I. The Monopolist, Market Size and Price Discrimination

Similar documents
First degree price discrimination ECON 171

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

Price Discrimination and Two Part Tariff

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 11 Pricing With Market Power

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE

ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes.

Economics 431 Fall st midterm Answer Key

Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits.

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power

Final Exam 15 December 2006

SOLUTIONS TO HOMEWORK SET #4

Price Discrimination

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Market Structures. Market Structures (cont.) The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly

SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

Profit Maximization. 2. product homogeneity

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Exam Prep Questions and Answers

Midterm Exam #1 - Answers

Economics 335, Spring 1999 Problem Set #7

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron.

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it?

Figure 1, A Monopolistically Competitive Firm

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

1) If the government sets a price ceiling below the monopoly price, will this reduce deadweight loss in a monopolized market?

Pricing with Perfect Competition. Business Economics Advanced Pricing Strategies. Pricing with Market Power. Markup Pricing

Chapter. Perfect Competition CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE

Chapter 14 Monopoly Monopoly and How It Arises

Name Eco200: Practice Test 2 Covering Chapters 10 through 15

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

KEELE UNIVERSITY MID-TERM TEST, 2007 BA BUSINESS ECONOMICS BA FINANCE AND ECONOMICS BA MANAGEMENT SCIENCE ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

Monopoly and Monopsony Labor Market Behavior

2. Price Discrimination

Chapter 15: Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE HOW MONOPOLIES MAKE PRODUCTION AND PRICING DECISIONS

PRICE DISCRIMINATION Industrial Organization B

Economics 100 Exam 2

Managerial Economics

nonrivalry => individual demand curves are summed vertically to get the aggregate demand curve for the public good.

-1- Worked Solutions 5. Lectures 9 and 10. Question Lecture 1. L9 2. L9 3. L9 4. L9 5. L9 6. L9 7. L9 8. L9 9. L9 10. L9 11. L9 12.

Pricing and Output Decisions: i Perfect. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e By Paul Keat and Philip Young

Consumers face constraints on their choices because they have limited incomes.

Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing)

Lecture 10 Monopoly Power and Pricing Strategies

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Practice Questions Week 8 Day 1

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 15. MONOPOLY

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Demand, Supply and Elasticity

Chapter 8 Production Technology and Costs 8.1 Economic Costs and Economic Profit

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

Practice Multiple Choice Questions Answers are bolded. Explanations to come soon!!

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK

A. a change in demand. B. a change in quantity demanded. C. a change in quantity supplied. D. unit elasticity. E. a change in average variable cost.

Price Discrimination

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Monopoly. E. Glen Weyl. Lecture 8 Price Theory and Market Design Fall University of Chicago


Solution to Exercise 7 on Multisource Pollution

Learning Objectives. After reading Chapter 11 and working the problems for Chapter 11 in the textbook and in this Workbook, you should be able to:

Second degree price discrimination

Answers to Chapter 6 Exercises

Pricing to Mass Markets. Simple Monopoly Pricing, Price Discrimination and the Losses from Monopoly

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

Final Exam Microeconomics Fall 2009 Key

Economics Chapter 7 Review

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination

Marginal cost. Average cost. Marginal revenue

4. Market Structures. Learning Objectives Market Structures

Figure: Computing Monopoly Profit

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

This file includes the answers to the problems at the end of Chapters 1, 2, 3, and 5 and 6.

chapter >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Section 3: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, and the Gains from Trade

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1

Monopolistic Competition

The Cost of Production

CHAPTER 11 PRICE AND OUTPUT IN MONOPOLY, MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, AND PERFECT COMPETITION

Pure Competition urely competitive markets are used as the benchmark to evaluate market

Pre-Test Chapter 25 ed17

Exercises for Industrial Organization Master de Economía Industrial Matilde Pinto Machado

Basic Monopoly Theory

At the end of Chapter 18, you should be able to answer the following:

BEE2017 Intermediate Microeconomics 2

Transcription:

Economics 335 February 16, 1999 Notes 5: Monopoly and Price Discrimination I. The Monopolist, Market Size and Price Discrimination A. Definition of a monopoly A firm is a monopoly if it is the only supplier of a product for which there is no close substitute. A monopoly sets the price of its product without concern that the price might be undercut by rivals. A monopoly faces a downward sloping demand curve. B. Example of price discrimination 1. setup Consider a elderly farmer named Grandpa Jones who owns all the 194 John Deere Spoker D tractors in existence. He wants to sell them all. They have marginal value to him of. As it turns out he has 7 tractors. Suppose that there are N individuals interested in buying these tractors. They are identical and each have a demand schedule as follows. Tractors Price First $16, Second $1, Third $8, Fourth $6, Fifth $4, Sixth $, Seventh $1, Aggregate demand is obtained by summing the demand over consumers. For example, if N = 4, and the price is $16,, the demand is 4. If N = 4 and the price is $1,, the demand is 8. Specifically, at a price of $16,, the demand is between and N, at a price of $1,, the price is between N+1 and N. At $1,, it is between N+1 and 3N and so on.. uniform pricing Grandpa Jones practices uniform pricing, that is, he announces a price and all who want can buy at that price. 3. case when N $ 7 If N $ 7, then the demand curve is perfectly elastic at a price of $16,. Grandpa Jones isn t really a monopolist because he is small relative to the market.

4. N = The demand now looks like this: Price (Demand) Total Revenue Marginal Revenue > $16, $16, 1 16, 16, $16, 3, 16, $1, 3 36, 4, $1, 4 48, 1, $8, 5 4, -$8, $8, 6 48, $8, $6, 7 4, -$6, $6, 8 48, $6, $4, 9 36, -$1, $4, 1 4, $4, $, 11, -$18, $, 1 4, $, $1, 13 13, -$11, $1, 14 14, $1, To sell all 7 tractors, Grandpa Jones must set a price of $6,. Doing so he will obtain total revenue of $4,. This is not Grandpa Jones s best strategy, however. If he sets a price of $1,, he will sell 4 tractors and have revenue of $48,. This is clearly larger than the $4, obtained from selling 7 tractors at $6, a piece. 5. marginal revenue for the monopolist Consider the change in revenue that occurs from lowering the price from $1, to $8,. Total revenue at $1, is $48,. Total revenue at $8, is also $48,. The change is revenue is.. The change in the number of tractors sold is (from 4 to 6) and so marginal revenue is $.. Notice that marginal revenue is less or equal to price at all points in the table. Marginal revenue is often significantly less than price. 6. efficiency loss Even though Grandpa has puts no value on the tractors, an individual who would pay $6, for them is closed out of the market.

