2. Theory and Discussion

Similar documents
Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE

Price Discrimination and Two Part Tariff

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron.

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 15. MONOPOLY

ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes.

Monopoly: static and dynamic efficiency M.Motta, Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge University Press, 2004; ch. 2

Final Exam 15 December 2006


Chapter 15: Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE HOW MONOPOLIES MAKE PRODUCTION AND PRICING DECISIONS

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

Rutgers University Economics 102: Introductory Microeconomics Professor Altshuler Fall 2003

Monopolistic Competition

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

Quantity of trips supplied (millions)

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits.

Chapter 8 Application: The Costs of Taxation

Thus MR(Q) = P (Q) Q P (Q 1) (Q 1) < P (Q) Q P (Q) (Q 1) = P (Q), since P (Q 1) > P (Q).

Economics Chapter 7 Review

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table.

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade

Market is a network of dealings between buyers and sellers.

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

Chapter 03 The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Pre-Test Chapter 18 ed17

SOLUTIONS TO HOMEWORK SET #4

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Price Discrimination

A. a change in demand. B. a change in quantity demanded. C. a change in quantity supplied. D. unit elasticity. E. a change in average variable cost.

Monopoly. Monopoly Defined

SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION

Chapter 6 MULTIPLE-CHOICE QUESTIONS

Monopoly and Monopsony Labor Market Behavior

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it?

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

Figure 1, A Monopolistically Competitive Firm

LABOR UNIONS. Appendix. Key Concepts

Monopoly Quantity & Price Elasticity Welfare. Monopoly Chapter 24

Principle of Microeconomics Econ chapter 13

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

Pricing and Output Decisions: i Perfect. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e By Paul Keat and Philip Young

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

6. Which of the following is likely to be the price elasticity of demand for food? a. 5.2 b. 2.6 c. 1.8 d. 0.3

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Econ 201 Final Exam. Douglas, Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

CHAPTER 11 PRICE AND OUTPUT IN MONOPOLY, MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, AND PERFECT COMPETITION

chapter: Solution Solution Monopoly 1. Each of the following firms possesses market power. Explain its source.

Sustainable Energy Systems

Figure 1. D S (private) S' (social) Quantity (tons of medicine)

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Market Structures. Market Structures (cont.) The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

I. Introduction to Taxation

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Problem Set #6 Due: Wednesday, November 3

Common in European countries government runs telephone, water, electric companies.

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

Marginal cost. Average cost. Marginal revenue

Problem Set 9 (75 points)

At the end of Chapter 18, you should be able to answer the following:

An Integrated Approach to Teaching Price Discrimination

Market Failure. presented by: Dr. Ellen Sewell

Practice Multiple Choice Questions Answers are bolded. Explanations to come soon!!

Basic Monopoly Theory

How To Calculate Profit Maximization In A Competitive Dairy Firm

Economics 335, Spring 1999 Problem Set #7

CEVAPLAR. Solution: a. Given the competitive nature of the industry, Conigan should equate P to MC.

Exam Prep Questions and Answers

Econ 202 Exam 3 Practice Problems

Economics 100 Exam 2

THE UNIVERSITY OF AUCKLAND

4.1.1 Monopolistic Competition

Monopolistic Competition

Market Structure: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D)

Figure: Computing Monopoly Profit

Chapter 6 Supply, Demand, and Government Policies

Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes

MPP 801 Monopoly Kevin Wainwright Study Questions

Name Eco200: Practice Test 2 Covering Chapters 10 through 15

Econ 202 Exam 2 Practice Problems

Long Run Supply and the Analysis of Competitive Markets. 1 Long Run Competitive Equilibrium

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

1) If the government sets a price ceiling below the monopoly price, will this reduce deadweight loss in a monopolized market?

Standard Costs Overview

Transcription:

