Generic Drug Companies:

Similar documents
Pharmaceutical Report Royalty Purchasing Industry. Thomas R. Wells

Intellectual Property and Access to HIV/AIDS Treatment Case Studies

PROMOTING ACCESS AND MEDICAL INNOVATION: INTERSECTIONS BETWEEN PUBLIC HEALTH, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND TRADE

EC s Preliminary Pharmaceutical Sector Report: An Aggressive Review of Industry Conduct

Life Sciences & Healthcare

Pharmaceutical Products Liability. Michael C. Dubin Stephen Knobloch

Ryerson Digital Media Zone Online Resources Patent Essentials

EROSION OF EXCLUSIVE MARKETING RIGHTS- BOON FOR THE PHARMACEUTICAL SECTOR

SCIENCE, TECHNOLOGY AND INNOVATION FOR THE TRANSFORMATION OF AFRICAN ECONOMIES

Privilege - pitfalls and obstacles for clients operating in multiple jurisdictions

The Geography of Markets for Technology: Evidence from Bio- Pharmaceuticals

GENEVA STANDING COMMITTEE ON THE LAW OF PATENTS. Fourteenth Session Geneva, January 25 to 29, 2010 PROPOSAL FROM BRAZIL *

ar gthe international journal of

Strategic Licensing in the New Economy

The Prize Fund for HIV/AIDS

The Biotech Business Life Cycle. The Lawyer s Role as Counselor and Advisor

Ensuring Safety and Access

Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting. Novak druce centre insights No. 8

Overcoming Restriction Requirements On Pharma Patents

The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment

First to File and Beyond: Paragraph IV Business Strategies

Access to Medicines, Patent Information and Freedom to Operate

WIPO TRAINING OF TRAINERS PROGRAM ON EFFECTIVE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ASSET MANAGEMENT BY SMALL AND MEDIUM-SIZED ENTERPRISES (SMEs)

AUTM U.S. Licensing Activity Survey: FY2014

Parallel Importation: Economic and social welfare dimensions

GLOBAL ACCESS LICENSING FRAMEWORK

Pay-for-Delay: How Drug Company Pay-Offs Cost Consumers Billions. An FTC Staff Study January Federal Trade Commission ftc.

The Intellectual Property System in Ethiopia

Health Law in Canada. Constitutional Division of Power

Roopa Ramamoorthi PhD, PMP, Associate Director, Partnering and Scientific Affairs

Medicines for Neglected Diseases Workshop. Dennis Liotta, Ph.D. Director Emory Institute for Drug Discovery Atlanta, Georgia

Legal FAQ: Introduction to Patent Litigation

CHEM-E4140 Selectivity 12. Pharma Business

Trends in Patent Litigation in India

209: Using Competitive Intelligence to Drive your IP Portfolio

Mywish Maredia, Frederic Erbisch, Anwar Naseem, Amie Hightower, James Oehmke, Dave Weatherspoon, & Christopher Wolf 1

Institute for OneWorld Health

THE BIOTECH & PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY

Guidelines for the National IP Strategy of the Republic of Macedonia ( ) Version 2

ENFORCEMENT OF IP RIGHTS IN THE DIGITAL ENVIRONMENT CONCERNS, CHALLENGES AND ACTIONS REQUIRED FOR THE PROTECTION OF THE SINGLE MARKET.

IP Valuation. WIPO Workshop on Innovation, Intellectual Asset Management and Successful Technology Licensing: Wealth Creation in the Arab Region

shutterstock.com Interim Management and Strategic Transactions for International Life Science Companies TCG: experienced, connected, proven success

RE: Transatlantic Business Concerns about Indian Government IP Policies

Intellectual Property Rights in the USA

Biosimilar Monoclonal Antibodies in the Pipeline: Major Players and Strategies

A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDING FOR EARLY STAGE COMPANIES

U.S. DRUG IMPORT BILL HAS SERIOUS IMPLICATIONS FOR CANADA

Efficient alternative dispute resolution (ADR) for intellectual property disputes

Access to Medicines and Vaccines: Implications of Intellectual Property Protection and Trade Agreements

DUE DILIGENCE IN TRANSACTIONS INVOLVING INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY 1. Edward A. Meilman James W. Brady, Jr. Jamie Ryerson Dickstein Shapiro LLP

Philippines Philippines Philippinen. Report Q202. in the name of the Philippine Group by Rogelio NICANDRO

Adopt IP Protections to Ensure Regulatory Exclusivity for Orphan Drugs

Valuation of Your Early Drug Candidate. By Linda Pullan, Ph.D. Toll-free USA Worldwide

A Guide To Conducting IP Due Diligence In M&A

Energizing Innovation. By Kazem Kazempour, PhD, George Steinfels, PhD, MBA and Mukesh Kumar, PhD, RAC

Beat the AIDS epidemic Press for fair prices and better access to medicines.

