTS OF DRUG ABUSE IN THE UNITED STATES

United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (UNODC)

Patterns and Trends of Drug Abuse in the Baltimore/Maryland/Washington, DC, Metropolitan Area Epidemiology and Trends:

Prescribing Heroin to Heroin Addicts: A Drug Policy in Search of a Disaster? Neil McKeganey. Professor of Drug Misuse Research. University of Glasgow

FACT SHEET SERBIA (REPUBLIC OF)

Random Student Drug Testing Deterrence & Intervention

A conversation with CDC s Alcohol Program, September 5, 2014

Copyright 2010 by the Cato Institute. All rights reserved. Cover design by Jon Meyers. Printed in the United States of America.

What drug policies cost. Estimating government drug policy expenditures

Down the Up Staircase

The demand for cigarettes and other tobacco products. Anne-Marie Perucic Tobacco Control Economics Tobacco Free Initiative WHO

PERSPECTIVES ON DRUGS Models for the legal supply of cannabis: recent developments

Prescription Drug Abuse

COMMITTEE ON COMMODITY PROBLEMS

Addictions TREATMENT When Knowing the FACTS

The Effects of Macro-level Interventions on Addictive Behavior. and. September, 1998 Revised: December 1999

SURVEY MEASURES OF DRUG/SUBSTANCE USE

DASPOP Organized For Advocacy

TRENDS IN HEROIN USE IN THE UNITED STATES: 2002 TO 2013

ARIZONA DRUG CONTROL UPDATE. Drug Use Trends in Arizona

Behavioral Health Trends in the United States: Results from the 2014 National Survey on Drug Use and Health

Supplement Unit 1. Demand, Supply, and Adjustments to Dynamic Change

Speaker Sheldon Silver. Breaking New York s Addiction to Prison: Reforming New York s Rockefeller Drug Laws

Minnesota County Attorneys Association Policy Positions on Drug Control and Enforcement

Literature review: UK veterans and the criminal justice system

Module 6 Alcoholism, Drug Abuse and Corruption

REMARKS BY R. GIL KERLIKOWSKE DIRECTOR OFFICE OF NATIONAL DRUG CONTROL POLICY EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT. before the

SOUTH CAROLINA DRUG CONTROL UPDATE. Drug Use Trends in South Carolina

J0MUN XIII INTRODUCTION KEY TERMS. JoMUN XIII General Assembly 3. Ending the illicit trafficking of drugs in Africa. President of General Assembly

The Economic Costs of Drug Abuse in the United States

Position Statement: Nicotine Dependence

9. Drugs, Alcohol and Crime

Drugged Driving. What is Drugged Driving? How Many People Take Drugs and Drive?

Drug and Alcohol Use Survey

Market Size and Demand for Marijuana in Alaska

CONNECTICUT DRUG CONTROL UPDATE. Drug Use Trends in Connecticut

Beef Demand: What is Driving the Market?

Behavioral Health Barometer. United States, 2013

OHIO COUNTY. Demographic Data. Adult Behavioral Health Risk Factors:

Stuff You Need to Know About Party Drugs

Research Note RN 00/91 1 November 2000 DRUG COURTS

Moving the Needle. Stephen L. Buka, Jasmina Burdzovic-Andreas, Elizabeth Kretchman, Charles Williams, Paul Florin

WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE?

Drug-Free Workplace. Policy Statement. Reason for the Policy. Policy V

CT-167. February 2000

A Publication Of Drug Free Nation

Substance Abuse Treatment Admissions Data

HowHow to Identify the Best Stock Broker For You

CHARLES & SUE S SCHOOL OF HAIR DESIGN DRUG AND ALCOHOL POLICY DRUG AND ALCOHOL POLICY; SUBSTANCE ABUSE RESOURCES:

Developing a Framework for Estimating Government Drug Policy Expenditures

Sacramento County 2010

VERMONT DRUG CONTROL UPDATE. Drug Use Trends in Vermont. Substance Abuse Treatment Admissions Data

PUBLIC SAFETY ACTION PLAN. Prepared for Governor Haslam by Subcabinet Working Group

DRUG AND ALCOHOL POLICY

Addiction and Substance Abuse among Nevada Youths

No Eastern International student shall coerce, even subtly, another Eastern International student to use drugs or alcohol.

