Deterrence, litigation costs, and the statute of limitations for tort suits



Similar documents
The Reasonable Person Negligence Standard and Liability Insurance. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

1 SHORT ANSWER QUESTIONS

WORKERS COMPENSATION SUBROGATION AND THIRD PARTY SETTLEMENTS. B. Industrial Revolution and Workers Compensation Statutes

Liability Insurance as Protection Against Legal Error. Vickie Bajtelsmit Colorado State University. and

HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS

Boalt Hall UC Berkeley

IN THE SUPREME COURT OF TEXAS

STRICT LIABILITY VERSUS NEGLIGENCE

Chapter 17 Compromise; Settlement 2001 EDITION

No-Fault Automobile Insurance

The Effect of Product Safety Regulatory Compliance

Cardelli Lanfear P.C.

Claims College School of Construction LEVEL 1

No UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SEVENTH CIRCUIT. 427 F.3d 1048; 2005 U.S. App. LEXIS 22999

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 15: Repeated Games and Cooperation

Reed Armstrong Quarterly

Chapter 4 Crimes (Review)

Georgia Board for Physician Workforce

Empirical Comparisons of the Contributory versus Comparative Negligence Rules. Michelle J. White

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015

Faculty of Law Fall Semester 2015

Product Liability Risks for Distributors: The Basics. Susan E. Burnett Bowman and Brooke LLP

OREGON LAW AT-A-GLANCE

PROCEDURAL PROVISIONS IN NEVADA MEDICAL MALPRACTICE REFORM. Carl Tobias*

TOPIC IS IN THE ECONOMICS OF TORT LIABILITY (from COOTER, ULEN Introduction to Law and Economics 2000 (3rd ed))

Key Concept 4: Understanding Product Liability Law

AN ACT. To amend chapter 383, RSMo, by adding thereto thirteen new sections relating to the Missouri health care arbitration act.

UNINSURED AND UNDERINSURED MOTORIST COVERAGE - HISTORY

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH THE RECOVERY OF NATIONAL HEALTH SERVICE COSTS IN CASES INVOLVING PERSONAL INJURY COMPENSATION


Manufacturers versus Component Part and Raw Material Suppliers: How to Prevent Liability By Kenneth Ross *

STATE OF MINNESOTA IN COURT OF APPEALS A Faron L. Clark, Respondent, vs. Sheri Connor, et al., Defendants, Vydell Jones, Appellant.

GENERAL ASSEMBLY OF NORTH CAROLINA SESSION 2011 HOUSE DRH11149-TG-5 (12/01) Short Title: Tort Reform Act of (Public)

PRODUCT LIABILITY LAW IN EGYPT -- AN OVERVIEW OF SOME CIVIL AND COMMERCIAL CODE RULES. Howard L. Stovall *

Insurance Coverage In Consumer Class Actions

Full Compensation Criteria in the Law of Torts An Enquiry into the Doctrine of Causation Ram Singh

CHAPTER 2 THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN NO-FAULT INSURANCE AND DRIVER BEHAVIOR

Published in Journal of Legal Economics, Volume 5, Number 2, Fall 1995 pp

ORDER GRANTING SUMMARY JUDGMENT. THIS MATTER comes on for consideration of DEFENDANT S MOTION FOR I. STATEMENT OF THE CASE

SCOTTISH EXECUTIVE HEALTH DEPARTMENT THE RECOVERY OF NATIONAL HEALTH SERVICE COSTS IN CASES INVOLVING PERSONAL INJURY COMPENSATION

Manufacturing Defects

Case 1:07-cv MJW-BNB Document 51 Filed 08/21/2008 Page 1 of 8 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLORADO

PURSUANT TO INTERNAL REVENUE CODE SECTION 7463(b),THIS OPINION MAY NOT BE TREATED AS PRECEDENT FOR ANY OTHER CASE.

Automobile Negligence Lawsuits

VIRGINIA ACTS OF ASSEMBLY SESSION

(1) A person to whom damage to another is legally attributed is liable to compensate that damage.

