Longevity Risk and Optimal Asset Allocation with Consumption and Investment Constraints *

Similar documents
Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Life-cycle Asset Allocation with Annuity Markets: Is Longevity Insurance a Good Deal?

READING 14: LIFETIME FINANCIAL ADVICE: HUMAN CAPITAL, ASSET ALLOCATION, AND INSURANCE

Unlocking the Two Mysteries behind SPIAs

Fixed and Variable Payout Annuities: How Optimal are Optimal Strategies?

Human Capital, Asset Allocation and Life Insurance

Why Advisors Should Use Deferred-Income Annuities

Lifecycle Portfolio Choice With Systematic Mortality Risk

Wealth Management Redefined. Lifetime Wealth Portfolios SM

Reexamining To versus through new research Into an old debate. May 2014

The 50% Indicator Investment Security Analysis. Robert Ruggirello, CFA

How To Become A Life Insurance Agent

An Incomplete Market Approach to Employee Stock Option Valuation

NTA s and the annuity puzzle

A Basic Introduction to the Methodology Used to Determine a Discount Rate

Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA

Optimal Gradual Annuitization: Quantifying the Costs of Switching to Annuities

How to Ensure Adequate Retirement Income from DC Pension Plans

MANAGING FINANCIALLY DISTRESSED PENSION PLANS IN THE INTEREST OF BENEFICIARIES

Lecture 1: A Next-Generation Solution for Funding Retirement: A Case Study in Design and Implementation of Financial Innovation

Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary. 12 April 2016

Insights. Building a sustainable retirement plan. From asset allocation to product allocation

CHOOSING YOUR INVESTMENTS

Sweden. Qualifying conditions. Benefit calculation. Earnings-related. Key indicators. Sweden: Pension system in 2012

Are Managed-Payout Funds Better than Annuities?

Meeting the Global Challenge of Funding Retirement:

e-brief The Piggy Bank Index: Matching Canadians Saving Rates to Their Retirement Dreams

The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity

PRINCIPAL ASSET ALLOCATION QUESTIONNAIRES

LDI for DB plans with lump sum benefit payment options

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING

The Equity Premium in India

Insights. Investment strategy design for defined contribution pension plans. An Asset-Liability Risk Management Challenge

Discussions of Monte Carlo Simulation in Option Pricing TIANYI SHI, Y LAURENT LIU PROF. RENATO FERES MATH 350 RESEARCH PAPER

Life-cycle Finance and the Dimensional Managed DC Solution By Wade Pfau May 22, 2012

L actuaire et la SécuritS

ThoughtCapital. Strategic Diversification for a Lifetime Principal LifeTime Portfolios

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*:

Delayed Income Annuities / Longevity Insurance. Presented By: Scott White, AAPA, ALMI Annuity Marketing Manager

Annuity Decisions with Systematic Longevity Risk. Ralph Stevens

Allocation to Deferred Variable Annuities with GMWB for Life

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Discount Rates in General Insurance Pricing

Are Unconstrained Bond Funds a Substitute for Core Bonds?

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 9. Binomial Trees : Hull, Ch. 12.

Retirement Income Investment Strategy by Andrew J. Krosnowski

OVERVIEW. The goals of this paper are to:

Rare Events and Annuity Market Participation

Invest in Direct Energy

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36)

Retirement sustainability for defined contribution plan participants

APPENDIX. Interest Concepts of Future and Present Value. Concept of Interest TIME VALUE OF MONEY BASIC INTEREST CONCEPTS

Dimensional Managed DC

Introduction to Binomial Trees

MEETING THE FINANCIAL NEEDS OF RETIREES: a layering approach to building retirement income portfolios

1.2 Structured notes

Best Practices for a Successful Retirement: A Case Study

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

Betting on Death and Capital Markets in Retirement:

Retirement Income Adequacy With Immediate and Longevity Annuities

Better Guidance on Matters of Life and Death

ECONOMICS AND FINANCE OF PENSIONS Lecture 8

INVESTMENT AND PLANNING SOLUTIONS. Redefine your means in retirement. Member FINRA/SIPC

A Life Cycle Model with Pension Benefits and Taxes

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

Choice 6. American Equity. Simple Choices for a Secure Retirement. The one who works for you!

Lecture 9. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 8

The Binomial Option Pricing Model André Farber

Fund Manager s Portfolio Choice

Anumber of recent articles in the

Modified dividend payout ratio =

A new toolbox for retirement planning

What Annuities Can (and Can t) Do for Retirees With proper handling and expectations, annuities are powerful retirement income tools

ThoughtCapital. Investment Strength and Flexibility

The diversity of pension plans and their accounting liabilities

Chapter 13 Composition of the Market Portfolio 1. Capital markets in Flatland exhibit trade in four securities, the stocks X, Y and Z,

GUARANTEES. Income Diversification. Creating a Plan to Support Your Lifestyle in Retirement

University of New South Wales Group. Group leader: John Piggott

Asset Allocation with Annuities for Retirement Income Management

Practice Set #4 and Solutions.

10 Binomial Trees One-step model. 1. Model structure. ECG590I Asset Pricing. Lecture 10: Binomial Trees 1

Personal Financial Plan. John & Mary Sample

How To Fund Retirement

Funding Retirees Budgets: Ways of Managing the Investment Risks. Anthony Asher and Ribhi Alam Deloitte Actuaries and Consultants Ltd

Are Bonds Going to Outperform Stocks Over the Long Run? Not Likely.