1. Introduction First degree price discrimination is generally regarded as a socially efficient alternative to standard pricing for monopoly firms. A single price strategy in a monopoly market results in a price above marginal cost, creating a deadweight loss. First degree price discrimination is commonly believed to eliminate deadweight loss by charging consumers according to their willingness to pay and transferring consumer surplus to the producer. However, standard price discrimination theory ignores both the costs that firms incur to successfully price discriminate and the costs imposed on consumers from a price discrimination strategy. While previous research has alluded to the costs involved in price discrimination (Posner, 1975), Varian (1989) is one of the first to question the impact of complex forms of price discrimination on economic welfare. He notes that the costs required of producers and imposed on consumers may grow as price discrimination techniques become more complex. In a survey of recent economic literature regarding price discrimination, Armstrong (2006) highlights a number of creative strategies that firms can employ to engage in price discrimination. In order to successfully implement such price discrimination schemes, firms incur costs through activities such as information collection, the design of pricing schemes, and resale prevention when attempting to price discriminate. Costs are also imposed on consumers as the consumer must search for the least expensive way to purchase and provide information to the firm to prove their willingness and ability to pay. These costs are prevalent in the most common examples of price discrimination such as airline ticket sales, used car purchases, and higher education tuition. The consideration of these costs alters the impact of first degree price discrimination on social welfare. Bhaskar and To (2004) show that price discrimination can be socially inefficient with free entry in a monopolistic competition setting due to excessive entry into the industry. Leeson and Sobel (2008) provide the first model to incorporate transaction costs into price discrimination theory. They note that the monopolist will engage in price discrimination if the gains to the monopolist, composed of extracted consumer surplus and deadweight loss, are greater than the costs associated with the price discrimination strategy. This can result in a reduction of social welfare if the firm s costs of price discrimination are less than the combined gains to the monopolist but greater than the social welfare gains from eliminating deadweight loss. While socially inefficient, the monopolist may find it privately beneficial to price discriminate. The model developed in this paper evaluates first degree price discrimination by examining the additional costs incurred by the monopolist firm and the costs imposed on consumers from a price discrimination strategy. The inclusion of consumer costs reduces the consumer surplus and the deadweight loss that the monopolist can transfer through price discrimination while also reducing producer surplus previously attributed to the firm. These additional costs alter the scenarios under which the monopolist will find price discrimination profitable and impact the extent to which price discrimination can improve social welfare. 2. Theory and Discussion Assuming linear demand and constant marginal cost, the conditions for the monopolist firm are displayed in Figure 1. Standard price discrimination theory suggests that the monopolist can gain the area of triangle ace (consumer surplus) and triangle egi (deadweight loss). However, this 371

does not include the additional costs that are required of consumers and producers due to price discrimination. Figure 1: Monopolist Private Benefit and Social Welfare Gains with Producer & Consumer Transaction Costs P a b P M c d e f C C P C g h i MC MR D D Q M Q C Q C Q For simplicity, it is assumed that the price discrimination strategy imposes a constant cost on consumers and all parties have full information. 1 has the effect of reducing the benefit of purchase to consumers. Graphically, this reduction of benefit can be displayed similar to the imposition of an excise tax on consumers. Because reduces the benefit to the consumer, consumers are less willing to pay for the good or service by the amount of. This cost is 1 The costs imposed on consumers from a price discrimination strategy may not necessarily be constant as lower paying customers may need to exert more effort to identify the lower price available to them and prove their willingness and ability to pay. Higher paying customers may simply pay the price indicated on the demand curve. 372

accounted for in Figure 1 with demand curve. The firm will sell fewer units at any given price with when employing price discrimination relative to under a single pricing scheme. With the demand curve accounting for the additional costs that consumers face, the monopolist sells the quantity under first degree price discrimination. However, the costs imposed on consumers from price discrimination have a negative impact on the amount of consumer surplus that the monopolist can capture through price discrimination. Additionally, the deadweight loss available to the monopolist for transfer is reduced by the transaction cost imposed on the consumers. The consumer transaction costs reduce the consumer s value gained from purchase of the product, thus reducing their willingness to pay for the product. This results in a reduction of both consumer surplus and deadweight loss available for transfer. The eliminated consumer surplus and deadweight loss that cannot be captured by the firm are displayed in Figure 1 as area abde and area efhj respectively. Furthermore, the monopolist loses a portion of the producer surplus that the firm enjoyed under a single pricing scheme. This occurs because consumers are less willing to pay for the product due to the transaction costs. This is defined as area def in Figure 1. The monopolist is able to capture some of the consumer surplus, area bcd, and some of the deadweight loss, area fgh, when engaging in price discrimination with consumer costs included. Furthermore, the monopolist firm faces additional costs when engaging in price discrimination. For simplicity, it is assumed that the monopolist firm faces a fixed cost when engaging in price discrimination, defined as. 2 Once accounting for both the costs imposed on consumers,, and the costs that the monopolist firm must expend to successfully price discriminate,, the conditions under which the monopolist firm will find price discrimination profitable and the conditions where price discrimination results in social welfare gains can be defined. Referring to Figure 1, the monopolist firm will choose to engage in price discrimination if the gains to the firm from transferring consumer surplus (area bcd) and capturing deadweight loss (area fgh) outweigh the loss of producer surplus under a single pricing scheme (area def) and the transaction cost of implementing the price discrimination strategy ( ). Otherwise, the monopolist will choose a single price strategy. However, social welfare may be enhanced or reduced when the monopolist chooses to engage in price discrimination. In order to evaluate the impact of price discrimination on social welfare, it is necessary to compare the deadweight loss that the monopolist gains (area fgh) to the combination of the lost portion of consumer surplus (area abde), the lost portion of producer surplus (area def), and the transaction cost that the firm must undertake to successfully price discriminate ( ). If the deadweight loss captured by the monopoly firm exceeds the loss of producer and consumer surplus and the cost of price discrimination attributed to the firm, social welfare is improved. Formally, the gained deadweight loss can be identified as. The combined loss of consumer surplus and producer surplus can be written as. When combined with the transaction cost of the firm ( ), we can derive the formal conditions under which price discrimination enhances or reduces social welfare. 2 Firms may experience variable costs when engaging in first degree price discrimination as there could be different costs associated with implementing a price discrimination strategy for different consumers. The inclusion of variable costs would not alter the general results of this analysis. 373