LAW REFORM (CONTRIBUTORY NEGLIGENCE) AMENDMENT BILL 2001

UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT EASTERN DISTRICT OF VIRGINIA Richmond Division

APPORTIONMENT OF LIABILITY: UNIFORM APPORTIONMENT OF TORT RESPONSIBILITY ACT AS COMPARED TO RESTATEMENT THIRD, TORTS

****************************************************** The officially released date that appears near the beginning of each opinion is the date the

Navigating the Statute of Limitations in Texas

SUPREME COURT OF LOUISIANA

Advocate Magazine March Why medical malpractice still matters.

Attorney for Plaintiff SUPERIOR COURT OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA LOS ANGELES COUNTY CENTRAL DISTRICT STANLEY MOSK COURTHOUSE

Massachusetts Legislature Reforms Medical Malpractice Legislation to Promote Apologies and Encourage Settlements

Figure 6: Effect of ITC on Skilled and Unskilled Labor Markets

LIABILITY FOR ACCIDENTS

Key Concept 9: Understand the differences between compensatory and punitive damages 1. A. Torts. 1. Compensatory and Punitive Damages

Roche v. NJ Mfg Ins Co

CHAPTER 30: EMPLOYEE INJURIES

MONTANA SELF INSURERS ASSOCIATION

October 9, Honorable Orrin G. Hatch United States Senate Washington, DC Dear Senator:

Executive summary and overview of the national report for Denmark

NEGLIGENCE PER SE II. BACKGROUND. Richard B. Kilpatrick*

TORT AND INSURANCE LAW REPORTER. Informal Discovery Interviews Between Defense Attorneys and Plaintiff's Treating Physicians

ALABAMA COURT OF CIVIL APPEALS

MISSOURI COURT OF APPEALS NORTHERN DISTRICT. David Moore, for Appellant, and Stone C. Defense for Respondent.

)LQDQFLDO$VVXUDQFH,VVXHV RI(QYLURQPHQWDO/LDELOLW\

Cole, Scott & Kissane, P.A.

VII. JUDGMENT RULE 54. JUDGMENTS; COSTS

How To Defend Yourself In A Lawsuit Against A Car Insurance Policy In Illinois

Case: 1:07-cv Document #: 44 Filed: 03/12/09 Page 1 of 5 PageID #:<pageid>

The following is an excerpt from the 2012 Manual on Town Government. LIABILITY

THE TOP 10 QUESTIONS YOU SHOULD ASK YOUR CAR ACCIDENT LAWYER

Chapter 11 Torts in the Business Environment

Sensitivity Analysis 3.1 AN EXAMPLE FOR ANALYSIS

QUESTION NO. 3. Amendment to Titles 1 and 3 of the Nevada Revised Statutes. CONDENSATION (ballot question)

Structured Settlement Program

IN THE SUPERIOR COURT OF THE COMMONWEALTH OF THE NORTHERN MARIANA ISLANDS

ILLINOIS LAW MANUAL CHAPTER I CIVIL PROCEDURE. A statute of limitations is a statute establishing a time limit for suing in a civil case,

PART III MEDICAID LIEN RECOVERY. 1) From the estate of the Medicaid recipient.

No. 62 February 13, IN THE COURT OF APPEALS OF THE STATE OF OREGON. Scott HUGHES, Plaintiff-Appellant,

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

IN THE APPELLATE COURT OF ILLINOIS FIRST DISTRICT

HARVARD. Lucian Arye Bebchuk. Discussion Paper No /1997. As published in 3 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law (1998)

How To Settle A Lawsuit Against The City Of Naperville

3.1. Solving linear equations. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes. Learning Style

Credible Discovery, Settlement, and Negative Expected Value Suits

South Australia LAW REFORM (CONTRIBUTORY NEGLIGENCE AND APPORTIONMENT OF LIABILITY) ACT 2001

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT EASTERN DISTRICT OF MISSOURI EASTERN DIVISION

THE EFFECT OF SETTLEMENT IN KAPLOW S MULTISTAGE ADJUDICATION

MANAGEMENT OPTIONS AND VALUE PER SHARE

Keyspan Gas E. Corp. v Munich Reins. Am., Inc NY Slip Op Supreme Court, New York County. Scarpulla, J.