The Illusion of Precision. Glidepaths STEPHEN SEXAUER CHIEF INVESTMENT OFFICER ALLIANZ GLOBAL INVESTORS SOLUTIONS

Pensions: A Corporate Finance Perspective. Economics of pensions. Corporate pension finance

American and European. Put Option

Full Circle: Purchasing Insured Annuities in a Defined-Benefit Plan

Expected default frequency

The Impact on Inequality of Raising the Social Security Retirement Age

Model-Free Boundaries of Option Time Value and Early Exercise Premium

Estimating internal rates of return on income annuities

Actuarial Speak 101 Terms and Definitions

Computing the optimal portfolio policy of an investor facing capital gains tax is a challenging problem:

HOW HAS SHIFT TO DEFINED CONTRIBUTION PLANS AFFECTED SAVING?

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2011: RETIREMENT-INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES SWEDEN

Estimating the True Cost of Retirement

CHOOSING YOUR INVESTMENTS

Transcription:

Longevity Risk and Optimal Asset Allocation with Consumption and Investment Constraints * Bong-Gyu Jang **, Taeyong Kim, Seungkyu Lee **, Hyeon-Wuk Tae ** September 2015 Abstract This paper investigates optimal retirement planning when investors desire to maintain a certain minimum level of consumption, which can be achieved only by a guaranteed income stream after retirement. Our model incorporates the subsistence level in consumption and social securities and defined-contribution retirement pensions, all of which are necessary to guarantee an income stream. Our model shows that the movements of the optimal risky investments might dramatically change with the subsistence level in consumption. Our numerical results show that the risky investment rate in the retirement pension can increase with the risk-free gross return rate and with the risk aversion level when the low risk-free rate and risk aversion level are both low. Furthermore, the risky investment rate in the retirement pension can decrease even when the market condition is favorable. * This work was supported by the National Research Foundation of Korea Grant funded by the Korean Government (NRF-2014S1A3A2036037, NRF-2013R1A2A2A03068890). **Department of Industrial and Management Engineering, POSTECH, Republic of Korea, E-mail: bonggyujang@postech.ac.kr (Jang), lseungkyu@gmail.com (Lee), taehy@postech.ac.kr (Tae) Morningstar Associates Korea, Republic of Korea, E-mail: Kevin.kim@morningstar.com

1. Introduction This paper proposes an integrated portfolio management system that guarantees a certain minimal income stream. Individuals desire for the guaranteed minimum income is incorporated as a subsistence level of consumption. The existence of this subsistence level forces our portfolio management system, or our retirement planning, to generate a steady income stream even though the income stream does not maximize its market value. Although many traditional retirement plans (Blanchett and Straehl, 2015 1 ; Gomes and Michaelides, 2005; Horneff et al., 2008) consider annuities to provide the after-retirement income stream, they mainly focused on the market value of the future income stream rather than on its safety. 2 Different from the previous research, this paper presents an integrated retirement planning system that both maximizes the market value of the future income stream, and guarantees a minimum income stream. Our numerical result shows that the subsistence level in consumption, which is conceptually related to the minimum guaranteed income, is crucial in the optimal retirement planning because the movements of the optimal consumption and investment strategies change greatly depending on the subsistence level. The concept of the subsistence level in consumption 3 is closely related to the minimum guaranteed income. Current consumption can be financed by an initial wealth, but all future consumption should be financed by labor income and non-labor income. This requirement means that a certain level of consumption can be maintained only by a guaranteed minimum income stream. Therefore, our model adopts the subsistence level in consumption and shows that the optimal consumption and investment decisions can dramatically change with the subsistence level in consumption. To secure a sufficient future income stream, almost all individuals hold a social security 1 Our model is different from the efficient income portfolios of Blanchett and Ratner (2015) in three ways. (1) Our retirement planning is a dynamic, not a static, portfolio management, and can therefore incorporate the investors elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption. (2) Our problem is mainly long-term portfolio management for a comfortable life after retirement, not an efficient short- or intermediate-term horizon investment. (3) The stability of income in our model is mainly related to income variation across the time, not across the state. 2 Dai et al. (2008) and Milevsky and Salisbury (2006) study the financial value of guaranteed minimum withdrawal benefits. 3 To explain the equity premium puzzle, Constantinides (1990) also incorporates the subsistence level in consumption.