3 7. non-uniform pricing to the consumers If Grandpa could charge different prices to different buyers, he might choose to sell two tractors to one person at $1, each, and sell the other 5 tractors to the other at person for $6,, for total revenue of $3,. This would give total revenue of $54,. This is larger than the revenue obtained when a uniform price of $6, was charged. And notice that all 7 tractors are sold. But to do so Grandpa must be able to decide who gets the 5 tractors and who gets tractors. 8. auction pricing Consider an auction where the tractors are auctioned off one at a time. Suppose the two individuals buying are Matt and Derrick. Suppose Derrick wins the first auction and buys the tractor for $16,. The second tractor will be obtained by Matt for $1,1 because Derrick will drop out at this point. The third tractor will also be obtained by Matt for $1,1. This is because the most Derrick will pay for two tractors is $8, and having already spent $16,, he is not willing to spend more than 1, for a second one. Matt, on the other hand would also pay up to $8, for two, and having only spend $1,1, he can pay up to $15,999 and still break even. Now consider the fourth tractor. Matt would pay up to $36, for 3 tractors. He has spent $4, and so would be willing to spend $11,998 for the third tractor. Derrick has only one tractor and would pay up to $8, for two. So he would spend up to $1, for his second tractor. Derrick this win the bidding for tractor number 4 with a bid of $11,999. Now consider tractor number 5. Each individual has tractors at this point. Each would pay up to $36, for 3 tractors. Matt has spend $4, and so he would be willing to spend $11,998 on a third tractor. Derrick has spend $7,999. So he would bid up to $8,1 for a third tractor. Matt will win the bidding and will pay $8, for his third tractor (the fifth tractor overall). Now consider tractor number 6. Matt has 3 tractors and will pay up to $4, for 4 tractors. Derrick has only tractors and will pay up to$36, for 3 tractors. Matt has spent $3,4 to this point (1,1 + 1,1 + 8,), So he would pay up to $9,996 for his fourth tractor. Derrick has spent 7,999 (16,+ 11,999) and so would pay $8,1 for a third tractor. Matt will win this bidding and pay $8, for total expenditure at this point of $4,6. Derrick has still only spend $7,999. Now consider tractor number 7. Matt has 4 tractors and will pay up to $46, for 5 tractors. Derrick has only tractors and will pay up to$36, for 3 tractors. Matt has spent $4,6 to this point (1,1 + 1,1 + 8, + 8,), So he would pay up to $5,994 for his fourth tractor. Derrick has spent 7,999 (16,+ 11,999) and so would pay $8,1 for a third tractor. Derrick will win this bidding and pay $5,995 for total expenditure at this point of $33,994. All seven tractors have been sold for a total cost (revenue) of $74, (4,6 + 33,4). This is much higher than in any previous case. The table below summarizes the data. Cumulative Derrick s Matt s Tractor # Purchased by Price Paid Revenue Derrick s Value Matt s Value Total Expense Total Expense 1 Derrick 16, 16, 16 16 16 Matt 1,1 8,1 1 16 16 11 3 Matt 1,1 4, 1 15999 16 4 4 Derrick 11,999 5,1 1 11998 7,999 4 5 Matt 8 6,3 81 11998 7,999 34 6 Matt 8 68,5 81 9996 7,999 46 7 Derrick 5995 74, 81 5994 33,994 46

4 C. Some simple observations from the example 1. Price discrimination is the selling of two varieties of a product to two different buyers at different net prices, where the net price is the price paid by the buyer adjusted for any cost of product differentiation. In our example, there was no product differentiation and so the two varieties of the tractor were the same.. In order to practice price discrimination, the seller must be able to identify the different buyers. In the case of an auction, the identification is easy because of the pricing mechanism. But an auction is expensive in terms of transactions costs. One way to discriminate without an auction would be to offer an early morning special ½ price sale and sell 5 tractors at $6, and then sell the other two at $1, a piece later in the day. 3. Another problem with price discrimination is that the seller must prevent arbitrage. For example, the early bird buyer may come back and resell the tractors for $1,, make a profit and put an end to more sales by Grandpa Jones. 4. With uniform pricing, the monopolist cannot extract all of the surplus that he generates. As a result he may limit the amount supplied. In this example, with uniform pricing, Grandpa Jones chose to hold back 1 tractor because his marginal revenue from its sale was negative, even though its sale created positive surplus for society. 5. A monopolist who can price discriminate can extract more surplus and will typically supply more. In the example, Derrick got 3 tractors and paid $33,994. So Grandpa got $,6 of Derrick s surplus (36, - 33, 994). Matt got 4 tractors and paid $4,6. So Grandpa got $1,994 of Matt s consumer surplus. In this case Grandpa got $74, out of possible consumer surplus of $78,. In the non-uniform pricing case, Grandpa Jones got total surplus of $4,. II. Strategies and Degrees of Price Discrimination A. Ways to identify consumers and their separate demand 1. long term relationships such as insurance agents, car dealers, appliance repairmen, jewelers, furriers, tailors, doctors, etc.. age 3. sex 4. family status 5. type of job 6. method of payment 7. other commonly bought items 8. place of residence