If > + C F, the implementation of price discrimination results in an increase in social welfare. The gained deadweight loss outweighs the lost consumer surplus, lost producer surplus, and the costs incurred by the firm. However, if < +, social welfare is reduced when price discrimination is employed. While the producer may find it privately beneficial to engage in price discrimination, the result is a net reduction in social welfare. 3. Conclusion When the costs that producers incur to engage in price discrimination and the costs that are imposed on consumers as the result of a price discrimination strategy are examined, the potential gains from price discrimination available to the firm are less than previously considered when ignoring transaction costs. While the price discriminating firm is able to capture a portion of consumer surplus and deadweight loss relative to a single pricing scheme, the firm must expend resources to successfully price discriminate and concede a portion of their previous producer surplus. Additionally, a portion of consumer surplus and part of the deadweight loss from a single price strategy are eliminated due to the transaction costs imposed on consumers. The model described in this manuscript shows that first degree price discrimination does not necessarily result in an increase in social welfare. While price discrimination can lead to an increase in social welfare, the improvement in social welfare is contingent on the deadweight loss that the monopolist captures outweighing both the transaction costs incurred by the firm from implementing price discrimination and the reduction in consumer and producer surplus that is the result of the price discrimination strategy. As Varian (1989) argues, the transaction costs that consumers and producers face become important as price discrimination techniques advance and become more complex. The costs of price discrimination can rise as firms develop increasingly sophisticated techniques to engage in price discrimination. Additionally, complex forms of price discrimination may impose nontrivial costs on consumers who must search for the best price and signal their ability and willingness to pay for a good or service. The consideration of these additional transaction costs highlights the difficulty of engaging in price discrimination. Firms must consider a number of potentially significant costs that are difficult to measure when considering a price discrimination strategy. Producer and consumer transaction costs are present in all forms of price discrimination and regardless of the demand and cost conditions. Although this analysis assumes that first degree price discrimination imposes a constant cost on consumers, costs may vary among consumers that pay different prices. Lower paying consumers may face higher transaction costs as they must identify themselves to firms while higher paying consumers may simply pay the higher price and not incur additional transaction costs. Additionally, an examination of the consequences of alternate demand specifications and varying cost structures would be useful. While this analysis focused on the social efficiency implications of first degree price discrimination, producer and consumer transaction costs will also impact social efficiency in second and third degree price discrimination. If the additional transaction costs outweigh gains in efficiency, price discrimination can be socially inefficient in second and third degree cases as well. 374

References Armstrong, M. (2006) Recent Developments in the Economics of Price Discrimination in Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Ninth World Congress, Vol. II. by R. Blundell, W.K. Newey, and T. Persson, Eds., Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, 97-141. Bhaskar, V. and T. To (2004) Is Perfect Price Discrimination Really Efficient? An Analysis of Free Entry Rand Journal of Economics 35, 762-776. Posner, R. (1975) The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation Journal of Political Economy 83, 807-828. Leeson, P.T. and R.S. Sobel (2008) Costly Price Discrimination Economic Letters 99, 206-208. Varian, H. (1989) Price Discrimination in Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 1.by R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, Eds., North-Holland: Amsterdam, 597-654. 375