INTIMATE PARTNER VIOLENCE

San Diego County 2010

Methodology for ACLU-WA Marijuana Law Enforcement Costs Data Visualization 1

Source/Reference: Drug-Free Workplace Act of 1988 Drug-Free Schools and Communities Act Amendments of 1989

Addiction and Drug Policy. disadvantages. Through legalization controlling illicit drugs will create jobs through

Behavioral Health Barometer. United States, 2014

Energy drinks are flavored beverages

Special Report Substance Abuse and Treatment, State and Federal Prisoners, 1997

WHY THE FDA SHOULD REGULATE TOBACCO PRODUCTS

Notes for an Address by. Hilary Geller. during the. General Debate on the Special Session of the UN. General Assembly on the World Drug Problem

The Current State of Drug Abuse Across the Nation. December 12, 2015

Enforcement - Aggressively Attacking Unlawful Drug Activity. Treatment/Recovery - Getting Treatment Resources Where They Are Needed

New National Poll Reveals Public Attitudes on Substance Abuse, Treatment and the Prospects of Recovery

Substance Abuse Chapter 10: Substance Abuse

The 2012 National Drug Control Strategy: Building on a Record of Reform

The NJSAMS Report. Heroin Admissions to Substance Abuse Treatment in New Jersey. In Brief. New Jersey Substance Abuse Monitoring System.

What brings you to the work of the Blue Ribbon Commission, and marijuana?

Transcription:

Addiction September 96, Volume 91 Issue 9, p. 1261, 4p. By Johnathan Caulkins and Peter Reuter Introduction THE MEANING AND UTILITY OF DRUG PRICES The metaphor of markets has become standard in discussing policy toward illicit drugs, particularly in the United States. For example, policy is often debated in terms of the division of expenditures between supply side and demand side programs (Falco, 1994). Prices naturally play a prominent role in the metaphor, but they have been given only lip service in terms of analysis and data collection. That is unfortunate because: (1) price affects consumption, both in total and composition; (2) many harms relate to expenditure, which is the product of price and consumption; and (3) price data are a potentially important research tool for understanding the workings of policy. This paper makes the case for giving more priority to prices in analysis and data collection. Consumption and prevalence Prices are of interest in the first place because they affect drug use. Prices affect the quantity consumed, who uses, and even how drugs are used. Economists are devoted to the proposition that for almost any good a higher price will lower consumption (Mansfield, 1988), and they have a broad array of evidence demonstrating that this does not apply only to "rational economic agents" making choices about conventional goods. Inmates of psychiatric institutions respond to prices in experiments, as do animals (Kagel et al., 1981), and there is a considerable literature (reviewed by Manning et al, 1991) showing that consumption of the two licit addictive substances, cigarettes and alcohol, responds to changes in price, as measured by the price elasticity of demand. Formally, the price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in consumption associated with a 1% change in price; it is a negative number. Even though nicotine is a notoriously addictive drug, cigarette consumption turns out to exhibit substantial elasticity. Becker, Grossman & Murphy (1994) found short and long run elasticities of demand for cigarettes of -0.4 and -0.75, respectively. The long-run effect is greater because price increases reduce initiation as well as suppress consumption by current users. For alcohol similar elasticities have been observed, with surprisingly high figures specifically for hears' drinkers (Coate & Grossman, 1988). Until recently elasticity estimates for illicit drugs were often simply borrowed from those for licit drugs (e.g. Rydell & Everingham, 1994), but empirical evidence is just now beginning to accumulate. van Ours (1995) estimated short and long run elasticities of demand for pre-world War II opium consumption in the Dutch East Indies (-0.7 and -1.0, respectively). Using survey data on the household population, Saffer & Chaloupka (1995) estimate elasticities for cocaine of