pension and a (defined-contribution) retirement pension. Social security, which is mandatory for all individuals, requires a fixed amount of saving until retirement and promises fixed regular payments until death. In contrast, the defined-contribution (DC) retirement pension s payments can change depending on their investment performance whereas the retirement pensions require a fixed amount of saving. Although social security and the retirement pension have these characteristics, traditional optimal lifetime consumption and investment problems have excessively simplified their structures (Chen et al., 2006; Huang and Milevsky, 2008; Milevsky and Young, 2007). However, our model integrates all of these characteristics of social securities and retirement. Incorporating the social security and the retirement pension is consistent with the philosophy of Merton (2003, 2014): a retirement plan should divide after-retirement income stream into three categories (minimum guaranteed income, conservatively flexible income, and desired additional income). First, the social security corresponds to the minimum guaranteed income. Governments provide social security for the welfare of their retirees; it guarantees a minimal, but sufficient, amount of income stream. Second, the DC retirement pension corresponds mainly to the conservatively flexible income. The retirement pension is both conservative in that it makes a fixed and regular payments like a coupon bond, and flexible in that individuals can choose their investment strategy in the pension account. Third, the traditional asset allocation between risk-free and risky assets can be considered as an investment for a desired additional income. After preparing a minimum after-retirement life by saving into such pensions, individuals can invest a portion of their surplus wealth into risky assets. Therefore, in constructing an after-retirement income stream, both the social security and the retirement pension, as well as a traditional investment, should be considered. Our numerical results show that the risky investment in the retirement pension has two opposite effects on the direct investment in the risky asset: a complementary effect and a substitution effect. The complementary effect is that investment in the retirement pension reinforces the total investment amount in the risky asset. When the complementary effect is dominant, individuals raise both the risky investment rate in the retirement pension and the direct risky investment rate, so the total risky investment amount grows dramatically. In this case, we can say that individuals use the retirement pension for a desired additional income. In contrasts, the substitution effect decreases the amount of direct investment in the risky asset. When the substitution effect dominates the complementary effect, the total risky investment amount decreases even though the risky investment in the retirement pension increases. This

relationship occurs mainly because risk-averse individuals prefer the risky investment in the retirement pension, which can partially hedge the mortality risk of individuals, to the direct risky investment. To get a steady and sufficient annuity income stream from the retirement pension rather than a high return on the total wealth, individuals will increase the risky investment in the retirement pension and decrease the direct risky investment. In this case, we can say that individuals use the retirement pension for a guaranteed minimum income. These analyses suggest that the retirement pension can be used for different objectives (i.e., for a guaranteed minimum income or for a desired additional income), depending on the investment environment and the individuals risk preferences. The risky investment in the retirement pension is fundamentally a part of the investment in the risky asset, so the retirement pension is usually used as a desired additional income. However, we observe that individuals save a part of their wage as retirement pension to obtain a guaranteed minimum income when the risk-free gross return is low and when the individuals are less risk-averse. In both cases, the risky investment in the retirement pension increases with the risk-free gross return rate and with the risk aversion level, whereas the total risky investment amount decreases trivially. This observation implies that the guaranteed sufficient annuity income is more important than the high expected return of the total wealth, and that the risky investment in the retirement pension is related to the guaranteed minimum income. Furthermore, our numerical result shows that the individuals can reduce the risky investment in the retirement pension when the probability with high return of the risky asset is excessively high. Because the future income stream from the retirement pension is exposed to mortality risk as well as to market risk, the individuals might prefer the direct risky investment to the risky investment via the retirement pension (an inverse substitution effect). From this observation, we can say that the traditional asset allocation, which includes the direct risky investment, is more closely related to the desired additional income than is the retirement pension. Following Merton s categories, we assert that the retirement pension is related to the conservatively flexible income. 2. Model 2.1. Financial Markets and Investors Wealth Our model is a 4-period (nn = 0,1,2,3,4) discrete-time binomial tree model. We assume that a

financial market has one risk-free asset with a constant gross return rate RR and one risky asset with a stochastic return rate: the time nn gross return rate αα nn of the risky asset is αα uu with probability pp uu and αα dd with probability pp dd = 1 pp uu. (uu and dd represent up and down markets, respectively.) The gross return rates of the risk-free and the risky assets are assumed to satisfy the following no-arbitrage condition: αα uu > RR > αα dd. Investors in our model are assumed to have initial wealth WW 0 = WW, and we denote time-nn wealth level as WW nn for nn = 0,1,2,3,4. They also receive wage incomes II 0 and II 1 at times nn = 0 and nn = 1, respectively. The investors are assumed to retire at time nn = 2, so they do not receive any wage incomes after that time. Before retirement, they should save a portion of their wage income with given rates θθ nn SS in the social security and and θθ nn RRRR into the retirement pension. 4 Because we consider only a DC retirement pension, not a defined-benefit (DB) retirement pension, 5 the investors choose the risky investment rate ππ nn RP (nn = 0,1) in the retirement pension. After saving in two pensions and making their asset allocation in the retirement pension, the investors sequentially choose the consumption level CC nn and the risky investment rate ππ nn of the surplus wealth (WW nn CC nn + (1 θθ SS θθ RRRR )II nn ). When we denote time-nn wealth level in the retirement pension by WW nn RRRR with initial wealth WW 0 RRRR = 0, the relationships between two subsequent wealth levels, (WW nn 1, WW RRRR nn 1 ) and (WW nn, WW RRRR nn ), before the retirement are given as follows: WW nn = (αα nn RR)ππ nn 1 (WW nn 1 CC nn 1 + (1 θθ SS θθ RRRR )II nn 1 ) + RR(WW nn 1 CC nn 1 + (1 θθ SS θθ RRRR )II nn 1 ), WW RRRR nn = (αα nn RR)ππ RRRR nn 1 (WW RRRR nn 1 + θθ RRRR II nn 1 ) + RR(WW RRRR nn 1 + θθ RRRR II nn 1 ), for nn = 1,2. After retirement, investors wage income is replaced by annuity income from the social security and the retirement pension. The social security income is assumed to be proportional to the last wage income II 1 with a given constant rate ρρ SS. In contrast, the regular payment II RRRR of the retirement pension is fairly determined; i.e., the expected value of discounted sum of 4 Although, in reality, the investors can choose the amount of saving in the retirement pension, such as 401(k), RRRR we suppose that the savings-to-income ratio θθ nn is exogenously given. This is because we want to focus on the risky investment ratio in the retirement pension. 5 Milevsky and Young (2007) consider only a DB retirement pension. However, we choose a DC type because, after dot-com crash in 2000, the shift from DB pensions to DC pensions has accelerated.