5 B. Prevention of arbitrage in price discrimination 1. Sale of products that are customer specific a. haircuts b. dental filling c. house plans. Sales of products where use is predicated on a characteristic a. senior citizen discount cards b. student bus passes c. air travel with a weekend stay 3. Sales where it is hard to resell because of distance or transactions costs a. purchase of cattle in a local market b. sale of specialty product with limited number of buyers C. First-degree price discrimination 1. Definition A firm practices first-degree or perfect price discrimination is it is able to charge the maximum price each consumer is willing to pay for each unit sold. Specifically, perfect price discrimination involves the seller charging a different price for each unit of the good in such a way that the price charged for each unit is equal to the maximum willingness to pay for that unit. For the tractor example, this means selling the first two tractors at $16,, the next two at $1,, the 4 th an 5 th ones at $8, and the 7 th one at $6,. In this case the firm would obtain revenue of $78,. All consumer surplus goes to the seller.. Efficiency implications Under first degree price discrimination, the monopolist will produce the socially optimal level of output but will appropriate all the economic surplus. The monopolist will not have to lower the price on a unit to sell the next unit and so marginal revenue will always equal price. 3. Two-part or non-linear pricing as a means to price discriminate a. form: A two-part pricing scheme is a policy that consists of i) a fee that entitles the consumer to buy the good ii) a price (or usage fee) charged for each unit purchased b. examples i) membership in a club ii) amusement park iii) wholesale warehouse

6 c. analysis of a racquet club Demand P = V - Q P = price is the price per game (court) Q = number of games played per week V = maximum amount the consumer would pay for 1 game per week Cost of service C(Q) = F + cq F = fixed cost c = cost per game Uniform pricing Revenue = PQ = (V-Q)Q = VQ - Q Marginal revenue = V - Q Marginal cost = c Solving we obtain P ' V & Q MR ' V & Q ' c ' MC Y Q ' V & c Y Q ' V & c Y P u ' V % c The monopolist will earn some surplus from each consumer. The surplus is given by the difference between the price received and the cost for each unit of service. Specifically u ' (P u & c)q V % c ' & c ' ' V & c V & c V & c V & c In the diagram below, the surplus is given by the area dbeg.

7 First-Degree Price Discrimination Price V a (V+c)/ d Demand b c g e MR f MC (V-c)/ V/ V - c V Quantity If there are n customers per week, then profit per week will be u ' n u & F ' n (V & c) 4 & F The issue is whether the club owner can obtain more surplus. Each consumer is obtaining surplus equal to the area abd in the figure. This area is (V % c) CS u ' V & (V & c) ' 8 V & c 1 The club owner is thus losing out on this area. If the owner got this area, this total surplus would TS u ' 3(V & c) 8 be. Suppose the owner charges an weekly fee just less than and continues to charge a (V & c) 8

8 price per game of (V % c). The consumer will continue to choose to enter since total surplus is positive (just larger than ) and play the same number of games as before because the entry (V & c) fee is independent of the number of games played. Surplus has gone up by. The owner can do better by lowering the price per game and raising the fee per week. The best two-part price is obtained as follows. i) set the cost per game equal to marginal cost (c) ii) set the weekly fee equal to the consumer surplus at this price (afg). This is equal to 8 CS ' V & c V & c ' (V & c) 1 Profit per game is now zero, like with perfect competition. But the entire weekly fee is profit (because the per-game fees covers the variable costs). Total profit is now equal to f ' n (V & c) & F This is much larger than before. Total expenditure by each consumer is the entry fee plus the cost per game times the number of games. This is equal to (V & c) Expenditure ' % c(v & c) ' V & cv % c % cv & c ' V & cv % c ' V & c (V & c) (V % c) ' ' (V & c) V % c % cv & c

9 Because the quantity of games purchased is (V - C) then the average price per game has to be (V % c) game has remained the same, but the monopolist has increased profits significantly.. This is the same as the profit maximizing uniform price. The average price per 1. Two-part tariffs with non-identical consumers a. procedure i) Set price per unit equal to marginal cost per unit ii) Set the fixed tariff for each consumer type equal to the consumer surplus for that type at the unit price. b. example Two types of consumers - college students and professors where P CS = 1 - Q CS P PR = - Q PR Assume that the marginal cost per game is $.. At a price equal to marginal cost the college students will demand 5 games per week. P CS ' 1 & Q CS Y ' 1 & Q CS Y Q CS ' 1 Y q CS ' 5 Similarly the professors will demand 9 games per week. Consumer surplus for the college students will be $5.. Consumer surplus for the professors will be $81..

