Optimal Credit Use With Uncertain Income



Similar documents
An Improved Measure of Risk Aversion

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

Chapter 4 Inflation and Interest Rates in the Consumption-Savings Framework

Quantifying the Economic Benefits of Personal Financial Planning

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Redistributive Taxation and Personal Bankruptcy in US States

How to Forecast Your Revenue and Sales A Step by Step Guide to Revenue and Sales Forecasting in a Small Business

Chapter Objectives. Chapter 6. Short Term Credit Management. Major Topics. Reasons for Using Credit. How to Get Credit. Disadvantages of Using Credit

The Determinants Of Outstanding Balances Among Credit Card Revolvers

Capital Budgeting OVERVIEW

Is a 30-Year Mortgage Preferable to a 15-Year Mortgage?

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

Dynamics of Small Open Economies

Seniors Money Ireland Limited t/a Seniors Money 60plus Loan Seniors Money is a joint venture company equally owned by IFG Group plc and Sentinel

Female labor supply as insurance against idiosyncratic risk

APPENDIX. Interest Concepts of Future and Present Value. Concept of Interest TIME VALUE OF MONEY BASIC INTEREST CONCEPTS

9. Short-Term Liquidity Analysis. Operating Cash Conversion Cycle

All you need to know about the. Seniors Money Lifetime Loan. Information for you, your family and your advisers

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Resilience, Debt, and Net Worth: Has Resilience Increased with Higher Debt-to-Income Ratios? *

Money and Public Finance

The impact of loan rates on direct real estate investment holding period return

Monetary Neutrality, Home Mortgages, and the Phillips Curve

14.74 Lecture 16: Savings and Insurance: how villagers deal with risk

Global Financial Management

Cash in advance model

13. SAVINGS RATE: WHY IS IT DECLINING?

For individuals who have a

The central question: Does the bankruptcy process make sure that firms in bankruptcy are inefficient, and that inefficient firms end up in bankruptcy?

Does Financial Sophistication Matter in Retirement Preparedness of U.S Households? Evidence from the 2010 Survey of Consumer Finances

1.1 Introduction. Chapter 1: Feasibility Studies: An Overview

How To Understand The Theory Of Finance

Preparation course MSc Business & Econonomics- Macroeconomics: Introduction & Concepts

Student Loan Market Trends Is College Worth It. Presenter: Kelly Savoie, Director Business Development April 2016

DOES HOUSEHOLD DEBT HELP FORECAST CONSUMER SPENDING? Robert G. Murphy Department of Economics Boston College Chestnut Hill, MA 02467

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Consumption and Savings Decisions: A Two-Period Setting

AGENDA ITEM 12. Action requested:

Economics 202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory 1. Syllabus Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2013

Exam 1 Review. 3. A severe recession is called a(n): A) depression. B) deflation. C) exogenous event. D) market-clearing assumption.

DRN. Debt Solutions Scenarios Pack

Assessing the Effect of Self-Control on Retirement Preparedness of U.S. Households

RETIREMENT SAVINGS OF AMERICAN HOUSEHOLDS: ASSET LEVELS AND ADEQUACY

Higher Education Finance & Student Loans Scheme Options for Romania

[03.03] Guidelines for the User Cost Method to calculate rents for owner occupied housing. International Comparison Program

The Effect on Housing Prices of Changes in Mortgage Rates and Taxes

VALUE %. $100, (=MATURITY

Credit Spending And Its Implications for Recent U.S. Economic Growth

A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory. By Student E XXXXXXX

Structure and Function of Capital Markets. Structure and Function of Capital Markets Major Topics

Indexed and Non-Indexed Insurance

Economic Effects of a California Minimum Wage Increase: An Econometric Scoring of AB 10

The Economics of Consumer Credit

National Standards for Personal Finance Education - Jump $tart Correlation to Virtual Business - Personal Finance

SOA/CAS Course 2 - Interest Theory, Economics, and Finance

RETIREMENT PLANS AND SAVING DECISIONS: THE ROLE OF INFORMATION AND EDUCATION. Robert L. Clark Professor North Carolina State University

TEACHING AGGREGATE PLANNING IN AN OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT COURSE

The Effect of Housing on Portfolio Choice. July 2009

Life insurance with great cash values at affordable prices.