February 20, You inquire concerning section 4 of 1977 House Bill 2490, an amendment. Dear Commissioner Bell:

United States Court of Appeals

IN THE COMMONWEALTH COURT OF PENNSYLVANIA

Pennsylvania Superior Court Renders Pro-Policyholder Decision on Primary Insurer s Attempt to Obtain Reimbursement of Defense Costs

Defenses in a Product Liability Claim

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA

H.R. 5 Help Efficient, Accessible, Low-cost, Timely Healthcare (HEALTH) Act of 2003

Transcription:

International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 Deterrence, litigation costs, and the statute of limitations for tort suits Thomas J. Miceli Department of Economics, U-63, University of Connecticut, Storrs, CT 06269-1063 Received May 1999; received in revised form October 1999 1. Introduction The conventional justification for a statute of limitations on tort suits (or any other legal claim) is that evidence deteriorates over time, thereby increasing the likelihood of legal error. 1 The optimal statute balances this cost of a longer statute length against the dilution in deterrence that results from a shorter length. In this paper I develop a formal model to show that a finite statute length is optimal even in a world without the possibility of legal error. The trade-off involves only litigation costs and deterrence: while a shorter statute reduces deterrence, it also saves on litigation costs by limiting the number of suits that can be filed. I examine this trade-off under both strict liability and under negligence, and show that the optimal statute length is (probably) shorter under strict liability than under negligence. Intuitively, the marginal benefit of lengthening the statute is higher under a negligence rule because, by increasing the length of time over which victims can file suit, deterrence is enhanced, which in turn reduces the likelihood that a given injurer will be found negligent. Thus, fewer victims file suits at each point in time because their chances of winning are reduced. As a result, litigation costs fall, which partially offsets the extra litigation costs when the statute is lengthened. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the basic model, Section 3 derives the Tel. 860-486-5810; fax: 860-486-4463. E-mail address: Miceli@uconnvm.uconn.edu (T.J. Miceli). 1 See, e.g., Cooter and Ulen (1988: p. 155), andes and Posner (1987: p. 307), and Epstein (1986). Despite (or possibly because of) the wide acceptance of this argument, there has been almost no formal analyses of statutes of limitations in the law and economics literature. An exception is Baker and Miceli (2000). 0144-8188/00/$ see front matter 2000 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved. PII: S0144-8188(00)00038-7

384 T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 optimal statute of limitations for a strict liability rule, and Section 4 repeats the analysis for a negligence rule. Section 5 then offers some informal evidence in support of the theory based on the enactment of statutes of repose for products liability cases, the emergence of the rule of discovery under negligence law, and differences in the statute of limitations for trespass versus nuisance cases. Finally, Section 6 concludes. 2. The model The model is based on the one developed by Hylton (1990). Injurers and victims are both risk-neutral, and injurers alone can take care to reduce the likelihood of an accident (i.e., the model is one of unilateral care). For simplicity, the injurer s care choice is dichotomous: either take care or no care. et q be the probability of an accident if the injurer takes care, and p be the probability if he does not, where p q 0. The cost of care for injurers is denoted x, which varies across the population of injurers according to the distribution function H(x). Injurers know their own cost of care, but victims do not observe the costs of individual injurers (though they know the distribution function), nor do they know if an injurer actually took care in a given case. However, I assume that the court can observe whether or not an injurer took care as well as the injurer s cost of care (for purposes of applying a negligence rule) if a case goes to trial. Victims vary in their (fixed) damages in the event of an accident, denoted D. The distribution function of victims damages is F(D). At the time they make their care choice, injurers do not know the damage that an individual victim will suffer, but they know the distribution of victim damages. However, the court can observe D after the fact when determining a damage award. When an accident occurs, if the victim files suit, she incurs litigation costs of c v while the injurer incurs litigation costs of c i. In Hylton s (1990) static model, all victims who find a suit profitable file immediately. Here I allow the possibility that some victims will delay filing suit. For example, some injuries might not be immediately evident or some injurers might avoid immediate detection or identification. To keep the model simple, I abstract from the specific reason for delay and simply treat the length of time after an accident that a victim files suit, denoted t, as a random variable with distribution function G(t). Thus, for example, if the statute of limitations is set at, then G() is the probability that a randomly chosen victim will file suit by time. 2 3. Strict liability Under strict liability, all victims for whom D c v and t will file suit. Thus, if an accident occurs, the probability of a lawsuit is g(t)[1 F(c v )] at any t up to (where 2 Alternatively, G() can be interpreted as the number of suits filed by. I assume that t is independent of the victim s damages, D.

