POWER OF CHOICE (EPR 0022)

Similar documents
Changes in regulated electricity prices from 1 July 2012

Australian Energy Market Commission

Clean Energy Council submission to Queensland Competition Authority Regulated Retail Electricity Prices for Interim Consultation Paper

2014 Residential Electricity Price Trends

Updated SCER Demand Side Participation Program December 2013

Rule change request. 18 September 2013

15 April 2011 Re: Expansion of the Victorian Energy Efficiency Target

Design Guide. Managing Peak Energy Demand In Live Performance Venues

2013 Residential Electricity Price Trends

Changes in regulated electricity prices from 1 July 2012

Total 5,926 24,514 66,355 97,042 68, ,

APRIL 2014 ELECTRICITY PRICES AND NETWORK COSTS

Response to the Energy White Paper Issues Paper PREPARED BY EMC ENGINEERING FOR THE AUSTRALIAN GOVERNMENT DEPARTMENT OF INDUSTRY

Possible future retail electricity price movements: 1 July 2012 to 30 June 2015

Australian Solar Council Submission on Queensland Competition Authority Issues Paper Estimating a Fair and Reasonable Solar Feed-in Tariff for

Smart meters: Removing regulatory barriers and maintaining consumer safety for a market-led roll out of smart meters in New South Wales

Realising the benefits of smart meters for consumers and industry

Energy Markets and Programs Division GPO Box 1264 Adelaide SA 5001

Retailer Margins in Victoria s Electricity Market. Discussion Paper

Promoting the long term interests of electricity customers. IPART s submission SCER on network policies and regulation

Managing Rising Energy Costs for Seniors in the ACT

Re: The Performance and Management of Electricity Network Companies

2015 Retail Competition Review Approach Paper

Western Australian Feed-In Tariff Discussion Paper

Power of choice review - giving consumers options in the way they use electricity

The primary reason for JEN making this request is that the F&A paper that was published on 29 May 2009 (old F&A paper) is outdated.

Committee on the Northern Territory s Energy Future. Electricity Pricing Options. Submission from Power and Water Corporation

Energy markets current challenges for Victoria. Mark Feather Executive Director, Energy Sector Development

The Mathematics 11 Competency Test Percent Increase or Decrease

ELECTRIC SCHEDULE E-1 Sheet 1 RESIDENTIAL SERVICES

Everything you should know about smart meters

Challenges And Opportunities For The NEM s Retail Electricity Market

Hardship Policy-Victoria

Using the sun to generate electricity

Retail Licence Exemptions for Solar Power Purchase Agreement Providers. Department of Finance Public Utilities July 2015

Skills Knowledge Energy Time People and decide how to use themto accomplish your objectives.

CANEGROWERS submission to the 30-year electricity strategy

Energy Efficiency Improvement Scheme

Regulatory Implications of New Products and Services in the Australian Electricity Market

Consumer guide. be brighter. actewagl.com.au/solar

AER Issues Paper Tariff Structure Statement Proposals Victorian Electricity Distribution Network Service Providers

Energy efficiency improvement and environmental protection have ranked first priorities in utility policies, in developed and developing countries.

2014 Retail Competition Review

Comments of the Edison Electric Institute Net Benefits and Costs of Distributed Solar Energy and Innovative Solar Deployment Models, DOE-EERE

Review of the Energy Savings Scheme. Position Paper

Energy Efficiency Improvement Scheme: Setting Key Scheme Parameters to Regulatory Impact Assessment

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Causes of residential electricity bill changes in Victoria, 1995 to prepared for: Victorian Electricity Distribution Businesses

Solar PV For Surrey Schools - Information Pack

Dairy Companies Association of New Zealand (DCANZ) Submission to Emissions Trading Scheme Review Select Committee

Submission to the 2015 Retail Competition Review Approach Paper (RPR0003)

Submission to the Senate Select Committee on Electricity Prices

UNDERSTANDING ENERGY BILLS & TARRIFS

Winter heating This winter heating guide includes ways to reduce heating costs and provides advice on choosing the right heater to suit your needs.