1 First-Degree Price Discrimination College Students Price 1 a 5 Demand c b MC 5 6 Quantity Price a First-Degree Price Discrimination Professors 81 Demand c b MC 9 1 Quantity The owner of the racquet club should charge a weekly fee for professors of $81. and then charge $. per game. He should charge the college students a weekly fee of $5. and also charge them $. per game.

11 c. applications i) amusement park ii) telephone company that has a flat fee plus a price per call or minute iii) car rental or machinery rental iv) copy machines v) fertilizer application equipment vi) buying club or group vii) feed cooperative D. Second degree price discrimination 1. Definition Second-degree price discrimination or nonlinear pricing, occurs when prices differ depending on the number of units bought, but not across consumers. That is, each consumer faces the same price schedule, but the schedule involves different prices for different amounts of the good purchased. Second degree price discrimination is sometimes called block pricing.. Problems with implementing first degree price discrimination using a two-part tariff a. customers may not be identical or may not be easily identifiable b. there may be no way to effectively limit access to those not paying the fixed fee c. if customers are not easily identifiable, they will have an incentive to cheat 3. Possible solutions for the racquet club policy if there is no identification of customers a. Charge $81 per week and $ per game to everyone. If there are N PF professors in town, this will given profits of = 81 N PF. No college students will buy a membership. b. Charge $5 per week and $ per game to everyone. If there are N PF professors and N CS in town, this will given profits of = 5 N PF + 5 N CS. Everyone will now buy a membership. c. The lower weekly fee will have a larger profit if 5 N CS > 56 N PF. For example if there are 1 professors and 3 students the weekly fees under the two schemes will be Student Purchases/Profit Professor Purchases/Profit Total Profit Fee = $81 / 1 / 81 81 Fee = $5 3 / 7,5 1 /,5 1, If the ratio of college students to professors is more than 56/5 =.4, the lower price scheme will be preferable.

1 4. An alternative solution that may work b. a. If you pay $81, you may play up to 9 games per week at a cost of $. per game. If you pay $5., you may play up to 5 games per week at a cost of $. per game. c. What happens with the college students? They pay the $5 fee and then play 5 games per week as we previously determined. They have zero consumer surplus. d. What happens with the professors? If they pay the $81 fee, they will play 9 games per week and have zero consumer surplus. If they pay the $5 fee and play 5 games per week at $. as allowed, they will have some consumer surplus. We can determine this by looking at the following figure. Professors CS with $5. Package and 5 Game Limit Price a 5 1 f d 4 Demand c 1 e b MC 5 9 1 Quantity If there is no fee the consumer s surplus for the professors can be determined by integrating the inverse demand function from Q = to Q = 5. This will give CS(5 games, professor) ' m 5 ( & x) dx ' x & x 5 * ' 1 & 5 & ' 75

13 We can also compute this by using the area of the triangles and the fact that inverse demand will intersect the quantity line for Q = 5 at a price of $1. (P = - () (5)). The cost of the games is $1. because each game costs $.. The cost of the package is $5.. So the professors end up with $4. (75-1-5) of consumer surplus. They will choose the low cost package even though they end up with only 5 games per week. So the professors will not choose the high price package and the firm will end up with only low profits if there are lots of professors. 5. An alternative solution that does work a. College students Figure out what is the maximum they will pay for 5 games. This can be done by integrating their inverse demand from to 5. Doing so we obtain CS(5 games, student) ' m 5 (1 & x) dx ' 1x & x 5 * ' 6 & 5 & ' 35 An strategy might be to then offer a 5 game per week package for a total price of $35.. The students will pick this package and have consumer surplus. b. Professors and the student package Figure out how much consumer surplus the professors get if they buy the 5 game per week package. We integrate their demand curve from to 5 and subtract the fee. We know the area under the curve is $75. from before. So if they buy this package, they get surplus of $4. (75-35).