Pennino Corporation TECHNOLOGY TO IMPROVE LIFE

OFFICE OF ATTORNEY GENERAL LAWRENCE G. WASDEN AVERAGE WHOLESALE PRICE LITIGATION REPORT AUGUST 2013

PATENTS. Pharmaceutical Product Patenting Strategies

When treating a disease is bad business: orphan and neglected diseases

cost of taking on an interference proceeding under the old first-to-invent system, which cost around $2 million.

Pharmaceutical royalties: a new securitisation frontier Malcolm S Dorris Dechert LLP. Dechert LLP 2007

OVERVIEW OF CONTRACTUAL AGREEMENTS FOR THE TRANSFER OF TECHNOLOGY

[Name of Company] [ ] [ ] [ ] [ ] (4) List of states and foreign countries in which qualified to do business. [ ] [ ] [ ] [ ] (5) All Business Plans.

Open Innovation: An Imperative for the Pharmaceutical Industry. Berkeley Innovation Forum

Investing in Invention TM

United States of America Takeover Guide

Creating Joint Value. In Biopharma and Many Other Industries, Not Invented Here Is SO Last Century. By Ben Gomes-Casseres

Pharmaceutical Counterfeiting: Issues, Trends, Measurement

The Technology Transfer Process

K-12 Entrepreneurship Standards

INVITATION LETTER ASSIGNMENT TITLE: INDIVIDUAL CONSULTANCY SERVICES RELATED TO THE TRAINING ON ADVANCED GCP TRAINING FOR RBC/MRC.

Q&A Intellectual Property Policy

TACD RECOMMENDATIONS ON HEALTH CARE AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND EUROPEAN COMMISSION SERVICES RESPONSES

The 505(b)(2) Drug Development Pathway:

The economics of the Export-Import Bank: a teaching note

The Medicines Patent Pool Understanding the Patent Status of Antiretroviral Drugs. Ellen t Hoen Medicines Patent Pool

South Africa s IP Policy

CLIENT MEMORANDUM. I. The Basics. June 18, 2013

Due Diligence Request List: IP and IT

FDLI s IP Throughout the Drug Development Lifecycle

PDP Funders Group Briefing Paper Background. 2. Methods

DECREE THE GOVERNMENT

INTERNET USAGE AND THE POTENTIAL EFFECT IN YOUR MANAGEMENT OF YOUR PATENT PROGRAM. Steven D. Hemminger. Lyon & Lyon, LLP

Intellectual Property

Vectura Group plc. Annual Report and Accounts 2015

Road map for establishing Technology & Innovation Support Centers (TISC)

Future Perspectives of Health Insurance

THE POTENTIAL IMPACT OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS ON PUBLIC HEALTH

Universal Declaration on Bioethics and Human Rights

MAIN BIO EXPERIENCE SPEECHES PUBLICATIONS NEWS

The Pharmaceutical Industry and the Patent System. Bruce Lehman 1 President, International Intellectual Property Institute

PATENT BOX HOW TO MAXIMISE THE BENEFITS

House Proposal of Amendment S. 7 An act relating to social networking privacy protection. The House proposes to the Senate to amend the bill by

1. A. Name of Applicant: Partnership Limited Liability Partnership. B. Street / Mailing Address: City: County:

CHAPTER 17. Financial Management

STATS WINDOW. INDUSTRY REVIEW AT A GLANCE Global Pharmaceutical Industry

Canada s Patented Medicines (Notice of Compliance) Regulations: Removing Inefficiencies to Encourage Generic Competition

INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCE ON HARMONISATION OF TECHNICAL REQUIREMENTS FOR REGISTRATION OF PHARMACEUTICALS FOR HUMAN USE S1A. Current Step 4 version

ON: Examining Legislative Proposals to Modernize Business Development Companies and Expand Investment Opportunities

Transcription:

Michael Gollin Venable LLP October 7, 2003 Generic Drug Companies: Competing at Boundaries of Time and Geography

