Industrial Organization Lecture 4: Discrimination

Similar documents
PRICE DISCRIMINATION Industrial Organization B

3 Price Discrimination

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing)

Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Sustainable Energy Systems

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

Monopoly: static and dynamic efficiency M.Motta, Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge University Press, 2004; ch. 2

Second degree price discrimination

2.2 Price Discrimination

Exercises for Industrial Organization Master de Economía Industrial Matilde Pinto Machado

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

2. Price Discrimination

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

Oligopoly: Cournot/Bertrand/Stackelberg

1.4 Hidden Information and Price Discrimination 1

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Price Discrimination

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Problem Set 9 Solutions

Figure 1, A Monopolistically Competitive Firm

2.4 Multiproduct Monopoly. 2.4 Multiproduct Monopoly

Product Differentiation In homogeneous goods markets, price competition leads to perfectly competitive outcome, even with two firms Price competition

Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly]

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

HORIZONTAL MERGERS Advanced Industrial Organization 1

Answers to Chapter 6 Exercises

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Managerial Economics. 1 is the application of Economic theory to managerial practice.

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE

Exam Prep Questions and Answers

Lecture 9: Price Discrimination

ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes.

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation. Chapter 8. Group pricing and personalized pricing

Advertising. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Advertising February / 32

Monopolistic Competition

Market Structure: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Monopoly and Monopsony Labor Market Behavior

p, we suppress the wealth arguments in the aggregate demand function. We can thus state the monopolist s problem as follows: max pq (p) c (q (p)).

Solution to Homework Set 7

Frequent flyer programs and dynamic contracting with limited commitment

Foreclosure, Entry, and Competition in Platform Markets with Cloud

ECON 312: Oligopolisitic Competition 1. Industrial Organization Oligopolistic Competition

Common in European countries government runs telephone, water, electric companies.

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

TRADE WITH SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION (CONT'D)

ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS (TUTORIAL)

Conditions for Efficiency in Package Pricing

9.1 Cournot and Bertrand Models with Homogeneous Products

CHAPTER 6 MARKET STRUCTURE

KEELE UNIVERSITY MID-TERM TEST, 2007 BA BUSINESS ECONOMICS BA FINANCE AND ECONOMICS BA MANAGEMENT SCIENCE ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

Monopoly. E. Glen Weyl. Lecture 8 Price Theory and Market Design Fall University of Chicago

Economics 431 Fall st midterm Answer Key

Chapter 11 Pricing With Market Power

Monopoly Quantity & Price Elasticity Welfare. Monopoly Chapter 24

Price Discrimination

Pricing to Mass Markets. Simple Monopoly Pricing, Price Discrimination and the Losses from Monopoly

Cournot s model of oligopoly

Mobile Number Portability

Final Exam 15 December 2006

Managerial Economics

The economics of online personalised pricing

Pure Competition urely competitive markets are used as the benchmark to evaluate market

Price Discrimination and Two Part Tariff

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

Oligopoly and Trade. Notes for Oxford M.Phil. International Trade. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. November 26, 2009

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

On the Antitrust Economics of the Electronic Books Industry

A Strategic Guide on Two-Sided Markets Applied to the ISP Market

Price Discrimination

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it?

Efficient Access Pricing and Endogenous Market. Structure. Kaniska Dam, Axel Gautier and Manipushpak Mitra CAHIER DE RECHERCHE / WORKING PAPER

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

Imperfect information Up to now, consider only firms and consumers who are perfectly informed about market conditions: 1. prices, range of products

Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

First degree price discrimination ECON 171

Pricing in a Competitive Market with a Common Network Resource

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015

Lecture 10 Monopoly Power and Pricing Strategies

Economics Chapter 7 Review

Terry College of Business - ECON 7950

Platform Competition under Asymmetric Information

Why do merchants accept payment cards?

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

Price Discrimination

ECON101 STUDY GUIDE 7 CHAPTER 14

1) If the government sets a price ceiling below the monopoly price, will this reduce deadweight loss in a monopolized market?