T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 385 g(t) G(t)), and zero thereafter. If a suit is filed, the injurer faces liability equal to the damage suffered by the victim, D. For suits filed in the future (t 0), this amount should be discounted to the present (the date when the injurer makes his care choice) by the interest rate r, yielding a present value of liability equal to De rt for a suit filed at time t. I assume, however, that the court awards the victim interest on D at rate r, beginning at the accident date (t 0), 3 thereby exactly offsetting the injurer s discounting. Thus, regardless of the date when a case is filed, the injurer bears expected liability of D as of t 0. In the absence of this prejudgment interest, the injurer s incentives would clearly be diluted merely by the victim s delay in filing. 4 The same is not true of the injurer s litigation costs. Specifically, a case filed at time t costs the injurer c i e rt in present value terms. Thus, the injurer does gain from delay in this respect. Given the above factors, the injurer s expected costs of taking care under a rule of strict liability with a statute of limitations of are given by x qg cv DdFD 1 Fc v 0 c i e rt gtdt. (1) Similarly, the expected costs of not taking care are pg DdFD 1 Fc v cv 0 c i e rt gtdt. (2) Combining Eq. (1) and Eq. (2) yields the condition for the injurer to take care: x p qg cv DdFD 1 Fc v 0 c i e rt gtdt x s. (3) The right-hand side represents the highest cost injurer who chooses to take care under strict liability as a function of. Taking the derivative of Eq. (3) with respect to yields [Eq. (4)] x s p q g D c i e r dfd 0. (4) c v Thus, increasing the statute of limitations increases the number of injurers who choose to take care, by increasing both expected liability and the present value of litigation costs. This captures the impact of the statute of limitations on deterrence. Socially, care is desirable when the social costs of care are less than the social costs of no care. The social costs of care are 3 I ignore the problem of possible differences between the discount rate and the interest rate. 4 See Ross and Goelz (1985) on the calculation of prejudgment interest. Some states allow it to begin accruing at the date of the accident (the assumption here), while others use the date that the complaint is filed or the date when a settlement is first offered.

386 T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 x qed 1 Fc v 0 c i c v e rt gtdt. (5) This differs from Eq. (1) in two respects: the inclusion of damages suffered by victims who do not file suit, and the inclusion of the present value of the litigation costs of victims who do file. The social cost of not taking care are ped 1 Fc v 0 c i c v e rt gtdt, (6) which differs from Eq. (2) by the same factors. Combining Eq. (5) and Eq. (6) shows that care is socially desirable when x p qed 1 Fc v 0 c i c v e rt gtdt x s *. (7) The right-hand side of Eq. (7) represents the highest cost injurer for whom it is socially desirable to take care under strict liability. Comparing Eq. (3) and Eq. (7) shows that x s *() x s () for any, implying that strict liability underdeters (Hylton, 1990). This is true because, as noted above, injurers ignore the damages imposed on victims who do not file suit (i.e., those with D c v ), and the litigation costs of victims who do file. We are now in a position to derive the optimal statute of limitations under strict liability. To do so, we first need to write down the expression for expected social costs. This is given by Eq. (5) weighted by the number of injurers who take care, H( x s ()), plus Eq. (6) weighted by the number of injurers who do not take care, 1 H( x s ()). The resulting expression, after rearranging, is given by SC s ped 1 Fc v 0 c i c v e rt gtdt H x s p q ED 1 Fc v 0 c i c v e rt gtdt x s xdh x. (8) The optimal statute of limitations is found by minimizing Eq. (8). The first-order condition, after rearranging, is given by 5 1 Fc v e r c i c v gp1 H x s qhx s xs x h s x s * x s. (9) 5 I assume (here and below) that the second-order condition for a minimum issatisfied.