Energy Market Productivity and DM - Energy Efficiency Schemes

Energy Savings Agency: The Greens plan to fix Australia s energy system

The Virtual Power Station - achieving dispatchable generation from small scale solar

Policy options for maximising downward pressure on electricity prices

Training Programme: Introduction to the Regulation of Electricity Markets June 14-16, 16, 2010 Istanbul, Turkey. Electricity demand

AEMC Electricity Price Trends report released

Department of Water and Power City of Los Angeles PROPOSED RATE RESTRUCTURING

ERM Business Energy welcomes the opportunity to respond to the Department of State Development s (DSD) REES Consultation Paper (the Paper).

Solar Power Frequently Asked Questions

APPLICATION FOR INDIVIDUAL RETAIL EXEMPTION. 8 July SOLAR PANELS Pty Ltd ACN

CEFC finance supports Australian solar PV manufacturer

2016 Santee Cooper Solar Home & Solar Share Home Program Manual

Saving energy, growing jobs

Report on the Status of Net Energy Metering In the State of Maryland. Prepared by The Public Service Commission of Maryland

MAKING SOLAR ENERGY COST-EFFECTIVE TODAY IS A SNAP

JEA Net Metering Policy Tiers 1-3

A target cost is arrived at by identifying the market price of a product and then subtracting a desired profit margin from it.

I write in response to your request for feedback on SAPN s electricity tariff reforms. Executive Summary

Causes of residential electricity bill changes in Victoria, 1995 to prepared for: Victorian Electricity Distribution Businesses

Energy Price Fact Sheet. Red Energy FIT. Standing Offer - Business - Energy Made Easy Reference RED79307SS

COPY. Simon Corbel' MLA

Figure 1. D S (private) S' (social) Quantity (tons of medicine)

Distributed Energy Resource Options and The Importance of The Electric Power Grid

SUBMISSION TO THE QUEENSLAND PRODUCTIVITY COMMISSION ISSUES PAPER ON SOLAR FEED IN PRICING IN QUEENSLAND

National Electricity Amendment (Network Support Payments and Avoided TUoS for Embedded Generators) Rule 2011

Europe Economics Report to DCMS. Independent Review: Government Cost Benefit Analysis of Digital Radio Switchover. Summary

Understanding Network Tariff Reform

Energy Training Week 2013 Course 3: Energy Efficiency Policy and Measures Introduction to Energy Efficiency Policies Grayson Heffner and Robert

DESIGNING AUSTIN ENERGY S SOLAR TARIFF USING A DISTRIBUTED PV VALUE CALCULATOR

ENERGY ADVISORY COMMITTEE. Electricity Market Review : Electricity Tariff

Submission fmm the Electricity Supply Association of Australia (ESAA) Limited

Energy Price Fact Sheet. Red Energy. Flexible Living Energy Saver - Offer Reference RED25341MR

RE: Submission to the 30 Year Electricity Strategy Discussion Paper

NSW Business Chamber Submission to the Special Commission of Inquiry into Electricity Transactions

The Taskforce's Proposed Process to Reduce Energy Costs in Australia

Retail Tariffs. Business, Irrigation and Farming Tariffs

Report on impact of the Renewable Energy Target on power prices

COTTON AUSTRALIA LIMITED

Natural gas heating versus split system heating and the current and future viability of the Natural gas network

Final decision. Priorities and objectives of electricity transmission network service provider performance reports

ELECTRIC SCHEDULE ET Sheet 1 MOBILEHOME PARK SERVICE

Box 1: Four party credit card schemes

ELECTRIC SCHEDULE E-9 EXPERIMENTAL RESIDENTIAL TIME-OF-USE SERVICE FOR LOW EMISSION VEHICLE CUSTOMERS

Bundled Bills. Energy Charges

Transcription:

Australian Energy Market Commission PO Box A2449 Sydney NSW 1235 [by email] 26 August 2011 Dear Commissioners POWER OF CHOICE (EPR 0022) Thank you for the opportunity to comment on the AEMC s Issues Paper Power of Choice. My comments centre on the economic framework that the AEMC has set out in this paper and, based on this economic framework, the assessment process the AEMC intends to use. As the AEMC is aware, establishing a robust economic framework up front is central to ensuring that customers are the primary beneficiaries of proposed regulatory changes. AEMC s proposed economic framework overly supply-side side orientated The AEMC s economic framework (section 3.2) appears overly supply-side orientated in that it focuses primarily on the opportunity cost of the capital invested in the industry (particularly networks) rather than considering the relative costs and benefits to the customer of demand side participation. There are fundamental problems with adopting a supply-side focused economic framework. First, it ignores the value that consumers derive from energy use of a given quantity at a point in time. Second, it risks overlooking the costs consumers can incur in accessing DSP services (eg solar panels). Third, it implies that if the capital invested in networks were reduced, that society as a whole would be better off whereas the value that customers place on consuming energy at any point in time might suggest otherwise. The economic framework should focus on the consumer The economic framework should focus on the consumer and seek to make consumer sovereignty the central tenant of the AEMC s assessment. To this end, the framework should seek to assess the status quo for customers (ie no change in energy usage) against the value to customers of changing their energy use. In effect: promoting the use of DSP up to the point at which the value of reducing demand by an extra kwh is equal to the cost of supplying an extra kwh of electricity 1 should be replaced by: The value to consumers of changing their energy use must exceed (or at least equal) the value the consumer derives from not changing their use. For example, society as a whole will be better off if the benefit a consumer receives from peak shifting exceeds the benefit of not peak shifting. However, it also works in reverse so that society will also be better off if the benefits a consumer receives from not peak shifting exceed the benefits of peak shifting. 1 AEMC 2011 Power of Choice, p. 15

Allowing the customer to choose the outcome they want at any point in time will ensure that there is an efficient allocation of resources. The AEMC s supply-side economic framework runs the risk of pre-determining the customer s choice. For example, peak shifting will always be the preferred outcome (regardless of what the customer actually wants) because it can reduce the cost of supply. However, consumers may be prepared to pay this cost if the value that they receive from additional network services exceeds that cost. The AEMC s framework seems to assume that lower cost equals an efficient allocation of resources. However, this is not always the case as an efficient allocation of resources actually means that sufficient resources are allocated to meeting customer demand. This could mean that more resources need to be allocated to an industry (ie costs should rise) if that is what customers demand. Measuring value Having established the right framework, the question then becomes one of how value is measured. Measuring the value to consumers of changing how they use energy is fairly straight forward as it can be measured as the change in the value of energy services used (ie, c/kwh) Measuring the value to consumers of not changing their energy use is more difficult and needs to consider the following: The value derived from energy use. Ideally this would be measured using a contingent valuation methodology (eg, a survey of customer value). However, in the absence of this type of valuation methodology, a shadow price could be derived using the total cost to the consumer of the appliance plus the cost of using them (ie cost of the energy and connection over the life of the appliance). However, this needs to recognise that the shadow price may under-estimate the true value of use for consumers because their willingness to pay may exceed the dollar price that they pay. To the value of the derived demand must be added the avoided cost of not participating in DSP (eg the cost of solar panels), the information and time cost to consumers of evaluating their tariff structure to understand and make decisions about when and how they use energy, cost of switching fuels etc. AEMC s assessment process The result of the economic framework that the AEMC has used is that the AEMC s assessment process (section 3.4) starts from a position that the customer places a net positive valuation on DSP (ie that the benefits of DSP exceeds the value lost from changing usage behaviour). The AEMC has not undertaken this assessment nor has it demonstrated that this is the case. Conclusion The AEMC should not feel compelled to generate an outcome for the MCE because of the wording used in a Terms of Reference. I would recommend that the AEMC look toward the Productivity Commission for guidance on how to use first principles to develop recommendations of benefit to the customer, even if it is not what the MCE want to hear.