between -1.10 and -0.72, and for heroin between - 1.80 and - 1.60. Caulkins (1995a) estimates that for arrestees, a group responsible for much of the social harm related to drugs, elasticities of demand for cocaine are between -1.50 and -2.0. These findings suggest that if enforcement is able to raise prices, an untested proposition, then tougher enforcement can substantially reduce consumption. If the elasticity is less than one in absolute value, then that reduction in use will none the less result in increased expenditures. Price can influence the nature and consequences of drug use, not just the quantity consumed. Changes in price have been linked to changes in the number of emergency room and medical examiner mentions for cocaine (ONDCP, 1992). Higher prices are likely to lead users to more efficient, and frequently dangerous, modes of drug-taking. The dominance of injection among American heroin users has many sources but the high price is certainly one of them. Similarly, the average THC content of marijuana rose during the late 1980s along with marijuana prices. Lower price also affects the character of the drug user population; the declining cocaine prices in the 1980s (Caulkins, 1994) seems to have increased the share of users from lower SES groups. Expenditure Although reducing use is the principal goal of current drug policy, many aspects of "the drug problem" are associated not so much with the quantity consumed or the number of users as with the dollar value of the black market (roughly $50 billion/year for the United States according to Rhodes et al., 1995), which is the product of price and consumption. At the individual level, many heroin addicts' budgets are dominated by purchases of illegal drugs (Johnson et al., 1985), and higher drug expenditures immiserate the user. Drug expenditures matter for non-users as well. The volume of property crime is plausibly related to total expenditure, given that a large share of expenditures are financed by such crime and about 30% of inmates serving time for property crimes report committing their crime to finance the purchase of illicit drugs (BJS 1991, 1994). The paucity of data on expenditures has led to no studies of this relation, although the classic Silverman & Spruill (1977) finding that heroin prices were positively related to property crime was probably mediated through expenditures. Market violence, probably the principal source of violent crime related to illegal drugs (Goldstein et al., 1989), is also a function of expenditures (and thus prices). If drugs were not enormously valuable per unit weight and if large quantities were not sold, then the incentives for violence, whether to protect territories or punish cheating, would be modest. The same can be said for corruption of authorities; high prices provide the incentive for paying police to overlook violations, and it is the total dollar volume that provides the means for doing so. The incentive of organized crime to enter these activities also is positively affected by price and quantity. Research tool Price data are an appealing research tool for three reasons. First, prices display enormous variation over time (Caulkins, 1994), between cities within the United States (Caulkins, 1995b), and across market levels. Cocaine that sells for scarcely $3 per gram at the point of export from

the Andes fetches almost $150 per gram (pure) on the streets of American cities (DEA, 1992) or $250 in European cities (Hartnoll, 1993). Understanding the sources and consequences of this variation is an important task but the magnitude of that variation, particularly over time and place, offers prospects for gaining substantial insight into behavior. Secondly, price data are easy to collect, as compared to either prevalence or consumption, because they can be obtained through interviews with users or through undercover purchases made as part of routine enforcement. For example, the DEA's STRIDE (System to Retrieve Information from Drug Evidence) contains about 6000 price observations per year, primarily from federal enforcement operations (Frank, 1987). Unfortunately, price data have traditionally been collected unsystematically and reported very casually, primarily because police have little motivation to take data collection seriously. Surveys, such as the National Household Survey, include questions about prices but usually in a rather primitive form. Few analyses of these data have been published; conversations with researchers involved in the surveys suggest that they have little faith in those data. The official published price series often provide little useful information since they do not report central tendency, just movements in extremes. In Europe it appears that only broad averages are available. Thirdly, price data are directly related to the analysis, planning and evaluation of the whole range of drug policy issues. We offer here examples from epidemiology, treatment and enforcement. Epidemiology Changes in the incidence of drug use are not currently investigated with models that include price. Implicitly, it is assumed that drug epidemics have their origin in attitudinal changes, but supply shifts leading to lower prices may be an important factor in initiating an epidemic. Historically, it is fairly clear that the timing and speed of the crack epidemic in the US was a function of its lower cost per dose, compared to powder cocaine. Treatment effectiveness Motivations for entering treatment are various but for many patients it is the difficulty of coping with dependence on drugs which are so expensive. The incentive to remain in treatment will be attenuated if prices decline. Thus treatment evaluations would be enriched by including data on price variation faced by clients since this may explain some of the variation in outcomes across programs. Enforcement A principal argument for pursuing high-level enforcement (including source country control and interdiction) is that it imposes costs on suppliers and, therefore, raises prices. Hence, one way to evaluate the success of enforcement operations is to track changes in price. Since different enforcement programs (e.g. interdiction vs street level enforcement) affect different levels of the drug distribution system, the analysis can be sharpened by examining the behavior of prices at the stage being targeted (see e.g. Rydell & Everingham, 1994).

Conclusion Surveys should give more serious attention to the collection of price data by including more detailed questions. Ethnographic studies, which routinely include expenditure data (Needle & Mills, 1993), should also include more price observations. The numerous price observations made by state and local police should be collected systematically as STRIDE does for federal agencies. It is not only better price data, but also better analyses that are needed. Prices can only be understood in the context of market dynamics. Too often the term "demand" is used when consumption is more appropriate, and supply is equated simply with the total quantity produced, thus suppressing important behavioral issues. This is obviously a task for economists, who are trained in, and obsessed by, such analysis, although not nearly so good at or interested in data collection; with rare exception (see Wagstaff & Maynard, 1988), they have been notably absent from empirical work in this area. Prices are central to understanding drug policy, but they are poorly measured and analytically marginalized. The development of better price data, along with their analysis, would serve well both researchers and policy makers.