International Pricing with Costly Consumer Arbitrage

2. Information Economics

BEE2017 Intermediate Microeconomics 2

Chapter 7: Market Structure in Government and Nonprofit Industries. Soft Drinks. What is a Market? Do NFPs Compete? Some NFPs Compete Directly

Quantity Tax Incidence Subsidy Welfare Effects Case Study. Equilibrium Chapter 16

Transcription:

Industrial Organization Lecture 4: Discrimination Marie-Laure Allain Ecole Polytechnique January 14, 2015 Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 1 / 41

Introduction So far, we have assumed that prices were uniform : unit price, for perfect competition as well as for monopolies / oligopolies One good = one price All consumers pay the same price, irrespective of their valuation (ex: rationing) In practice, different units of a same good can be sold at different prices to the same customer or to different ones: discrimination Example: Different classes (airlines) or packages - different prices for different services Different prices for the same class too: plane tickets prices depends on many factors (when you buy the ticket, flexibility, etc.). Quantity rebates ( the second half price : same product sold at different prices for the same consumer), fidelity rebates Supermarket chains charge higher prices in richer areas. Special prices for young, retirees, large families Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 2 / 41

Introduction Debate on price discrimination: law versus economics Law: discrimination has a negative flavour: does not seem fair a priori Contrast with universal service for telecoms, postal services, electricity Reflecting cost difference is not discriminatory (e.g. delivered prices p + tx) Economics: discrimination = personalisation Other things equal, A firm benefits from offering tailored prices Customers: some win, some lose, and the overall effect is ambiguous (efficiency / redistribution) Strategic interaction: discrimination can increase competition Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 3 / 41

Introduction Three types of discrimination (Pigou, 1920) First degree price discrimination: perfect discrimination A specific price for each unit (for the same or different customers): p ih (q ih ) or T i (q i ). Scond degree price discrimination: self-selection Same menu for all customers, with options tailored to specific needs {p i, q i } i or T (q) (example: two-part tariffs) Third degree price discrimination: based on observable characteristics Age, location, family, etc: a tariff for each group (movie theater, railway services, etc.): {p g } g (example: discount for students) Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 4 / 41

Price discrimination: outline First degree discrimination Third degree discrimination Second degree discrimination Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 5 / 41

First degree price discrimination Perfect discrimination : Supposes perfect information about customers Different prices for different customers Different prices for different units sold to same customer (not very realistic, but useful benchmark) Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 6 / 41

First degree price discrimination Example: consider a monopoly Consumer willing to pay u i for i th unit Constant unit cost c Benchmark: no discrimination Uniform price p Trade-off markup / volume : (p c) p = 1 ε Monopoly: p > c inefficient as W < W Welfare is not maximal, but it is shared between firm and consumers. Cf next figure: due to uniform pricing, consumers with high valuation have a positive surplus. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 7 / 41

First degree price discrimination No discrimination: welfare is shared. P Consumers surplus Monopoly profit «Dead weight loss» (welfare loss) p c = c q c q Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 8 / 41

First degree price discrimination Assume perfect dicrimination is possible: Maximal price for each unit: p i = u i All units such that u i > c are traded Trade is efficient: W = W But consumer surplus is zero: the whole welfare is seized by the firm. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 9 / 41

First degree price discrimination Discrimination: welfare is maximal, but seized by the monopoly. P Monopoly profit = welfare p c = c q c q Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 10 / 41

First degree price discrimination Remark: implementation Quantity q Utility: U(q), U 0, U 0 Production cost C(q) Efficient trade: q : max q U(q) C(q) U (q ) = C (q )(= p ) Nonlinear tariff T (q) = U(q) Or two-part tariff: T (q) = S(p ) + p q ( sell the technology ) Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 11 / 41