I have set out short responses to some of the questions raised in the paper in the attachment. If you would like to discuss this submission further, please contact me on (03) 8807 1132. Yours sincerely Dianne Shields Senior Regulatory Manager

Attachment: Response to questions raised in the Issues Paper Chapter 3: Methodology and assessment 1. Do you agree with our approach? See commentary in main letter 2. How should benefits be measured? See commentary in main letter 3. What are appropriate discount rates? No comment 4. Are there other issues we should consider See commentary in main letter Chapter 4: Consumer participation and DSP opportunities 5. What are the drivers for consumers changing their electricity consumption patterns? 6. Are there other plausible DSP options? 7. Are there DSP options not commonly used? 8. Are there DSP options that could be available if the appropriate technology were available? Chapter 5: Market conditions 9. What are considered the relevant market conditions to promote the take up of DSP? 10. Are there specific market conditions which may need to be in place to enable third parties to facilitate consumer decision making? 11. What market conditions are needed to make other DSP options available to consumers? 12. Do you consider retail tariffs currently reflect the costs to a retailer of supplying consumers with electricity? The value that consumers receive from changing their behaviour relative to the value they derive from not changing their behaviour The paper also needs to recognise that customers are often constrained in their energy consumption decisions. When and how they consume energy can be dictated by geographical location, income, life circumstances (eg children, unemployed) This question is an example of why the AEMC s economic framework may lead to the wrong outcome. Promoting DSP should not be the AEMC s starting position. Rather the AEMC should focus on whether there are market failures that prevent customers from maximising their welfare. Assuming that the AEMC is referring to the structure of retail tariffs and not the level. As is common in a lot of retail markets, pricing structures are a form of product differentiator between retailers. Mobile phone charging is a classic example of where retailers will offer different pricing structures to ensure their mobile phone services are appealing to a wide variety of customers. Some customers will want to buy their mobile out right and only pay for usage on an ongoing basis. Others may find it more convenient to bundle the price of their handset into their monthly bill. Hamburger outlets offer similar pricing structures with the availability of meal deals for one fixed price. Energy retailing is no different. Retailers already have

13. Are changes needed to retail price regulation to facilitate DSP? 14. Do the charges to retailers for use of the transmission network reflect the value of that use? 15. Do the charges to retailers for use of distribution networks reflect the value of that use? 16. Do all consumer groups benefits from having cost reflective prices in place? 17. Do customers understand how they can reduce their electricity bill? 18. What issues are associated with provision of existing information in the market? 19. Could better information be provided to consumers on the actual consumption of individual appliances and pieces of equipment? time-of-use tariffs available to customers but take up is limited because customers have traditionally wanted their retailer to manage the price risk for them and take up a flat rate tariff. Customers are not only buying energy from their retailer but they are also buying a risk management service so the customer can spend their time doing other things. What the customer wants will depend upon the customer. Some customers may want TOU pricing and so manage their own usage in accordance with that pricing structure. Others will find it more convenient to pay one flat rate charge to avoid the cost of managing their usage. It would need to be demonstrated that there was a market failure in the types of tariffs that customers have available to them before any regulated structures were forced upon customers. This question is an example of why the AEMC s economic framework may lead to the wrong outcome. This question assumes that customers are seeking to (and thus place a net positive value on) reducing their electricity bill. Each consumer will make their own electricity consumption choice based on the price, their income and the value they place on using energy at a point in time. It is possible that some consumers don t want to understand how they can reduce their bill. The primary issue with providing information to consumers about their energy use is their apathy about the topic. It would need to be demonstrated that customers demand different or more information for which they will have to pay and that the competitive market would not be able to provide this information. Most appliances have information on the power that it will consume. However, often consumers will place a much higher value on the output of the appliance than the cost associated with using it (big screen TVs are a classic example). It needs to be demonstrated that there is a market failure in the provision of this information where