14 Second-degree Price Discrimination College Students Price 1 a 5 Demand c 1 5 b 6 MC Quantity b. Owner of racquet club With this pricing scheme and everyone buying the $35. package, the owner of the club will have profit of $5. per package because his cost per package is only $1. [(5)()]. c. A better package for the professors What the owner would like to do is offer a package to the professors that will entice them to play more than 5 games per week. The professors would pay $1 per week to play 1 games. But if the owner offered this package along with the $35. package the professors would take the $35. package and have $4. in consumer surplus. What the owner needs to do is create a package that will give the professors at least $4 in consumer surplus, plus give him more profits. A package that will entice the professors to take it instead of the $35. package is called an incentive compatible package meaning that it is provides that same incentives as the $35. package. So what the owner does is offer the 1 game package for $6.. This gives consumer surplus of $4. (1-6) and induces the professors to play 1 games. The owner makes $4 per professor ([6 - (1)()]. The college students will not take this package because the most they will pay to play per week CS(6 games, student)' m 6 (1&x)dx' 1x&x 6 * ' 7&36 ' 36 is $36.. The racquet club owner will now have profit of $5 for each college student and $4 for each professor. A better solution, indeed.

15 d. average price per game Average price per game for the students is $7. (35/5). Average price per game for the professors is $6. (6/1). Those who play more get a quantity discount. 6. Examples of second degree price discrimination a. fertilizer b. feed c. chemicals d. pizza e. sub sandwiches 7. Determining the optimum packages a. Consider a college student package for $36. and 6 games per week. This will give revenue of $36. with a cost of $1 with profit to the owner of $4.. This is less than before. b. Consumer surplus for professors with $36. package CS(6 games, professor) ' m 6 ( & x) dx ' x & x 6 * ' 1 & 36 & ' 84 Now subtract the cost of the package (36) to obtain net surplus of $48 (84-36). The owner must offer a professor package with at least $48. of consumer surplus to match the student package in terms of attractiveness. This means he offers the 1 game package for $5. (1-48). The owner has net profit of $3 (5- ). This is also less than before. The owner was better off with the $35., 5 game package. c. Consider a college student package for $3. and 4 games per week. This will give revenue of $3. with a cost of $8 for profit to the owner of $4.. This is the same as for the 6 unit package. d. Consumer surplus for professors with $3. package

16 CS(4 games, professor) ' m 4 ( & x) dx ' x & x 4 * ' 8 & 16 & ' 64 8. A general rule Now subtract the cost of the package (3) to obtain net surplus of $3 (64-3). The owner must offer a professor package with at least $3. of consumer surplus to match the student package in terms of attractiveness. This means he offers the 1 game package for $68. (1-3). This is more than the previous cases. He has profit of $48. per professor. This is the highest so far. We could also consider other cases such as a 3,, 1 or unit package. Once we compute the profit per consumer type for the various packages, we can compute the overall profits using the numbers of consumers of each type. Consider a two-package pricing scheme. Assume that there are N L low demand consumers and N H high demand consumers. The owner makes L from each low demand consumer who takes the package. Assume that if the owner prices them out of the market and chooses a single package for the high demand consumers they will have consumer surplus of. Assume the owner has profit per consumer of HE where E denotes the exclusive package. If instead the owner provides two packages, the package for the high demand consumers must provide consumer surplus at least equal to CS HL where HL stands for high demand consumers taking the low demand package. The profits per high demand consumer will thus be CS HL lower than in the exclusive package case. Profits in the two cases are then Low Demand Purchases / Profit High Demand Purchases / Profit Total Profit Exclusive Package / N H / N H H N H H Two Packages N L / N L L N H / N H ( H - CS HL ) N L L + N H ( H - CS HL ) Profit Difference N L L + N H ( H - CS HL ) - N H H = N L L - N H CS HL Now rewrite the profit difference equation as Profit difference ' N L L & N H CS HL In order for the owner to offer two packages, this difference must be positive. Writing it out and rearranging we obtain