T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 387 The left-hand side of Eq. (9) represents the marginal cost of an increase in. It captures the increase in the present value of expected litigation costs when is increased by one period, where p(1 H( x s )) qh( x s ) is the probability of an accident, and [1 F(c v )]g() is the number of new cases filed in the event of an accident. The right-hand side captures the marginal benefit of an increase in in terms of increased deterrence. The term x s / represents the increase in the threshold for care when is raised, which is weighted by h( x s ), the fraction of injurers with cost of care equal to x s. The bracketed term represents the net savings in social costs when one more injurer takes care, where this term is positive due to the general underdeterrence under strict liability. According to Eq. (9), the optimal statute length balances the increased litigation costs from a longer statute against the increased deterrence benefits. 4. Negligence Negligence differs from strict liability in that a victim will not recover against the injurer, even if she files in a timely manner, if the injurer took due care. Following Hylton (1990), we define due care by the Hand Rule, 6 which, in the current context, says that an injurer is negligent if he failed to take care and x (p q)e(d) x H ; that is, if his cost of care is less than the social benefit of care (x H ) in a world of zero litigation costs. 7 The court can apply this rule because we assumed that it can observe the injurer s care choice and cost of care after the fact. Victims, however, cannot observe injurers costs of care, nor can they observe whether a given injurer has taken care at the time that they make their filing decision. Thus, they can at best calculate the probability that an injurer will be found negligent, given that an accident has occurred. et this probability be w, which we will define below. Thus, victims for whom wd c v and t will file suit under negligence. The probability of a suit, given that an accident occurs, is therefore g(t)[1 F(c v /w)] for any t, and zero thereafter. Given the above, note that an injurer with x x H will never take care because he will never be judged negligent by the court. Thus, only injurers with x x H are potentially negligent in the sense that they will be judged negligent if they failed to take care and the victim files suit following an accident. A potentially negligent injurer who takes care incurs expected costs of x q1 Fc v /w 0 c i e rt gtdt. (10) Thus, he incurs only the cost of care plus his expected litigation costs, given that he will be found non-negligent at trial. In contrast, when a potentially negligent injurer does not take care, his expected costs are 6 See U.S. v. Carroll Towing, 159 F.2d 169 (2d Cir. 1947). 7 The results would be qualitatively the same if the due standard were based on the optimal standard in the presence of litigation costs. See note 9 infra.

388 T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 pg DdFD 1 Fc v cv/w /w0 c i e rt gtdt, (11) which includes expected liability plus litigation costs. Combining Eq. (10) and Eq. (11) gives the condition for the injurer to take care: x pgcv/w DdFD p q1 Fc v /w0 c i e rt gtdt x N, (12) where the right-hand side is the highest cost injurer who chooses to take care under negligence. We can now calculate the equilibrium value of w, which, recall, is the probability that a given injurer will be found negligent, given that an accident has occurred. Since victims correctly anticipate the likelihood of a negligent verdict, we can use Bayes Rule to calculate ph x H H x N w p1 H x N qhx N. (13) The numerator is the probability of an accident when the injurer does not take care times the probability that the injurer is both potentially negligent and fails to take care, while the denominator is the overall probability of an accident. Note that w is positive if and only if x H x N (), implying that there are some injurers who are potentially negligent and fail to take care. Although this need not be true in general, it must be true in a negligence equilibrium. 8 Assuming that an equilibrium exists, we can totally differentiate Eq. (12) and Eq. (13) and solve simultaneously to find the impact of varying on the equilibrium [Eq. (14)]: x N w 0, 0. (14) Intuitively, an increase in the statute of limitations increases the expected liability of injurers, thereby causing more injurers to take care ( x N () increases), but because more injurers take care, the probability that a given injurer will be found negligent by the court (w()) decreases. We now turn to social costs. When the injurer takes care, expected social costs are given by x qed 1 Fc v /w 0 c i c v e rt gtdt, (15) 8 The intuition is as follows. If all potentially negligent injurers take care, then w0 and no victims will file suit. But then injurers have no incentive to take care since they face no threat of a suit. For more details, see Ordover (1978) and Hylton (1990).