20. Are retailers business models supportive of DSP? 21. What incentives are likely to encourage R&D? 22. Are there any barriers that affect the take up of DSP opportunities? 23. What contracts/clauses are required? 24. Are there specific issues associated with investment in infrastructure? 25. Are there split or misaligned incentives? 26. What are measures for addressing misaligned incentives? 27. What are the specific issues concerning access to capital? 28. What are the significant energy market challenges? 29. Do current technology, metering and control devices support DSP? 30. How can issues relating to weak and/or split incentives be addressed to ensure that the benefits of smart grid technologies are aligned? 31. How can pricing signals/tariff arrangements be made complementary? 32. What are the issues with consumer protection and privacy? customers demand it. The competitive market will provide this information where customers demand it as a supplier/retailer can use it as a product differentiator from their competitors. For example, a/cs are typically sold with information on the energy efficiency characteristics of the unit. This may influence the choice of unit but it is the value of staying cool in summer that will influence whether a customer buys an a/c or not. Retailers business models are supportive of providing the customer what he/she wants. If customers want DSP services, then the competitive retail market will evolve and provide this service to those customers who want it. Customers will seek out the services that they want and the retailers that can provide those services to them. If there is value in DSP to the customer, then a demand will be created and retailers will find value in supplying this service to customers. If retailers business models have not been supportive of DSP in the past, this is probably due to the fact that customers have not demanded these types of services until recently. Retailers business models have changed and will continue to change to support DSP if this is what customers are demanding.

Chapter 6: Market and regulatory arrangements 33. To what extent do parties have appropriate incentives? 34. Are there aspects of the NEL or Rules which prevent parties taking actions that would otherwise allow for more efficient levels of DSP? 35. Are there market failures? Forms of market failure include public good characteristics, either positive or negative externalities, information asymmetry, and imperfect competition or market power. Not aware of any studies that have identified that these market failures exist in regard to the take-up of DSP by consumers. Chapter 7: Energy efficiency 36. What energy efficiency policies and All energy efficiency schemes at the Commonwealth schemes should be considered? and State level require consideration. All white certificate schemes and feed-in tariff schemes require urgent review as they are poorly designed and are increasing energy prices for all customers for the 37. To what extent can energy efficiency schemes be adopted as options for DSP? 38. To what extent do existing retailer obligations facilitate efficient choices by consumers? benefit of the few. Increasing energy efficiency is a form of demand side response so energy efficiency schemes can be adopted as options for DSP. However, the current schemes (eg REES, VEET) are supply driven and very costly for consumers. They are schemes that have been forced upon retailers customers by government whereas, as far as I m aware, there has been no assessment of the value that customers place on achieving these energy efficiencies and whether the cost is worth it. Again, if customers valued these types of services, then there would be no need for a regulated scheme so it suggests that customers place very little value on the energy efficiency that these schemes achieve. The design of existing schemes is poor and it is likely that the cost of delivering a unit of energy efficiency to a householder under these schemes exceeds the value of that unit to the householder. It is not clear that they do as the true cost of delivering the energy efficiency activities to the householder concerned is hidden in energy prices. As a result, the householder does not see the real price they are paying. In its Review of Energy Efficiency Policy Options for the Residential and Commercial Building Sectors, PricewaterhouseCoopers noted that: While international experience is fairly limited

to date, early indications are that mandatory energy efficiency targets (ie white certificate schemes) can be effective in delivering energy efficiency improvements. However, the schemes are complex to design and do not come without their own challenges. A key concern with white certificate schemes is their level of cost-effectiveness. If mandatory targets are not easily met by liable parties, consumers could be forced to pay for uneconomic forms of abatement. 2 PricewaterhouseCoopers also noted that a key risk with these schemes was that retailers incur costs in seeking out and implementing energy efficiency gains that may happen anyway due to increases in energy prices. 3 2 PricewaterhouseCoopers 2008 Review of Energy Efficiency Policy Options for the Residential and Commercial Building Sectors, Report prepared for the Energy Retailers Association of Australia, p. 4. 3 Ibid, p. 5