The generic drug industry is locked in a perennial struggle with the patented drug industry. Legal battles are being fought constantly across boundaries of time and geography. For the individual companies, these battles are distressing and costly, and to hear the lobbyists, each side is poised to destroy the other. My view is more optimistic. I think that the fierce competition between the companies in the U.S. is a sign of a robust system at work. Indeed, I can not think of another system that would work as well at balancing the rival interests to achieve social benefit. The Dilemma of Human Desires At the core of the struggle are two fundamental human desires, which create what I call the dilemma of "medicine later vs. medicine now." On the one hand, people want new and better medicines in the future, to make us healthier and therefore happier. Our societies prize innovation. We believe that new ideas will improve our lives, and the lives of our children. And so we reward medical researchers. The Nobel prize for medicine, just awarded to Paul C. Lauterbur and Sir Peter Mansfield for magnetic resonance imaging, is a reward that can be shared by only a few individuals. A much more widespread instrument of reward is the system of laws and practices we call intellectual property, and in particular, for medicine, it is patents that give the inventor the reward of limited exclusive rights over the invention. On the other hand -- sick people want the best medicine they can get, now. This leads to the populist argument that patents keep the cost of medicine too high for poor patients, and so governments should help by granting compulsory licenses and importing less expensive generic drugs in order to protect the public health. The drug industry argues that weakening patents will reduce research, development, and improvements in health care, in effect robbing improvements from future patients. This argument is based on economics and is lost on people who frame the issue as a populist choice of patients vs. patents.' The conflict between medicine later and medicine now raises issues of intergenerational and international equity. We deal with the intergenerational issue first.

Intergenerational Equity Medicine Later vs. Medicine Now The problem may be framed as follows: How do we balance the needs of today s patients for today s medicine with the needs of future patients to have new medicine? This balance may be referred to as sustainable innovation, borrowing from the concept of sustainable development. 1 The answer must have to do with the specific boundaries of a patent in terms of its scope and its duration, but there is an appalling lack of guidance on the core issue what is the optimum strength and duration of drug patents? In the meantime, the answer to this question must take into consideration the complementary public roles of the generic industry and the patented pharmaceutical industry Let us review the pharmaceutical ecosystem, and the generic industry's niche within it, as shown in the Figure 1. THE PHARMACEUTICAL ECOSYSTEM Investors angels venture public Doctors Public Research Institutions Researchers Technology Transfers Academic Institutions Small Biotech Co s Researchers Investors Business Level Big Pharmaceutical Co s Researchers Shareholders Sales Generic Drug Co s Hospitals Public Health Agencies Patients Academic Researchers Technology Transfers Offices Government Patent Office & Trademark patent examination trademarks Government Drug Agency Approval of New Drugs Approval of Generics Insurers Figure 1 1 Michael Gollin, Sustainable Innovation for Public Health, Food and Drug Law Institute Update Magazine (January/February 2002)

This ecosystem has many "creatures" -- inventors, research institutions, corporations (biotechnology companies as well as patent holding "big pharma" and generics), funders (investors, insurers, donors), governmental regulators (patent offices and food and drug and health agencies), patients, doctors, nurses, hospitals, and insurance companies. Upon reflection it becomes clear that this is not a bipolar world of patented pharmaceutical companies vs. generic companies, but rather it is a rich and diverse community with many stakeholders. The competitive relationship between generics and patent holders is influenced not just by each other, but by all the other players. Generic competition arises at a crucial temporal boundary when a patent expires but that is in the context of many broader relationships. The Hand Off to Generics Next we focus in particular on that boundary the time for a particular drug when the generic company steps in. The boundary is clear in Figure 2, which shows the life cycle of a drug. LIFE CYCLE OF A DRUG literature know-how Research Development Patentee Commercialization Generic Commercialization education funding Basic Applied Applied Pre-Clinical Research Research Research Research Clinical O Trials O O O O O O O O O Generic Testing equipment time Biological Conception Reduction model to practice (in vitro) Animal tests positive 1st clinical trial positive 2nd clinical trial positive Regulatory Approval (country by country) Generic drug available (patent expires or invalid) Better drug available biological materials publication patent application safety efficiency sales 3-10 years bioequivalent patent prosecution exclusive rights bioinformatics data i f patent issuance (country by country) 20 years + New delivery system New method of use Figure 2 Again, it is important to note that "big pharma" (as the patented industry is sometimes referred to) is not the only source of new medicines. Much of the starting material for a new drug comes from publicly funded research. There is then a handoff of sorts from public research institutions to big pharma, either by