incomes from the retirement pension II RRRR + (1 δδ 3 )ββii RRRR should be equal to the wealth level WW 2 RRRR at retirement, nn = 2: WW 2 RRRR = II RRRR + (1 δδ 3 )RRII RRRR, so ρρ RRRR = 1 1 + (1 δδ 3 )RR, where δδ nn (nn = 1,2,3,4) is the time-nn probability of investor s death. Now, we can construct the relationships between two subsequent wealth levels WW nn 1 and WW nn, after retirement with these annuity incomes ρρ SS II 1 and ρρ RRRR WW 2 RRRR : WW nn = (αα nn RR)ππ nn 1 (WW nn 1 CC nn 1 + ρρ SS II 1 + ρρ RRRR WW 2 RRRR ) + RR(WW nn 1 CC nn 1 + ρρ SS II 1 + ρρ RRRR WW 2 RRRR ), for nn = 3,4. 2.2. The Problem: Optimal Lifetime Consumption and Investment Decisions Based on the wealth process, the investors choose consumption and investment strategies that maximize their happiness, which is measured by the value function. We use an Epstein-Zin type recursive utility to describe the characteristics of the investors. Therefore, our optimal continuation value function of the investors is written as equations (1) and (2), VV nn LL = for nn = 0,1, VV nn LL = 1 ρρ max cc CC nn CC bb,ππ nn,ππ ππ RRRR nn nn ππ DD + ββ δδ nn+1 EE nn VV nn+1 1 γγ LL + (1 δδ nn+1 )EE nn VV nn+1 1 1 ρρ 1 γγ 1 γγ 1 ρ max cc 1 ρρ DD nn + ββ δδ nn+1 EE nn VV 1 γγ 1 ρρ LL 1 γγ nn+1 + (1 δδ nn+1 )EE nn VV nn+1 CC nn CC aa,ππ nn, 1 1 γγ 1 ρ, (1) (2) for nn = 2,3, and VV nn DD = WW nn, for nn = 1,2,3,4, (3)

subject to WW nn = (αα nn RR)ππ nn 1 (WW nn 1 CC nn 1 + (1 θθ SS θθ RRRR )II nn 1 ) + RR(WW nn 1 CC nn 1 + (1 θθ SS θθ RRRR )II nn 1 ), WW RP nn = (αα nn RR)ππ RP nn 1 WW RP nn 1 + θθ RP II nn 1 + RR WW RP nn 1 + θθ RP II nn 1, for nn = 1,2, and for nn = 3,4, and WW nn = (αα nn RR)ππ nn 1 (WW nn 1 CC nn 1 + ρρ SS II 2 + ρρ RRRR WW 2 RRRR ) + RR(WW nn 1 CC nn 1 + ρρ SS II 2 + ρρ RRRR WW 2 RRRR ), CC nn CCbb for nn = 0,1, CC aa for nn = 2,3, ππ ππ nn RRRR ππ for nn = 0,1, (5) (4) where ββ represents subjective discount rate, γγ is the relative risk aversion level, and ηη = 1/ρρ means the level of elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption. In equations (1) and (2), our continuation value function is the maximized equivalent wealth level of the investors. Following the definition of the continuation value function, we can define the value DD DD function VV nn at death as a wealth level at that moment (equation (3)). The value function VV nn at death naturally reflects the bequest motif of the investors. Equations (4) and (5) represent constraints on control variables CC nn and ππ RP nn, respectively. Constraint (4) on consumption CC nn follows naturally from the requirement of a minimum consumption level required to sustain life. The subsistence levels CC bb and CC aa in consumption before and after retirement obviously restrict the possibilities of substituting consumption intertemporally. Constraint (5) is usually imposed from a legal point of view: to prevent illegal trading through a large-size retirement pension, some countries impose position limits on the investment rate in retirement pensions. 3. Data and Parameter Estimation We chose baseline parameters (see Table 1) by methods and from sources that we describe in this section.

Table 1. Base parameter set. In this section, we use the parameters in this table. The estimation process is presented in detail in the following paragraphs. Market Conditions Wealth & Wage Annuities Preferences Parameter Base Lines time interval (Δtt, year) 15 15-year gross return rate of risk free asset (RR) 1.33 probability of up markets (pp uu ) 0.722719 15-year gross return rate of risky asset in case of up markets (αα uu ) 4.28534 15-year gross return rate of risky asset in case of down markets (αα dd ) 0.409691 wealth level (ww 0 ) $347200 wage level ({II 1, II 2 }) {$630308, $644511} portion of wage saved in state social security ({θθ SS 1, θθ SS 2 }) {7.19%, 10.94%} output-to-input ratio of state social security (ρρ SS ) 43% portion of wage saved in retirement pension (θθ RRRR ) 10% or 15% upper position limit (ππ) 1.0 lower position limit (ππ) 0.0 mortality rate ({δδ 1, δδ 2, δδ 3 }) {4.0%, 13.0%, 38.1%} subjective discount rate (ββ) 0.86 level of relative risk aversion (γγ) 5 level of EIS (ηη) 1/3 Because the time interval Δtt = 15 years of our problem is rather large, we carefully chose the parameters RR, αα uu, αα dd, and pp uu related to financial market conditions. The 15-year risk-free gross return RR = 1.33 = 1.0192 15 is based on Ibbotson s Capital Market Assumptions (CMAs) as of December 31, 2011. The assumptions reported that the annual expected rate return rate of cash (IA SBBI US 30-Day TBill TR USD) is 1.92%. On the contrary, the stock parameters αα uu, αα dd, and pp uu are estimated using the following optimization process. In this parameter estimation process, we use the mean Mean = E[αα nn ] = pp uu αα uu + (1 pp uu )αα dd and standard deviation Std. = Var[αα nn ] = (pp uu (αα uu ) 2 + (1 pp uu )(αα dd ) 2 ) (pp uu αα uu + (1 pp uu )αα dd ) 2