Understanding the Student Loan Explosion. Implications for students and their families. Sponsored by:

Debt Freedom Plan. John and Mary Sample

IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET

Reforming the Tax System Lecture II: The Taxation of Savings. December 2015 Richard Blundell University College London

Balancing Passion and Practicality:

Verðtryggð Lán. Dr. Jacky Mallett

Saving and Life Insurance Holdings at Boston University A Unique Case Study

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

How Much Should I Save for Retirement? By Massi De Santis, PhD and Marlena Lee, PhD Research

Part 7. Capital Budgeting

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Home Buyer Self Pre-Qualification Workbook

IFSA Guidance Note No

Development Discussion Papers

Basic Concept of Time Value of Money

Choice of Discount Rate

Sahra Wagenknecht. Hie Limits of Choice. Saving Decisions and Basic Needs in Developed Countries. Campus Verlag Frankfurt/New York

14 ARITHMETIC OF FINANCE

Mortgage & Equity Release Guide

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

What are the key current issues shaping equity release by older home owners?

CREDIT RISK MANAGEMENT

Debt Recovery Strategy for Housing Benefit Overpayments.

A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

CHAPTER 5 Review... Page 1

3. a. If all money is held as currency, then the money supply is equal to the monetary base. The money supply will be $1,000.

What You Need to Know Before Considering a. Reverse Mortgage. Fair Housing Legal Support Center & Clinic

The Demand for Financial Planning Services 1

Loan Lessons. The Low-Down on Loans, Interest and Keeping Your Head Above Water. Course Objectives Learn About:

Concept 5. Inflation What is inflation? Inflation means prices are rising and the purchasing power of the dollar is declining.

NATIONAL SURVEY OF HOME EQUITY LOANS

Effects on pensioners from leaving the EU

Standby Reverse Mortgages: A Risk Management Tool for Retirement Distributions

Self-help Guide. Motherwell & Wishaw Citizens Advice Bureau. If you live in the Motherwell, Wishaw. or Shotts areas, You can contact:

Mathematics Crosswalk Common Core State Standards aligned to Personal Finance Standards

Is College Education Worthwhile?

Transcription:

Optimal Credit Use With Uncertain Income Xiaojing Jessie Fan 1, Yu-Chun Regina Chang 2 and Sherman Hanna 3 A two period analysis of optimal credit use for consumers facing uncertain income is developed to give insight into factors related to rational credit use. Extensions of the model to more realistic situations are described. KEY WORDS: credit, bankruptcy Economic investment theory models developed by Fisher (1930) and Hirshleifer (1970) suggest consumers may increase their utility through judicious selection of debts and assets (Herendeen 1975). A consumer expecting a sustained growth in real income might borrow to smooth consumption over the life cycle. Young consumers, especially students, may find borrowing rational. The availability of consumer credit makes it possible for families and individuals to have immediate consumption of goods and services. However, the dramatic growth of consumer installment debt and use of credit cards during the past two decades (Eastwood 1985, Canner, 1986) has led financial planners and educators to express alarm regarding whether consumers are becoming debt-ridden and overextended. The number of non-business bankruptcies in the United States increased from 312,914 in 1981 to 811,493 in 1991 (Administrative Office of the U.S. Courts, 1991). Clearly there is a need for more understanding of use and overuse of credit. The purpose of this article is to describe a model of optimal decision-making for credit use with uncertain future income. The analysis is original, but based on theoretical and empirical analysis in the economics literature. Three selected cases are studied. Extensions of the analysis to more realistic situations are described. Although analysis is confined to credit for current consumption, the results may be useful for financial counselors and educators, as well as for insight into empirical patterns of credit use. 1 Xiaojing Jessie Fan, Ph.D. student, Family Resource Management Department, The Ohio State University. 2 Yu-Chun Regina Chang, Ph.D. student, Family Resource Management Department, The Ohio State University. 3 Sherman Hanna, Professor and Chair, Family Resource Management Department, The Ohio State University, 1787 Neil Avenue, Columbus, Ohio 43210, (614) 292-4389.