17 Profit difference ' N L L & N H CS HL > Y N L L > N H CS HL Y N L N H > CS HL L Y N H N L > L CS HL 9. General conclusions for second-degree price discrimination a. offer a series of price quantity discount packages b. extract all the consumer surplus from the lowest demand class c. leave some consumer surplus for the other classes d. provide a quantity less than the social optimum for all but the highest demand class e. use quantity discounting 1. Comment Second-degree price discrimination involves a sorting mechanism. The firm cannot identify the consumers and so designs a scheme so that the consumers sort themselves D. Third degree price discrimination 1. Definition Third-degree price discrimination means that different purchasers are charged different prices, but each purchaser pays a constant amount for each unit of the good bought. In the case of third-degree price discrimination, there is some easily observable criterion by which the firm can group consumers in terms of willingness to pay. It is also assumed that arbitrage is prevented.. Examples a. airline tickets b. under 1 discounts c. senior citizen discounts d. college student magazine subscriptions e. early bird specials at stores or restaurants or seed stores f. coupons g. end of season sales h. movies i. first and economy class seats j. classy and junky stores k. good and lousy service where the cost difference in providing good service is less than the price difference in the service

18 3. Basic rule for third degree price discrimination If there are two groups, the group with the lower demand elasticity pays the higher price. Intuition: If the quantity purchased is not very sensitive to price, charge a high price. 4. Third degree price discrimination with constant marginal costs a. marginal cost of production is constant and equal to c b. consumers are of two types and can be segregated The inverse demand functions are Type 1: P ' A 1 & BQ 1 Type : P ' A & BQ A 1 > A The demand equations for each market are given by Type 1: Q 1 ' A 1 B & 1 B P Type : Q ' A B & 1 B P A 1 > A The demand elasticity for market 1 is given by Q 1 ' A 1 B & 1 B P D 1 ' dq dp P Q ' &1 B A 1 & BQ 1 Q 1 ' BQ 1 & A 1 BQ 1 ' 1 & A 1 BQ 1

19 Similarly for market D ' dq dp P Q ' 1 & A BQ With A 1 > A, market 1 is less elastic at any given Q because we are subtracting a larger number from 1. c. optimality conditions MR 1 = MR MR i = c Marginal revenue in each market is given by R i ' PQ i ' (A i & BQ i )Q i MR i ' A i & BQ i This then implies that MR 1 ' A 1 & BQ 1 ' A & BQ ' c Y BQ 1 ' A 1 & c Y Q 1 ' A 1 & c B Y Q ' A & c B We can substitute these into the inverse demand function to obtain the prices charged in each market.

P 1 ' A 1 & BQ 1 ' A 1 & B A 1 & c B ' A 1 & A 1 % c ' A 1 % c P ' A % c With A 1 > A, P 1 > P. d. graphical analysis P Third Degree Price Discrimination A 1 D 1 (A 1 +c)/b A (A +c)/b MC D A /B A 1 /B A 1 /B A 1 /B Q (A -c)/b (A1 -c)/b

1 5. Third degree price discrimination with increasing and non-identical marginal costs between plants a. marginal cost of production is increasing and is different between two different plants owned by the firm cost(y 1 ) ' 1 % 1y 1 % y 1 MC(y 1 ) ' 1 % y 1 cost(y ) ' 5 % 1y %.5y MC(y ) ' 1 % y b. consumers are of two types and can be segregated The inverse demand functions are P 1 ' & q 1 P ' 16 & q Marginal revenue in each market is given by R 1 ' P 1 q 1 ' ( & q 1 )q 1 MR 1 ' & q 1 R ' P q ' (16 & q )q MR ' 16 & 4q For later reference the demand functions are q 1 ' & P 1 q ' 8 & 1 P c. aggregate marginal revenue We get aggregate marginal revenue by adding the marginal revenue curves horizontally. This means we need to invert them to get q on the left hand side. When MR (and P) is greater than 16, only the first set of consumers will be in the market, so we will have a kinked marginal revenue curve. First for MR > 16.