of the expected return rate of the S&P 500 Index. We chose the set of parameter values that minimize the sum of squared errors of the mean and the standard deviation: min Mean (ppuu αα uu + (1 pp uu )αα dd ) 2 α u,α d,p u + Std. (pp uu (αα uu ) 2 + (1 pp uu )(αα dd ) 2 ) (pp uu αα uu + (1 pp uu )αα dd ) 2 2, subject to αα uu > RR > αα dd > 0 and 0 < pp < 1. To calculate the moments of the 15-year gross return of the S&P 500 Index, we used the closed value of the S&P 500 Index on a yearly basis from Yahoo Finance. Then, we generated two 15-year S&P 500 Index gross return data sets: the first data set contains 15-year gross return over a moving window; the second contains 15- year gross return from non-overlapping periods. Estimation results using the two data sets were quite similar and both sums of squared errors are significantly negligible. Therefore, we adopt the following parameters as a baseline: αα uu = 4.28534, αα dd = 0.409691, and pp uu = 0.722719. Table 2. Estimation results for the parameters related to market conditions. Rows: estimates of stock parameters αα uu, αα dd, and pp uu with different data sets: Ibbotson s Capital Market Assumptions (2 nd row), nonoverlapped 15-years gross return rate of S&P 500 Index from Yahoo Finance (3 rd row), and 15-years gross return of S&P 500 Index with a moving window sampling (4 th row). IA SBBI S&P 500 S&P 500 (1950-2012) Non-overlapping S&P 500 (1950-2012) Moving Window Mean Std. αα uu αα dd pp uu 3.96 0.7552 =(1+9.61%) 15 =0.1950*15 1/2 4.15617 1.05269 0.93679 3.274108 1.732944 4.31 0.375074 0.736744 3.210693 1.734957 4.28534 0.409691 0.722719 An individual s initial wealth level WW is estimated based on the data of the 2013 Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF). Because we are interested in the optimal lifetime consumption and

investment strategies of individuals aged 35 years, we use the estimates 6 of that group aged 35 to 44; i.e., WW = $488100. The wage income level II is obtained from the data of Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey. 7 We use the median weekly earnings of full-time wage and salary workers to estimate the wage income level. We calculate 15-year wage levels II 1 = $630308 and II 2 = $644511 by adding all discounted annual wage for 15 years: 14 aa II nn = II nn,kk kk RR kk=0 aa = II aa nn,kk 1 1 15 RR aa 1 1 RR aa, for nn = 1,2, aa where RR aa = 1.01192% is the gross annual risk-free return rate and II nn,kk is the annual wage income level at age (20 + 15nn + kk). We set the parameters related to the social security or the retirement pension as follows: θθ 1 SS = 7.19% and θθ 2 SS = 10.94%. The amount saved in the social security is mandated. We just assume that the saving rate starts at 3% at age 25 and increases by 0.25% per year until retirement. As we convert the annual wage level to the 15-year wage level, we also adjust the annual saving rate for the social security to the time interval Δtt = 15 of our model: θθ 1 SS = 7.19% and θθ 2 SS = 10.94%. The payment-to-income ratio ρρ SS of the social security is assumed to be 43%, which is calculated on the homepage of American Association of Retired Persons (AARP). We assume that the investors save 10% or 15% of their salary into the retirement pension throughout their career; these rates are commonly recommended in 401k, which is the most popular retirement pension. Because 401k has no position limits, we just assume ππ = 1.0 and ππ = 0.0, excluding leverages and short positions. The mortality rate, which is essential to the calculation on the retirement pension payment, is obtained from the Social Security Periodic Life Table, which is publicly available: δδ 1 = 0.04, δδ 2 = 0.13 δδ 3 = 0.381, and δδ 4 = 1.0. The annual subjective discount factor is assumed to be 0.99. Therefore, the 15-year subjective discount factor ββ = 0.86 = 0.99 15. The risk aversion and EIS in consumption are assumed 6 We use mean value of assets and before-tax family income before-tax family income for families with holdings as estimates for the wealth and income levels, respectively. 7 One can access to this statistics via Bureau of Labor Statistics.