T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 389 which is equivalent to (5) except that c v /w replaces c v as the lowest value of D that results in a suit. When the injurer does not take care, expected social costs are ped 1 Fc v /w 0 c i c v e rt gtdt, (16) which similarly differs from Eq. (6). Combining Eq. (15) and Eq. (16) yields the condition for care to be socially desirable [Eq. (17)]: x p qed 1 Fc v /w 0 c i c v e rt gtdt x N *, (17) where x N *() is the highest cost injurer for whom care is socially desirable under negligence. Note that x N *() x H due to the absence of litigation costs from x H. Further, since x H x N () for existence of a negligence equilibrium, it follows that x N *() x N (), or that negligence, like strict liability, underdeters in equilibrium (Hylton, 1990). 9 As above, the optimal statute of limitations under negligence minimizes expected social costs, which is given by Eq. (15) multiplied by the fraction of injurers taking care, H( x N ()), plus Eq. (16) multiplied by the fraction not taking care, 1 H( x N ()). After rearranging, this becomes SC N ped 1 Fc v /w 0 c i c v e rt gtdt H x N p q x N ED 1 Fc v c i c v e /w0 rt gtdt 0 xdh x. (18) where, recall, w is a function of. Minimization of Eq. (18) yields the first-order condition 1 Fc v /we r c i c v gp1 H x N qhx N xn h x N x N * x N w fc v /wc v /w 2 c i c v e 0 rt gtdt p1 H x N qh x N. (19) 9 The results of the analysis would therefore be unaffected if the due standard applied by the court is set at x N * rather than at x H. However, use of x H greatly simplifies the model because x H is independent of, whereas x N * is not. Moreover, there is no reason to believe that courts use x N * rather than x H as the due standard of care.

390 T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 Note that the first two terms of this condition resemble the two terms in Eq. (9) and have the same interpretation. Specifically, the term on the left-hand side of Eq. (19) is the marginal cost of a longer statute length in terms of increased litigation costs, while the first term on the right-hand side is the marginal deterrence benefits of an increased statute length. As was true under strict liability, greater deterrence is socially desirable because in equilibrium, negligence underdeters (as captured by the fact that x N *() x N () 0). What is different here compared to strict liability is the second term on the right-hand side of Eq. (19), which is positive given that w/ 0. This term captures an additional marginal benefit of increasing the statute length under negligence in the form of fewer lawsuits being filed in each period up to t. Intuitively, an increase in lowers the probability that any given injurer will be judged negligent (given that w/ 0), thereby making lawsuits less profitable for victims. Note that this effect was absent under strict liability because that rule did not require victims to prove negligence by injurers as a condition for recovery. The extra marginal benefit term in Eq. (19) suggests that the optimal statute length should be longer under negligence as compared to strict liability. This result cannot be established definitively because a comparison of the corresponding terms in Eq. (9) and Eq. (19) for any is ambiguous. However, if these common effects are roughly offsetting, one would expect that the additional term in Eq. (19) would dominate, resulting in a longer statute length under negligence. 5. Applications of the analysis The foregoing analysis suggests that one might try to test the model by asking whether the statute of limitations is longer in areas of tort law governed by negligence as compared to areas governed by strict liability. There are several problems in testing the model in this way. First, statutes of limitations are costly to change and therefore may respond only sluggishly to changes in relative costs and benefits. Second, economic theory maintains that the legal rule is itself an endogenous variable that should respond to changes in some of the same variables that affect the statute of limitations (e.g., litigation costs). Third, most torts are grouped under a single statute of limitations. Thus, for example, the shift in produces liability law from negligence toward strict liability during the twentieth century may have had no effect on the general statute length for personal injury cases. Despite these problems, I offer some evidence that the statute of limitations does in fact differ depending on whether a given area of the law is governed by strict liability or negligence. This evidence takes the form of variation in the rules that determine when the statute begins to run. 10 10 I thank a referee for suggesting the second and third applications in this section.