Price discrimination: outline First degree discrimination Third degree discrimination Second degree discrimination Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 12 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Supposes limited information about customers Identify customer segment More realistic: necessitates accessible information, e.g. student card, ID card (age), etc. In practice, sellers have to prevent arbitrage from buyers who would buy on the cheapest segment to resell to the high-price segment. Prevent distributors from selling actively outside their territories, and limit exports: quotas, dual pricing for domestic/exports (medicines), etc. Example of country-based prices: cars, pharmaceutical products Easier to prevent arbitrage for services (resell a meal at a restaurant?) Guarantees become void if sale outside country of origin Assumes also that the firms cannot discriminate within a group. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 13 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Example Framework A monopolist faces a constant unit cost c n consumers groups, demand for each group D i (p), i {1,..., n} No discrimination (refresher): price p for aggregate demand D = Di i Optimal pricing: p c = 1 p ε(p) with ε(p) = D (p)p D(p) the elasticity of demand on total market. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 14 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Example (contd) Discrimination: the monopolist maximizes its profit p i D i (p i ) c i i D i (p i ) yields the price p i for group i: p i c p i = 1 ε i (p i ) where ε i (p i ) = D i (p i )p i D i (p i ) is the elasticity of demand on market i. Note that ε(p) = D i (p) D(p) ε i(p i ). i Optimal pricing implies that the monopolist should charge more in markets with the lower elasticity of demand. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 15 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Welfare analysis: property For a given total output, not discriminating is more efficient: n n max U i (q i ) C(Q) st. q i = Q i=1 i=1 U i (q i ) = p : FOC yield i {1,..., n 1}, U i (q i) = U 1 (q 1). By definition of the demand function, p = U 1 (q 1). Price differences thus yield inefficient outcomes: U i (qi) = pi Implication: discrimination can increase total surplus only if it increases volume of trade Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 16 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Illustration Two markets, sizes N 1 and N 2, reservation prices v 1 and v 2 > v 1 Discrimination: p i = v i No discrimination: the firm can Either serve all consumers at price p 1 = v 1 : yields a profit π 1 = (N 1 + N 2 )(v 1 c); Or serve only market 2 at price p 2 = v 2 : yields a profit π 2 = N 2 (v 2 c). p p v 2 π 1 v 2 π 2 v 1 v 1 c c q q Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 17 / 41

Third degree price discrimination if π 1 > π 2, first option prevails; then forbidding discrimination: Does not affect total surplus; But benefits consumers in the second market. If instead π 1 < π 2, forbidding discrimination: Leads firm to withdraw from first market; Total surplus decreases: no consumer benefits and the firm loses. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 18 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Impact on competition? Discrimination tends to intensify competition: No discrimination: average sensitivity of residual demand Discrimination: more direct competition for each group Illustration: spatial differentiation à la Hotelling Two firms 1 and 2, located at the two ends of a street of length L Same constant unit cost c. Unit transportation cost t Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 19 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Benchmark: No discrimination - price free on board p i A consumer located at distance x from firm i(j i) will buy from i if: p i + tx < p j + t(l x) Demands thus are: D 1 = L 2 (p 2 p 1 ) 2t and D 2 = L D 1 Maximizing profit π i = (p i c)d i yields the best-response p i = tl+c+p j 2, hence the equilibrium prices: p 1 = p 2 = c + tl Consumer x thus buys from the closer shop and pays Lt + c + tmin{x, L x} Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 20 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Discrimination: delivered price p i (x) Actually, the good is not necessarily delivered, but the transport cost is subsidized by the firm. Homogenous good (delivered to same address), consumer x compares the two prices: similar to Bertrand competition; But the cost of delivery is not the same: c + tx for firm 1 and c + t(l x) for firm 2. As in Bertrand with asymmetric costs, the closer firm wins at price just below its competitor s price: Consumer x thus buys from the closer shop and pays Lt + c tmin{x, L x} Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 21 / 41

Third degree price discrimination c + 3Lt 2 without discrimina-on c + Lt c c + Lt 2 with discrimina-on 0 L 2 L Figure : Prices paid by consumers. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 22 / 41

Third degree price discrimination Conclusion: total prices are lower when firms compete in personalized delivered prices Remark: Firms are better off absent discrimination But each firm benefits from offering personalized prices Asymmetric regulation A unilateral move to discrimination can intensify competition Illustration: meeting competition defence for dominant firm Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 23 / 41

Price discrimination: outline First degree discrimination Third degree discrimination Second degree discrimination Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 24 / 41

Second degree price discrimination Firm Does not identify consumer type Can still discriminate by offering a menu of options Different customers choose different packages: Price, quantity, quality, services Each customer has more information about its preferences than the firm Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 25 / 41

Second degree price discrimination Tariff-based discrimination (quantity dimension): e.g. menu of two-part tariffs yields a concave, non-linear tariff (progressive rebate) T 1 (q) = F 1 +p 1 q T 0 (q) = p 0 q T 2 (q) = F 2 +p 2 q T(q) Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 26 / 41

Example Second degree price discrimination Consumers, gross surplus: U = θu(q) with u > 0 and u < 0. θ is the intensity of preference With two part tariff T = pq + F, Consumer s variable surplus is S(p, θ) = θu(q) pq Consumer s utility is θu(q) T (Inverse) demand is defined by q = D(p, θ) p = θu (q). Benchmark: perfect discrimination (personalized tariffs) Consumer θ s variable surplus is maximum for p = c: defines q such that S (c, θ) = θu(q ) cq The optimal tariff for consumer θ is T (q, θ) = S (c, θ) + }{{} cq }{{} fixed part variable part The firm then seizes the whole surplus of consumer θ at its maximum: π = T (q, θ) cq = S (c, θ). What if tariff must be the same for all consumers? Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 27 / 41