MR 1 ' & q 1 Y q 1 ' & MR 1 & MR Y q 1 ' Y Q ' q 1 % q ' & MR % ' 11 & 1 MR For MR # 16, we must aggregate the two curves as follows 16 MR MR = 16 4q q = = 4 1 MR 4 4 1 Q= q1+ q = 11 = MR+ 4 1 MR = 15 3 MR 4 4 For MR # 16, we can reinvert to obtain for aggregate marginal revenue Q ' 15 & 3 4 MR Y 3 4 MR ' 15 & Q Y MR ' & 4 3 Q This will apply as long as Q $ 3. If Q < 3, MR > 16. d. aggregate marginal cost We set marginal cost in each plant equal. Then we aggregate the marginal cost curves horizontally as follows

3 MC(y 1 ) ' 1 % y 1 Y y 1 ' MC & 1 Y y 1 ' 1 MC & 5 MC(y ) ' 1 % y Y y ' MC & 1 Y Q ' y 1 % y ' 3 MC & 15 We need not worry about any kinks because the marginal cost curves have the same intercept. We can then reinvert to get aggregate marginal cost Q ' y 1 % y ' 3 MC & 15 Y 3 MC ' Q % 15 Y MC ' 3 Q % 1 e. optimality We set aggregate marginal revenue equal to aggregate marginal cost and solve as follows MC ' 3 Q % 1 ' MR ' & 4 3 Q Y 6 3 Q ' 1 Y Q ' 1 Y Q ' 5

4 Aggregate marginal revenue is MR ' & 4 3 Q ' & 4 3 (5) ' & 3 ' & 6 3 ' 13 1 3 Aggregate marginal cost is MC ' 3 Q % 1 ' 3 (5) % 1 ' 3 1 3 % 1 ' 13 1 3 We can find the quantity sold in the first market by using the equation for marginal revenue MR 1 ' & q 1 Y 13 1 3 ' & q 1 Y q 1 ' & 4 3 Y q 1 ' 6 3 Y q 1 ' 13 3 ' 4 1 3

5 Using the equation for marginal cost we obtain the quantity produced in the first plant MC(y 1 ) ' 1 % y 1 Y 13 1 3 ' 1 % y 1 Y y 1 ' 3 1 3 Y y 1 ' 1 3 We can do the same for the second market by using the equation for marginal revenue MR ' 16 & 4q Y 13 1 3 ' 16 & 4q Y 4q ' 16 & 4 3 Y 4q ' 8 3 Y q ' 3 Using the equation for marginal cost we obtain the quantity produced in the second plant MC(y ) ' 1 % y 1 Y 13 1 3 ' 1 % y 1 Y y 1 ' 3 1 3

6 Note that q 1 + q = 5 and y 1 + y = 5. The price in each market is given by P 1 ' & q 1 ' & 4 1 3 ' 17 3 P ' 16 & q ' 16 & ()( 3 ) ' 16 & 4 3 ' 14 3 The following table summarizes the results Market 1 Market Plant 1 Plant Total Demand 4.33.66 5 Production 1.66 3.33 5 Price 17.33 14.66 Revenue 75.11 9.7 7 84.8 8 Marginal Revenue 13.3 3 13.3 3 Cost 9.4 4 43.8 8 73.3 3 Marginal Cost 13.33 13.33 Profit 11.55

7 Demand elasticities are computed as D 1 D ' dq dp P Q ' (&1) 17.33 4.33 '&4 ' dq dp P Q ' (& 1 ) 14.66.66 '&11 So market 1, with the lower elasticity, has the higher price.