a technology transfer agreement, as with Bristol-Myers Squibb's license of Taxol from the NIH, or by publication of the basic science. Research progresses to the clinical stage, and a drug is developed and approved for market, thus beginning the patentee commercialization phase. In the U.S. system, generic companies begin preparing early so they are ready to enter the market immediately upon patent expiration. Rules of fair play govern this hand off, such as the Hatch-Waxman Act, which allows generic companies to develop their manufacturing capability and to conduct clinical trials prior to patent expiration, and in effect to "free ride" on the patent holder's clinical data, by showing only that the generic drug is bioequivalent to the patented drug. Meanwhile, there is extensive skirmishing around that hand-off. Patent-holding big pharma has a strong incentive to innovate and patent new dosage forms, formulations, and chemical variants on successful drugs, bringing a stream of improvements to patients, improvements which may be more modest than a blockbuster, but are nonetheless important. Generic companies, too, innovate to optimize chemical synthesis processes, and they have an incentive to timely enter the marketplace when a patent expires, and even to challenge a weak patent so they can enter the market earlier. Let us consider what would happen without such a mechanism? One example is the new generation of so-called "biologics," such as therapeutic proteins. Examples are erythropoietin, human growth hormone, insulin, and interferon. The Hatch-Waxman Act does not apply to these drugs. Many people are concerned that because it is harder for generic companies to enter the market for a biologic, big pharma will have less incentive to make constant improvements on existing drugs (a variant of the economic argument for "medicine later"). Also, the generic companies will have to replicate the full clinical data instead, at great cost, and with no social benefit except to clinical research organizations, instead of investing in other more valuable projects (interfering with "medicine now").

The False Dichotomy This discussion raises another important point about the relationship between generics and patent-holding pharmaceutical companies -- it is a false dichotomy. Generic companies innovate and patent their inventions in areas such as chemical synthesis, new methods of use, and new delivery systems, and as they grow, they even do basic research. Patent-holders compete with each other by producing alternatives of other blockbuster products such as cox-2 inhibitors (Vioxx by Merck and Celebrex by Pfizer), and PDE5 inhibitors (Viagra, Cialis, and Levitra). Patent-holders run their own generic companies to take advantage of the separate market niche (as with Novartis with generic subsidiaries Sandoz and Geneva). So we see that generic companies hold patents and innovate, and patent-holders challenge other innovators, and sell generic drugs. The two industries have a substantial amount in common. The System at Work Some examples of the skirmishes at the temporal boundaries will illustrate that this is not a bad system, even if it is hard on the players. In recent patent litigation over the antihistamine Loratidine, Schering Plough owned a patent on a metabolite of the original patented drug, des-loratidine. The patent was ruled invalid in a challenge by Teva and other generic companies. As a result, generics entered the market, and Claritin lost most of its market share, and faced huge price erosion. Schering is still trying to recover. Also, GlaxoSmithKline's Paxil (paroxetine hydrochloride) was patented as a particular "polymorph" or crystal form. A trial court ruled the patent invalid this Spring, and without waiting for the appeal, generic company Apotex last month launched sales of the antidepressant. This will surely result in lower costs, making the drug more widely available. And it puts new pressure on GSK to innovate to find new blockbuster drugs, instead of optimizing existing drugs. A third example is Bayer's Ciprofloxacin. During the anthrax scare in 2001, US Secretary of Health and Human Services Thompson briefly threatened that the U.S. might assert compulsory license to gain access to Cipro at below market prices. At the same time, a generic company, Danbury, was challenging the

extension of the Cipro patent, but that challenge failed, giving the Cipro patent additional life. Another aspect of skirmishing involves heightened antitrust oversight of generics and big pharma. Without going into detail here, it is worth observing that the gist of the recent Federal Trade Commission efforts to block collusion between generics and patent holders is the desire to maintain robust competition the same goal that I am suggesting makes this system work well. International Equity -- Medicine Here vs. Medicine Elsewhere The second problem characterizing the role of the generic industry, and its competitive relationship with patented pharmaceutical companies, is the issue of international equity, or "medicine here vs. medicine elsewhere." The question may be framed as follows: How can we balance the needs of patients in rich countries like the U.S. with those of poor countries? This is an aspect of the overall North-South dynamic. Our concern here should be, what is the role of generic companies in striking such a balance? Increasingly, there are global markets for making and selling drugs, and patent-holding companies are seeking markets in all corners of the world. However, patients in poor countries can be at a terrible disadvantage because of the small markets, low purchasing power, lack of incentive for development of drugs for their worst public health problems (e.g. malaria, tuberculosis, leishmaniasis), and the absence of intellectual property expertise, which is concentrated almost entirely in the rich countries. One solution has been to promote a globalization of the generic industry. Some drugs are patented in some countries but not in others. Here, a generic version of the drug can be sold in any country where there is no patent in force. The only obstacle is to determine that no patent exists that would block sale of the drug, what we patent attorneys call "freedom to operate." That determination, in turn, requires patent expertise too often lacking in developing countries. As the WTO's agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property comes into force in developing countries, patents will become more valuable and the number of countries where patents for a particular drug are obtained may increase. So the international scope of freedom to operate is likely to diminish and the need for careful analysis of existing patents will grow.