Second degree price discrimination Uniform tariff: simplified model Assume two types of consumers: low with θ 1 and high θ 2 > θ 1, in proportions λ 1 and λ 2. With two part tariff T = pq + F, Utility normalized to zero for outside option not buying Optimal two-part tariff Maximize λ 1 [F + (p c)d(p, θ 1 )] + λ 2 [F + (p c)d(p, θ 2 )] Subject to participation constraint: F S(p, θ 1 )( S(p, θ 2 )). Yields F = S(p, θ 1 ) with p maximizing λ 1 [S(p, θ 1 ) + (p c)d(p, θ 1 )] + λ 2 [S(p, θ 1 ) + (p c)d(p, θ 2 )] = W (p, θ 1 ) + λ 2 (p c) [D(p, θ 2 ) D(p, θ 1 )] }{{} >0 Without the second term, the firm would choose efficient price p = c; The second term drives the price above marginal cost: p > c; However, since it recovers some surplus through fixed fee, p < p m (θ 2 ). Profit is however less than with perfect discrimination. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 28 / 41

Second degree price discrimination A non-linear tariff can do better: offer two options (t 1, q 1 ) and (t 2, q 2 ) so as to max λ 1(t 1 cq 1 ) + λ 2 (t 2 cq 2 ) (q 1,t 1 ),(q 2,t 2 ) s.t.θ 1 u(q 1 ) t 1 0 (PC 1 ) θ 2 u(q 2 ) t 2 0 (PC 2 ) θ 1 u(q 1 ) t 1 θ 1 u(q 2 ) t 2 (IC 1 ) θ 2 u(q 2 ) t 2 θ 2 u(q 1 ) t 1 (IC 2 ) (PC i ) are consumer i s participation constraint: higher utility if they accept their offer than no offer; (IC i ) are consumer i s incentive constraint: higher utility if they accept their offer than the offer designed for the other type of customers; Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 29 / 41

Second degree price discrimination IC constraints ensure self-selection of the customers: the main idea behind second-degree price discrimination. Remark: revealed preferences argument: incentive constraints can be rewritten as θ 2 [u(q 2 ) u(q 1 )] t 2 t 1 θ 1 [u(q 2 ) u(q 1 )] which implies that q 2 q 1 (as 0 < θ 1 < θ 2 ). Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 30 / 41

Second degree price discrimination The participation constraint of consumers of type 1 is thus The more restrictive of the two participation constraints (as θ 1 u(q 1 ) θ 2 u(q 2 )); Necessarily binding (otherwise, could uniformly increase both tariffs): implies t 1 = θ 1 u(q 1 ). Furthermore, the more restrictive incentive constraint is that of type 2 ( high ) consumers: Assume (IC 2 ) is binding: then t 2 t 1 = θ 2 [u(q 2 ) u(q 1 )] (IC 1 ) is satisfied too: t 2 t 1 θ 1 [u(q 2 ) u(q 1 )] Yet (IC 2 ) must be binding, otherwise can increase both tariffs; Implies t 2 = θ 2 u(q 2 ) (θ 2 θ 1 )u(q 1 ). Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 31 / 41

Second degree price discrimination A firm can thus Implement any profile q 2 q 1 At the maximal prices t 1 = θ 1 u(q 1 ) t 2 = θ 2 u(q 2 ) (θ 2 θ 1 )u(q 1 ). The programme of the firm thus amounts to max λ 1[θ 1 u(q 1 ) cq 1 ] + λ 2 [θ 2 u(q 2 ) (θ 2 θ 1 )u(q 1 ) cq 2 ] (q 1,q 2 ) = λ 1 [θ 1 u(q 1 ) λ 2 λ 1 (θ 2 θ 1 )u(q 1 ) cq 1 ] + λ 2 [θ 2 u(q 2 ) cq 2 ] Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 32 / 41