References BECKER, G., GROSSMAN', M. & MURPHY, K. M. (1994) An empirical analysis of cigarette addiction, American Economic Review, 84, 397-418. BUREAU OF JUSTICE STATISTICS (BJS) (1991) Correctional Populations in the United States, NCJ-142729 (Washington, DC, USGPO). BUREAU OF JUSTICE STATISTICS (1994) Drugs and Crime Facts, 1993, NCJ-146246 (Washington, DC, US-GPO). CAULKINS, J. (1994) Developing Price Series for Cocaine, MR-317-DPRC (Santa Monica, CA, Rand Corporation). CAULKINS, J. (1995a) Estimating the elasticities and cross elasticities of demand for cocaine and heroin, Heinz School Working Paper 95-13 (Pittsburgh, Carnegie-Mellon University). CAULKINS, J. (199b) Domestic geographic variation in illicit drug prices, Journal of Urban Economics, 37, 38-56. COATE, D. & GROSSMAN, M. (1988) Effects of alcohol beverage prices and legal drinking ages on youth alcohol use, Journal of Law and Economics, 31, 145171. DRUG ENFORCEMENT ADMINISTRATION (DEA) (1992) The Illicit Drug Wholesale/Retail Price Report (Washington, DC, Drug Enforcement Administration). EVERINGHAM, S. & RYDELL, C. P. (1994) Modeling the Demand for Cocaine (Santa Monica, Rand). FALCO, M. (1994) Toward a more effective drug policy, Chicago Legal Forum, 9-24. FRANK, R. S. (1987) Drugs of abuse: data collection systems of DEA and recent trends, Journal of Analytical Toxicology, 11, 237-241. GOLDSTEIN, P., BROWNSTEIN, H. H., RYAN, P. J. & BELLUCCl, P. A. (1989) Crack and homicide in New York City, 1988: a conceptually based event analysis, Contemporary Drug Problems, 16, 651-687. HARTNOLL, R. (1993) Multi-City Study of Drug Misuse (Strasbourg, France, Council of Europe). JOHNSON, B., GOLDSTEIN, P., PREBLE, E., SCHMEIDLER, J., LIPTON, D., SPUNT, B. & MILLER, T. (1985) Taking Care of Business: the economics of crime by heroin abusers (Lexington, DC, Heath).

KAGEL, J., BATI'ALIO, R., RACHLIN, H. & GREEN, L. (1981) Demand curves for animal consumers, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 96, 1-15. MANNING, W. G., KEELER, E. B., NEWHOUSE, J.P., SLOSS, E. M. & WASSERMAN, J. (1991) The Costs of Poor Health Habits (Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press). MANSFIELD, E. (1988) Microeconomics: theory and application, 6th edn (New York, W.W. Norton). NEEDLE, R. H. & MILLS, A. (1993) Drug Procurement Practices of the Out-of-Treatment Chronic Drug Abuser (Rockville, MD, National Institute on Drug Abuse). OFFICE OF NATIONAL DRUG CONTROL POLICY (1992) Price and Purity of Cocaine: the relationship to emergency room visits and deaths, and to drug use among arrestees (Washington DC, Office of National Drug Control Policy). RHODES, W., SCHEIMAN, P., PITTAYATHIKHUN, T., COLLINS, L. & TSARFATY, V. (1995) What America's Users Spend on Illegal Drugs, 1988-1993 (Washington, DC, Office of National Drug Control Policy). RYDELL, C. P. & EVERINGHAM, S.S. (1994) Controlling Cocaine: supply vs. demand programs (Santa Monica, CA, RAND, MR-331-ONDCP/A/DPRC). SAFFER, H. & CHALOUPKA, F. (1995) The demand for illicit drugs, Working Paper No. 5238 (Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research). SILVERMAN, L. P. & SPRUILL, N. L. (1977) Urban crime and the price of heroin, Journal of Urban Economics, 4, 80-103. VAN OURS, J. C. (1995) The price elasticity of hard drugs: the case of opium in the Dutch East Indies, 1923-1938, Journal of Political Economy, 103, 261279. WAGSTAFF, A. & MAYNARD, A. (1988) Economic Aspects of the Illicit Drug Market and Drug Enforcement Policies in the United Kingdom (London, Home Office). Copyright of Addiction is the property of Carfax Publishing Company and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.