to be 5 and 1/3, respectively. 4. Implication Using the baseline parameters (Table 2), we calculated the investors optimal lifetime consumption and investment strategies, including the optimal control variables, the consumption-to-wealth ratio CC /WW, the risky investment rate ππ, and the risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension, as functions of the subsistence level CC aa /WW = CC bb /WW in at 0 CC /WW to 2 (Figure 1). The range of the subsistence level in CC /WW is based on the definition of the subsistence level in consumption. The subsistence level in consumption is defined as a mode of consumption that corresponds to the basic needs of life. Our basic needs of life includes welfare as well as a dietary needs, so the interpretation of our subsistence level corresponds to the weak poverty line, not the strong poverty line which is used to identify that part of population that is regarded as absolutely poor. 8 The median income-to-wealth ratio of the group with income from the bottom 20% to the bottom 40% is 1.13 and the median ratio of the group with income from the bottom 40% to the bottom 60% is 1.85. Neither group is absolutely poor, but can be considered as weakly poor in some sense. Therefore, we guess that an appropriate subsistence level in CC /WW might be between 1 and 2. Figure 1. Optimal strategies ππ (left), ππ RRRR (middle), and CC /WW 00 (right) as functions of subsistence level 8 Steger (2000) interprets the subsistence level as the strong poverty line.

CC aa /WW = CC bb /WW in the consumption-to-wealth ratio. Although Figure 1 plots the optimal consumption and investment strategies for a wide range of subsistence level from 0 to 2, the optimal strategies are obviously trivial when the subsistence level in CC /WW is less than 1. The optimal strategies become trivial again when the subsistence level is large, i.e., larger than about 1.6. Based on these results, we choose two reasonable subsistence levels: a low (1.2) one and a high (1.5) one. With these two levels, we investigate the effect of the subsistence level on the optimal consumption and investment behaviors. Along the subsistence level in consumption-to-wealth ratio, the shape of optimal consumption and investment behaviors as functions of investment opportunities and investors preferences change greatly. This trend means that optimal consumption and investment decisions should be adjusted depending on the individuals subjective subsistence levels. Case 1: Low subsistence level 1.2 in consumption-to-wealth ratio Optimal consumption and investment strategies for this case vary with risk-free gross return RR (Figure 2). As has been seen in traditional optimal investment problems, the optimal risky investment rate ππ decreases with the risk-free gross return RR. This relationship is natural because as the risk-free gross return increases, the risky asset becomes decreasingly attractive to investors. However, the optimal risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension increases with the risk-free gross return RR when the risk-free gross return is considerably low. Based on this numerical result, we can say that the retirement pension also contributes to generation of a minimum guaranteed income stream that is necessary for subsistence level in consumption. When the risk-free gross return is not high enough, the investors underestimate their wealth level, so they think that their wealth is too low to sustain subsistence level in consumption after their retirement. When the risk-free gross return is low, some future optimal consumption-to-wealth ratios CC nn /WW at a future down state bind to the subsistence level CC a /W = CC bb /WW in the consumption-to-wealth ratio. In this case, the investors will prefer to increase the proportion of their wealth that is invested in the risky asset for a high-risk-highreturn investment. With increase in the riskiness of investment in the retirement pension, which RP is expected to maximize the wealth WW 2 in the retirement pension, investors expect to maintain the optimal consumption amount above the subsistence level for any economic state. In contrast, when the risk-free gross return RR is high enough, the retirement pension is used

to generate a desired additional income stream. Without using the retirement pension, investors can match the minimum guaranteed income stream by allocating assets directly to the risk-free asset and the risky asset. In this circumstance, investors choose the optimal risky investment rate in the retirement pension to maximize the risk-adjusted total return rate without any constraints. When the risk-free gross return is high, investors can obtain the maximum riskadjusted return even with small exposure to risk, so the investment rate in the retirement pension decreases with the risk-free gross return RR. Figure 2. Optimal strategies ππ (left), ππ RRRR (middle), and CC /WW (right) as functions of risk-free gross return RR with subsistence level 1.2 in consumption-to-wealth ratio. Optimal consumption and investment strategies show traditional optimal consumption and investment behaviors: the investment and consumption ratios increase with the up probability pp uu (Figure 3) and decrease with the relative risk aversion (RRA) level γγ (Figure 4). Because the investment environment becomes increasingly positive as pp uu increases, the two optimal investment rates ππ and ππ RP increase monotonically with pp uu. In contrast, all optimal strategies ππ, ππ RP, and CC /WW decrease with γγ because the attractiveness of the risky asset decreases as the risk-aversion of the investors increases. The graphs of the optimal risky investment rate ππ are steep when the graphs of the optimal risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension are flat. This relationship implies that both the direct risky investment and the risky investment in the retirement pension increase the

total risky investment. When the risky investment rate ππ RP binds to any boundaries ππ or ππ, the risky investment rate ππ RP rate ππ changes more dramatically. cannot change any more, so instead the direct risky investment Figure 3. The optimal strategies ππ (left), ππ RRRR (middle), and CC /WW (right) as functions of up probability pp uu with subsistence level 1.2 in consumption-to-wealth ratio. Figure 4. The optimal strategies ππ (left), ππ RRRR (middle), and CC /WW (right) as functions of the relative risk aversion level γγ with subsistence level 1.2 in consumption-to-wealth ratio.