Financial Counseling & Planning, Volume 3, 1992 In this article, consumers are assumed to use credit only to "smooth out" current consumption for life cycle purposes. There is no investment in durable goods, saving for retirement, or possibility of loan default. Loans are assumed to be repaid in one lump sum repayment during the second period. Despite these simplifications, this article provides useful original insights into rational credit use. A consumer who is confident that income will increase substantially will rationally take on more credit than will an otherwise similar consumer who does not think that a substantial income increase is likely. Financial educators and counselors should encourage consumers to realistically evaluate the prospects for increases in real income. If an increase in real income is not probable, credit use is not optimal. Hypotheses for empirical studies of credit use should take into account the insights provided by this article. Review of Literature There has been extensive discussion in the literature of optimal borrowingsaving and consumption behavior under uncertainty either in the context of infinite time horizon or in the two-period or multiperiod intertemporal models (eg., Leland 1968, Levhari and Srinivasan 1969, Sandmo 1970, Mirman 1971, Dreze and Modigliani 1972, Hey 1979, Sibley 1975). Uncertainty is generally considered in terms of uncertain lifetime, uncertain interest rate, or uncertain income. (For additional discussion of the literature, see Chang, Fan & Hanna, 1992.) Despite a number of analyses of credit use in the economics literature, there are almost no explicit discussions of economic models in papers with empirical analyses of household credit use. This article provides suggestions for constructing hypotheses for household credit use based on a model of optimal credit use for current consumption. Description of Method The two-period model of optimal credit use under uncertain income is based on the assumption that a consumer should maximize expected utility from consumption. The consumer decides how much to spend out of this year's income. Next year's income is uncertain, so the choice of the optimal consumption level this year is not obvious. (The Appendix presents the model rigorously.) 126

Discussion of Selected Case Studies Optimal Credit Use with Uncertain Income Three situations of income increase a consumer might face are analyzed: (1) Salary Increase. There is either a real increase of 1%, e.g., the nominal income growth rate is equal to 6% with an inflation rate of 5% (see Appendix), or real income remains constant, e.g., nominal income increases 5%.; (2) Good Promotion. The consumer changes jobs or gets a good promotion (e.g., is promoted from an assistant professor to associate professor) with a nominal income growth rate of 12% and a real growth rate of 6.7%, or real income remains constant; and (3) Additional Job. For a household, if a member (e.g., wife) is expected to enter or reenter the labor force market in the second year, and a substantial nominal income increase of 50% and a real growth rate of 43% is expected, or real income remains constant. These three selected cases are studied using the above model with the help of a computer program. Generally speaking, the higher the expected income growth rate, the more the consumer will borrow for a given probability; and the higher the probability of income increase, the more the consumer will borrow for a given real income growth rate. Figure 1 shows the patterns of optimal borrowing-saving for these three cases. For a nominal income growth rate of 6%, borrowing is never optimal, even if the consumer is certain that the income increase will occur. Note that this analysis does not apply to borrowing for a durable good such as a car. Note 127

Financial Counseling & Planning, Volume 3, 1992 Figure 1 Optimal Saving (Borrowing) as Percent of Year 1 Income, by Probability That Real Income Increases, for Nominal Income Increases of 6%, 12% and 50%, Inflation=5%. also that some consumers might rationally borrow for current consumption even if they did not expect an increase in income, if they did not consider the costs of default very high. For a nominal income increase of 12%, borrowing is not optimal unless the probability that there will be an increase in real income is at least 39%. If the probability that income will increase is 50%, optimal saving would be - $68 (i.e., optimal borrowing = $68) for a consumer with year 1 income of $20,000, so that the savings/income ratio = -0.3%. If a 12% nominal increase is certain, optimal borrowing would be $411 for a consumer with year 1 income of $20,000, so that the savings/income ratio = -2.1%. For a nominal income increase of 50%, borrowing is not optimal unless the probability that real income increases is at least 15%. If the probability that income increases is 50%, optimal borrowing would be $711 for a consumer 128