An organization like Public Interest Intellectual Property Advisors (PIIPA) can help developing countries pursue their interests in the globalization of competition between patented pharmaceutical companies and generic companies. PIIPA is a global non-profit resource for developing countries and public interest organizations seeking expertise in intellectual property matters to promote health, agriculture, biodiversity, science, culture, and the environment. PIIPA provides worldwide access to a network of IP professionals who can advise and represent such clients pro bono publico (as a public service). 2 A second way to promote globalization of the generic industry is via compulsory licensing consistent with the WTO agreements. We have seen skirmishes at the geographical borders with respect to anti-retrovirals in South Africa and Brazil, as well as the US as mentioned before. This, too, requires extensive expertise. The country that decides to exercise a compulsory license must then decide whether to make the drug domestically, or to import from a generic company in another country. The 2001 Doha declaration and the August 30, 2003 statement of the TRIPS council made it clear that countries have many avenues to encourage generic competition in their countries if the patent-holder does not make a drug available on acceptable terms. 3 Countries such as India, Brazil, South Africa, and Thailand are well-positioned to build a local generic industry for domestic use and export. This endeavor can serve many national development goals. Indeed, India's generic companies are growing rapidly and becoming important players in the global pharmaceutical market, due to skills and capacity dating from before patent laws there were strengthened. This kind of competition is likely to be very effective at bringing about supplies of drugs at a suitable price, and may reduce the need or interest for price controls. Again, the path to being able to obtain or produce a drug, by purchase from the manufacturer, license, independent production with freedom to operate, or compulsory licensing is extremely complicated. Figure 3 shows some of the decisions that need to be made to reach the goal of providing access to a particular medicine. 2 See www.piipa.org. 3 http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/implem_para6_e.htm

IP DECISION TREE FOR ACCESS TO ESSENTIAL DRUGS 4. Non-infringing version available? N Y 1. Patented in Country X? N Y 5. Patent Invalid? N Y Make it or buy it (import) 2. Available to purchase at low price? N Y 3. Patent Term Short? Long? Get ready to Jump In! 6. Negotiate License Litigate - challenge in Country X Patentee offer - WIN? $ High? $ Low? 7. Compulsory Buy License. License Available? -Law in effect? -Law applies? N Y 8. Government use? Compulsory license to private party Generic Manufacturing -Local or import Buy and Distribute Once Approved as a Drug Figure 3 Again, the complexity of this approach requires intellectual property expertise lacking in most developing countries. As noted above, this has been the driving demand for the non-profit service called Public Interest Intellectual Property Advisors, which makes IP professionals available to developing country clients who need their services. Meanwhile, the U.S. Congress is contemplating legislation that would permit the importation of drugs from foreign countries where the prices are lower, to bring increased price competition. One thing to be very cautious about is the possibility that importing will increase the amount of counterfeit "bad" drugs on the market, because it is more difficult to enforce quality standards on foreign companies. The flip side of importing, of course, is exporting. In Canada, a proposed amendment to the patent law would permit Canadian generic drug makers to produce medicines for export, even if they were listed and patent-protected in Canada, so long as they are directed to poor countries grappling with pandemic diseases. 4 Apparently Canadian patent drug makers are willing to work with the government "to frame any legislative proposal to assist in humanitarian relief." Presumably the generic companies would compete on price, and the patentholding companies would rather not go down that path. This is a fitting final 4 http://www.pbs.org/newshour/updates/canada_11-06-03.html

example, as it promises some collaboration between generic and patent-holding drug companies. In conclusion, society needs to support both those who innovate in medicine, and those who disseminate the best medical innovations. Social benefit is maximized by a framework that first, rewards innovator drug companies with patent rights that are limited by specific boundaries of time and geography, while second, encouraging generic drug companies to compete vigorously outside those boundaries. The consequence of this system may be furious policy battles over the optimal strength of medicine patents in general, and specific legal battles at the temporal and geographical boundaries. This leaves much hard work for lawyers, but this is an inherent part of the system, and can promote sustainable innovation, balancing our desire for the best medicines here and now with the desire for better drugs everywhere tomorrow.