T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 391 Statutes of repose for products liability As noted, one area of tort law that has shifted from negligence to strict liability is products liability. 11 In response to this change, many states enacted statutes of repose for products liability suits (Peacock, 1993). 12 In contrast to a statute of limitation, which begins to run at the time an accident occurs, a statute of repose begins to run at the time the product in question was sold (Martin, 1982: p. 749). Thus, a statute of repose puts a predictable upper bound on the length of time that a manufacturer is at risk of suit from the sale of a particular product. A statute of limitation alone provides no such bound because it allows suits for accidents that occur long after sale as long as they are filed in a timely manner after the accident. In the context of the model, it is easy to show that enactment of a statute of repose serves to reduce the expected number of suits that an injurer faces. In this sense, it is equivalent to a reduction in. To see this formally, suppose that consumers purchase a dangerous product at time t 0, and it causes an accident at time t 0 0, which varies across consumers based on differences in use and random factors. Victims then file suit after a delay of t as described in the above model (i.e., a victim of an accident at time t 0 files at t 0 t). Figure 1 shows all possible combinations of t 0 and t, where each point represents a potential lawsuit. In this amended model, the statute of limitations applies only to the delay in filing after occurrence of the accident. Thus, any suit with t is allowed to proceed, regardless of t 0. Graphically, the statute of limitations permits all suits to the left of in Figure 1 (i.e., areas A and B). In contrast, a statute of repose of length R applies to the length of time following sale of the product, and therefore allows only those suits for which t 0 t R. Thus, victims in area B of Figure 1 will no longer be allowed to proceed, leaving area A as the set of products liability cases that satisfy both the statute of limitations and the statute of repose. What this argument shows is that adding a statute of repose on top of a statute of limitations has the same effect as simply shortening the statute of limitations. Thus, the enactment of these statutes following the shift from negligence to strict liability for products liability suits seems to be consistent with the predictions of the model. The discovery rule for negligence Historically, a cause of action under negligence law began to run at the time that an injury actually occurred, or time t 0 (the damage rule ). Beginning in the area of medical malpractice, however, courts and legislatures began to replace this with the discovery rule, under which the statute does not begin to run until the negligent injury is, or should have been discovered. 13 This rule has now become the majority rule for negligence cases. The impact of the discovery rule is clearly to lengthen the statute of limitations by starting 11 This evolution has been gradual, but andes and Posner (1987: p. 307) roughly date the shift to Henningsen v. Bloomfield Motors, Inc., 32 N.J. 358, 161 A.2d 69 (1960). 12 Also see Martin (1982), who notes that as of 1982, as many as twenty-two states had enacted statutes of repose, ranging from six to fifteen years in length. Since then, however, many of these statutes have either been repealed or found unconstitutional (Warfel, 1991; Werber, 1995). 13 See Teeters v. Currey, 518 S.W.2d 512 (1974). Also see Keeton, et al. (1984: pp. 166-167).

392 T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 Fig. 1. The effect of a statute of repose. it at a later date relative to the time of the injury. It therefore works in the opposite direction of a statute of repose, which we saw above begins the statute prior to the time of the injury. (Indeed, Keeton, et al. (1984: pp. 166 167) observe that the enactment of statutes of repose was in part a response to the widening use of the discovery rule.) In combination, therefore, these two rules work in the predicted direction of effectively lengthening the statute of limitations for cases governed by negligence as compared to strict liability. Trespass versus nuisance The final application concerns the distinction between the torts of trespass and nuisance. Under trespass, the plaintiff is entitled to strictly enforce his or her right to exclusive possession of a piece of property. In contrast, the plaintiff can only assert a claim under nuisance law if the harm is both substantial and unreasonable, where the latter is based on a balancing of the gravity of the harm and the utility of the conduct (Keeton, et al., 1984: p. 630). Thus, trespass is governed by strict liability and nuisance by a negligence standard (andes and Posner, 1987: p. 49).