Second degree price discrimination The previous program yields the FOC: FOC q1 : [θ 1 λ 2 λ 1 (θ 2 θ 1 )]u (q 1 ) = c FOC q2 : θ 2 u (q 2 ) = c For large consumers: efficient quantity θ 2 u (q 2 ) = c For small consumers: quantity is lower than efficient level: [θ 1 λ 2 λ 1 (θ 2 θ 1 )]u (q 1 ) = c The solution is such that q 2 > q 1 Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 33 / 41

Second degree price discrimination Intuition: reducing quantity offered to small consumers Relaxes large users incentive constraint Allows the firm to extract more surplus from them Remark: The optimal menu differs from the one obtained with single two-part tariff Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 34 / 41

Second degree price discrimination More general model: continuum of consumers θ distributed over [θ 1, θ 2 ] according to density f (θ) and cumulative distribution function F (θ). Intuitively, consumer is excluded if θ is close to 0 let ˆθ denote the (endogenous) threshold characterizing the first consumer served. The programme of the firm becomes: + max q(.),t(.) ˆθ [t(θ) cq(θ)]f (θ)dθ s.t. θ, θu(q(θ)) t(θ) 0 (P θ ) θu(q(θ)) t(θ) θu(q(θ )) t(θ ) θ (I θ ) Note: as before, the incentive constraints imply that the quantity must increase with θ. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 35 / 41

Second degree price discrimination Defining the rent left to the consumer r θu t, we rewrite the programme as: max q(.),t(.) + ˆθ [θu(q(θ)) cq(θ) r(θ)]f (θ)dθ s.t. θ, r(θ) 0 (P θ ) r(θ) r(θ ) + (θ θ )u(q(θ )) θ (I θ ) The incentive constraint moreover implies r (θ) = d [θu(q(θ)) t(θ)] dθ = d dθ [max θ {θu(q(θ )) t(θ )}] = u(q(θ)) > 0 (using the envelope theorem) The rent r thus increases in θ: the binding participation constraint is that of ˆθ: r(ˆθ) = 0. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 36 / 41

Second degree price discrimination The rent can thus be rewritten as r(θ) = θ ˆθ r (x)dx = θ ˆθ u(q(x))dx Any increasing quantity profile q(θ) together with the rent profile r(θ) = θˆθ u(q(x))dx can be implemented using the non linear tariff t(θ) = θu(q(θ)) r(θ): Consider the incentive constraint I θ. The rent of a consumer of type θ who would choose a contract designed for a θ would be: V (θ, θ ) = θu(q(θ )) t(θ ) = (θ θ )u(q(θ )) + r(θ ) = (θ θ )u(q(θ )) + θ ˆθ u(q(x))dx Thus dv dθ = (θ θ )u (q(θ ))q (θ ) is positive if θ < θ and negative if θ > θ: consumer θ thus chooses the right contract (θ = θ). Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 37 / 41

Second degree price discrimination The expected rent over all consumers is thus equal to + ˆθ r(θ)f (θ)dθ = (integration by parts) = = + θ ˆθ [ ˆθ + + ˆθ + ˆθ [ θ u(q(x))dx]f (θ)dθ f (x)dx]u(q(θ))dθ [1 F (θ)]u(q(θ))dθ. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 38 / 41

Second degree price discrimination The objective of the firms can thus be rewritten as max q(.) + ˆθ max q(.) {[θu(q(θ)) cq(θ)]f (θ) [1 F (θ)]u(q(θ))}dθ + ˆθ [(θ 1 F (θ) f (θ) 1 F (θ) f (θ) s.t. θ, q (θ) 0 )u(q(θ)) cq(θ)]f (θ)dθ Assuming that h(θ) θ increases with θ, the solution is implicitely given by maximizing over q(.) inside the integral: h(θ)u (q) = c. As h(θ) < θ, the quantity is below the efficient level. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 39 / 41

Second degree price discrimination The total price paid by the consumer θ is t(θ) = θu(q(θ)) r(θ) Can be implemented via a non-linear tariff t = T (q), such that t(θ) = T (q(θ)) The marginal price T (q) satisfies T (q (θ)) = θu (q (θ)) = c + l(θ)u (q (θ)) where l(θ) 1 F (θ) f (θ) represents the likelihood ratio. Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 40 / 41

Second degree price discrimination When the likelihood ratio decreases with θ (as is the case for most usual distributions): The marginal price T (q) decreases with θ (since l(θ) decrease, and u < 0), The non-linear tariff T (q) is therefore concave Marie-Laure Allain (Ecole Polytechnique) IO 4: Discrimination January 14, 2015 41 / 41