Case 2: High subsistence level 1.5 in consumption-to-wealth ratio When the subsistence level in consumption-to-wealth ratio was high, the plots of optimal strategies ππ, ππ RP, and CC /WW functions of pp uu (Figures 5) and γγ (Figures 6) showed interesting responses. In the graph of risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension vs. pp uu (Figure 5, middle), the risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension increased until pp uu 0.7, then decreased. The increase in this graph can be explained as usual: generally, the increase in investment amount is natural when the investment opportunity improves. Especially, when the investment opportunity is bad, the investors underestimate their future annuity income, so to support future subsistence level in consumption, they increase their risky investments as pp uu increases. This explanation is confirmed by the consumption-to-wealth ratio graph in Figure 5. During the risky investment ππ RP increases, CC /WW binds to the subsistence level. After pp uu becomes high enough, the risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension does not increase, but decreases even though the market condition improves or pp uu increases. This response is a consequence of the mortality risk. The total earning from the retirement pension changes depending on the individual s death time, so we can say the exposed amount RP of mortality risk is proportional wealth level WW 2 at time 2 in the retirement pension. As pp uu increases, the investors overvalue the wealth in the retirement pension. This behavior leads to the increase in the volatility of the earnings from the retirement pension because the amount of the earnings varies due to the mortality risk, therefore risk-averse investors prefer the risk-free asset in the retirement pension.

Figure 5. The optimal strategies ππ (left), ππ RRRR (middle), and CC /WW 00 (right) as functions of up probability pp uu with subsistence level 1.5 in consumption-to-wealth ratio. The optimal investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension as a function of γγ is also humpshaped (Figure 6, middle). The optimal investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension increases even when γγ increases. Although this observation seems unnatural because the investment rates usually decrease with γγ, this trend can be explained by the influence of risky investment in the retirement pension as a substitution for a risky asset. An investor can invest in a risky asset in two ways: direct investment, and investment through the retirement pension. Total investment in the risky asset decreases as the investors risk-aversion increases. However, the investors can increase the investment in the retirement pension by dramatically decreasing the direct investment. Because the structural characteristics of the retirement pension can partially hedge the longevity risk, the investor can reduce the total risk by increasing their investment in the retirement pension, instead of by directly investing in the risky asset. The striking decrease in the investment rate ππ with a low γγ (Figure 6, left) is consistent with this explanation. Figure 6. Optimal strategies ππ (left), ππ RRRR (middle), and CC /WW 00 (right) as functions of the relative risk aversion (RRA) level γγ with subsistence level 1.2 in consumption-to-wealth ratio.

Figure 7. Optimal strategies ππ (left), ππ RRRR (middle), and CC /WW 00 (right) as functions of risk-free gross return RR with subsistence level 1.5 in consumption-to-wealth ratio. The optimal strategies ππ, ππ RP, and CC /WW as functions of risk-free gross return RR differ according to the subsistence level (Figures 1, 7). The major difference is observed in optimal risky investment rate ππ (Figures 1 and 7, left). At subsistence level 1.5 (Figure 7), the optimal risky investment rate ππ does not decrease monotonically. When the risk-free gross return is considerably low, investors increase both the direct risky investment amount and the risky investment amount in the retirement pension. This response occurs because as the risk-free rate increases, the minimal wealth in the risk-free asset required for future minimum consumption level decreases. Consistently, the optimal consumption-to-wealth ratio CC /WW stays in the subsistence level while the optimal risky investment rate ππ increases. After the risk-free gross return gets high enough, the investor currently consumes more than the subsistence level because the future subsistence levels can be supported by the surplus wealth after the current consumption. In sum, when subsistence level is high, the subsistence level reinforces the optimal consumption and investment behaviors. When subsistence level is low (CC aa /WW = CC bb /WW = 1.2), the risky investment in the retirement pension only increases with a low risk-free gross return, but when subsistence level is high (CC aa /WW = CC bb /WW = 1.5), the direct risky investment and the risky investment in the retirement pension both decrease. The difference in trends occurs because the individuals motive to achieve a minimum guaranteed income intensifies as

the subsistence level in consumption increases. Therefore we can say that when high subsistence level is high, the top priority of the investors financial management is to guarantee a minimum income stream. The reinforcing effect of the subsistence level on the optimal investment strategy is observed again in other figures. Contrary to the decrease in the direct risky investment in case when subsistence level is low (Figure 2, left), the risky investment rate ππ also increases with the risk-free gross return when subsistence level is high (Figure 7, left). The difference means that the investors who desire a high subsistence level of consumption can ensure current or future minimum incomes by holding both a risky asset and a retirement pension. In addition, the effect of the subsistence level is only observed when the subsistence level was high (Figures 5, 6); when it was low, the effects (Figure 3, 4) were definitely similar to that of classical Merton s problem that does not consider the subsistence level. The risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension very noticeably increases along with the increase in γγ only when the subsistence level is sufficiently high (Figure 6, middle). Because the risky investment rate ππ decreases with γγ as usual, we can conclude that in this case the risky investment in the retirement pension has different purpose from the direct risky investment. When the subsistence level is considerably high, the investors directly invest in the risky asset to generate the required additional income, but in the retirement pension the purpose of the risky investment is to stabilize the after-retirement income stream, which is less risky than the return from the direct risky investment. These results indicate that when the investors hold a retirement pension for the purpose of guaranteeing an income, the risky investment in the retirement pension can substitute the direct risky investment for own purpose. Both risky investments increase the risk to which the investor is currently exposed, but give different payoffs after the investors retirement. When the investors have a strong motive to stabilize their future income stream, they prefer the risky investment in the retirement pension to the direct risky investment. As a consequence, they increase the risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension and decrease the investment rate ππ ; i.e., the risky investment in the retirement pension has a substitution effect on the risky investment. The substitution effect is not the only consequence of risky investment in the retirement pension. Basically, the risky investment in the retirement pension has a complementary effect on the direct investment in the risky asset; i.e., that the investment in the retirement pension reinforces the total investment amount in the risky asset. This effect occurs because the risky