T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 393 It follows from the theory that the statute of limitations should be shorter for trespass as compared to nuisance, and this in fact appears to be the case. Specifically, under trespass, the statute of limitations begins to run from the time of unlawful entry 14 and without regard to harm (Keeton, et al., 1984: p. 70), whereas under nuisance, the statutory period does not begin to run until some injury has been sustained. 15 Once again, the law seems to conform to the predictions of the theory. 6. Conclusion This paper has developed a formal model of statutes of limitations for tort suits based on the trade-off between deterrence and litigation costs. While a longer statute enhances deterrence by confronting injurers with more lawsuits, it increases litigation costs. The optimal statute length balances these effects at the margin. A notable feature of the model is that, in contrast to conventional arguments in favor of statutes of limitations, it does not rely on arguments about stale evidence and legal error as a basis for imposing a finite statute length. 16 A key prediction of the model is that the optimal statute length appears to be longer under a negligence rule as compared to a strict liability rule. The reason is that, when the statute is lengthened, it increases incentives for care (deterrence), thereby making it harder for plaintiffs to prove negligence at trial. Thus, fewer cases are filed at any point in time, which lowers expected litigation costs. Since this benefit partially offsets the extra litigation costs incurred by lengthening the statute, the optimal statute is longer. The paper concluded by suggesting that this prediction is consistent with variations in actual statutes of limitations. We first argued that the enactment of statutes of repose in the 1970s, which effectively shortened the statute of limitations for products liability suits, was a response to the shift from negligence to strict products liability. We next argued that adoption of the rule of discovery effectively lengthened the statute of limitations for negligence suits by delaying the start of the statutory period until the plaintiff discovers (or should have discovered) her injuries, rather than when she actually sustains them. Finally, we argued that the statute of limitations is longer for nuisance as compared to trespass actions, reflecting the reliance on negligence principles under the former and strict liability under the latter. Acknowledgment I acknowledge the helpful comments of an anonymous referee. 14 See Am Jur 2d, Trespass, 200 (1986). 15 See Am Jur 2d, Nuisance, 308 (1986). 16 Though these factors are not inconsistent with the model, their omission makes it more parsimonious.

394 T.J. Miceli / International Review of aw and Economics 20 (2000) 383 394 References Baker, M. & Miceli, T. (2000) Statutes of limitations for accident cases: theory and evidence. Research in aw and Economics, 19, 47 67. Cooter. R. & Ulen, T. (1988). aw and Economics, New York: Harper-Collins. Epstein, R. (1986). Past and future: the temporal dimension in the law of property. Washington Univ. aw Quarterly, 64, 667 722. Hylton, K. (1990). The Influence of litigation costs on deterrence under strict liability and under negligence. International Review of aw and Economics, 10, 161 171. Keeton, W., Dobbs, D., Keeton, R. & Owen, D. (1984). Prosser and Keeton on Torts, 5th Ed., St. Paul, MN: West Publishing Co. andes, W. & Posner, R. (1987). The Economic Structure of Tort aw, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press. Martin, M. (1982). A statute of repose for product liability claims. Fordham aw Review, 50, 745 780. Ordover, J. (1978). Costly litigation in a model of single activity accidents. Journal of egal Studies, 7, 243 261. Peacock, M. (1993). An equitable approach to products liability statutes of repose. Northern Illinois Univ. aw Review, 14, 223 249. Ross, K. & Goelz, D. (1985). The availability of prejudgment interest in tort actions. Journal of Products iability, 8, 79 87. Warfel, W. (1991). Tolling of statutes of limitations in long-tail product liability litigation: the transformation of the tort system into a compensation system. Journal of Products iability, 13, 205 230. Werber, S. (1995). The constitutional dimension of a national products liability statute of repose. Villanova aw Review, 40, 985 1056.