investment in the retirement pension is a part of total risky investment. As the risky investment rate ππ RP in the retirement pension increases, the total investment rate also increases as long as the change of the investment in the retirement pension does not offset the change in the direct investment. This complementary effect is clearly observed when the subsistence level was low (Figures 3, 4). The complementary and the substitution effects are, respectively, related to the two different purposes of the retirement pension: the additional-income purpose and the guaranteed-income purpose. When the investors require additional income from the retirement pension as they expect in the direct risky investment, the complementary effect is dominant. On the contrary, when the investors want to make a minimum-guaranteed income from the retirement pension, the substitution effect becomes dominant; i.e., the prominence of the substitution effect increases when the investors have a high subsistence level in consumption. Finally, we can say that retirement planning that does not consider the subsistence level in consumption can lead to an inappropriate investment strategy in the retirement pension when the investors mainly want to receive a guaranteed stable income stream after retirement. 5. Conclusion Our model proposes an integrated retirement plan that both maximizes the market value of a future income stream, and guarantees a minimum income stream. Our main contribution is to show that the subsistence level in consumption, which means that the optimal lifetime consumption and investment strategy of an investor are influenced by the guaranteed minimum income stream that the investor desires. Our numerical results show that, depending on the market environment, investors hold a retirement pension for different purposes: either to guarantee a minimum income or to provide additional desired income. The amount of the annuity from the retirement pension does not depend on the economic states after investors retirement, so when the financial market is depressed, investors use the retirement pension to prepare a stable after-retirement income stream. In contrast, when the market condition is favorable, the retirement pension is used to generate a desired additional income because investors can support the subsistence level in consumption only by investing in a risk-free asset and a risky asset. Finally, our model confirms that the subsistence level in consumption must be considered

when developing an optimal retirement plan. The optimal behaviors that our model predicts for reasonable subsistence levels in consumption are different from the predictions of the classical optimal consumption and investment behaviors. Our numerical results demonstrate that the risky investment rate in the retirement pension can increase even when the low risk-free rate or the low risk aversion level increase and that the risky investment rate in the retirement pension can decrease even in a prosperous market condition. Appendix A. Summary of the Algorithm to Solve the Problem Equations (1) and (2) define the value function of our problem recursively. Therefore, in those equations, time-nn continuation value function VV nn LL depends on the optimal strategies ππ nn, RP ππ nn, CC DD nn /WW, the time-(nn + 1) value function VV nn+1 at death, and the continuation value LL LL function VV nn+1. Here, time-(nn + 1) continuation value function VV nn+1 depends on the nexttime optimal strategies ππ nn+1, ππ RP nn+1, and CC nn+1 /WW. Therefore, time-nn continuation value LL function VV nn depends on time-nn or time-(nn + 1) optimal strategies ππ RP nn, ππ nn, CC nn /WW, ππ nn+1, RP ππ LL nn+1, and CC nn+1 /WW. Repeating this logic, we can represent the current value function VV 0 with a maximization operator with respect to all choice variables at any node in our binomial tree model. Solving this maximization problem combined with (3), (4), and (5), yields the solution of our model. All results in this paper were calculated using the optimization toolbox and the global optimization toolbox of Matlab. References Blanchett, David M, and Hal Ratner, 2015, Building Efficient Income Portfolios, The Journal of Portfolio Management 41. Blanchett, David M, and Philip U Straehl, 2015, No Portfolio Is an Island, Financial Analysts Journal 71, 15 33. Chen, Peng, Roger G. Ibbotson, Moshe A. Milevsky, and Kevin X. Zhu, 2006, Human capital, asset allocation, and life insurance, Financial Analysts Journal 62, 97 109. Constantinides, George M., 1990, Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle, Journal of Political Economy 98, 519 543. Gomes, Francisco, and Alexander Michaelides, 2005, Optimal Life-Cycle Asset Allocation: Understanding the Empirical Evidence, The Journal of Finance 60, 869 904.

Dai, Min, Yue Kuen Kwok, and Jianping Zong, 2008, Guaranteed Minimum Withdrawal Benefit in Variable Annuities, Mathematical Finance 18, 595 611. Horneff, Wolfram J., Raimond H. Maurer, and Michael Z. Stamos, 2008, Life-cycle asset allocation with annuity markets, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32, 3590 3612. Huang, Huaxiong, and Moshe A. Milevsky, 2008, Portfolio choice and mortality-contingent claims: The general HARA case, Journal of Banking & Finance 32, 2444 2452. Merton, Robert C., 2003, Thoughts on the Future: Theory and Practice in Investment Management, Financial Analysts Journal 59, 17 23. Merton, Robert C. 2014. The Crisis in Retirement Planning. Harvard Business Review (July). Milevsky, Moshe A., and Thomas S. Salisbury, 2006, Financial valuation of guaranteed minimum withdrawal benefits, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 38, 21 38. Milevsky, Moshe A., and Virginia R. Young, 2007, Annuitization and asset allocation, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31, 3138 3177. Steger, Thomas M, 2000, Economic growth with subsistence consumption, Journal of Development Economics 62, 343 361.