Optimal Credit Use with Uncertain Income with a year 1 income of $20,000, so that the savings/income ratio = -3.6%. If a 50% nominal increase is certain, optimal borrowing would be $3,757, so that the savings/income ratio = -18.8%. Discussion The rate of increase in real income and the probability that real income increases are the most important variables in determining optimal credit use for current consumption. Analyses not presented in this article show that the real interest rate faced by the consumer and the consumer's preferences are much less important in determining optimal credit use. Durable Goods The analysis presented assumes that all spending is for current consumption, which may be realistic for a consumer who rents a home and leases automobiles. Use of credit for some types of durable goods, such as automobiles, and kitchen/laundry appliances may be rational even if real income is not expected to increase. However, for decisions about how expensive the durable good should be beyond minimum standards (e.g., reliable transportation), the analysis presented in this article may give some insights into how such choices should be made. Extensions to More Than Two Periods If the analysis is extended to three periods, but the assumption is made that the real income level during the third year is whatever the real income level is during the second year, then optimal credit for the first year is higher than the corresponding level shown in this article for the two period model. Allowing for changes between year two and year three introduces a much higher degree of complexity, and has not been addressed by the authors of this article. Allowing for Decreases in Real Income If there is a possibility that real income will decrease, optimal saving may be positive. For instance, if real income will either remain constant or decrease, and both states of the world are equally likely, the consumer should save some money from year one income in order to prevent too much of a decrease in year 2 consumption. If, however, the probability that real income decreases is small, optimal saving may be approximately zero. Extensions to More Than Two States of the World 129

Financial Counseling & Planning, Volume 3, 1992 If there are more than two states of the world, analysis of optimal behavior is complex. For consumers with a very small chance of a large decrease in real income, and approximately equal chances of constant real income or a substantial increase in real income, the optimal saving (credit) pattern will be approximately the same as the patterns presented in this article for the two states of the world model. For some consumers, a small possibility of a substantial decrease in income could be dealt with through help from relatives and the social safety net. Consumers could also implicitly assume that decreases in real income could be dealt with by default. Taking Default into Account The model used in this article assumes that the possibility of default and/or bankruptcy is ignored. The results described are based on the assumption that the consumer must repay the loan in full. There are obvious costs of default and various forms of bankruptcy. If these costs were low, even more consumers would become overextended. It is difficult to specify the monetary value of the costs of default, etc., but given the increasing number of bankruptcies, it is plausible that a priori, borrowing even if bankruptcy is possible is rational for some consumers. It is also plausible that many consumers may underestimate the true costs of bankruptcy, and therefore take too much risk with credit use. Most consumers who use credit face at least a small risk of default. The analysis presented in this article provides a starting point to development of a realistic evaluation of rational credit use. Conclusions Optimal credit use with uncertain income is described for three scenarios in a two period model. The analysis provides insights into conditions for which credit use may be optimal, although the limitations of the model should be carefully considered before generalization. In a situation where real income can safely be assumed to either remain constant or increase, credit use depends crucially upon the probability that real income increases. This relationship is most evident for a substantial income increase, where the optimal loan is about twice as high for a 100% chance of an increase as for an 80% chance (Figure 1). Hypotheses for empirical analyses of credit use should take the patterns found in this article into account. The growth rate of real income and the probability that real income increases are the crucial variables in the rational use of credit for current consumption. Researchers designing surveys about credit use should attempt to obtain consumers expectations about income 130

Optimal Credit Use with Uncertain Income increases or decreases and the likelihood of increases. Researchers using existing datasets without such information should try to use proxy variables for the income increases and probabilities, such as occupation, age and location. Financial counselors and educators should encourage consumers to realistically evaluate the chances of income increases. Credit use for investment for durable goods was not considered in this article. For some types of investment in durable goods (e.g., laundry equipment) credit use may be rational even if real income is not expected to increase. Savings goals such as retirement or saving for a down payment for a home were not considered. If a consumer has such goals, credit use is less likely to be rational. Finally, a possible rational basis for consumers becoming overextended can be seen in one of the scenarios. If a consumer thinks that there is a high probability that there will be a substantial increase in income (e.g., p>95%), then if income does not increase, default and possibly bankruptcy may seem tempting. Appendix Equation (1): Maximize T = U(C1) + p*u(c2) + (1-p)*U(C2a) The constraints are: Equation (2): C1 = I - S Equation (3): C2 = (1+g)*I + (1+r)*S Equation (4): C2a = I + (1+r)*S Variables: T = Total two-period utility I = First period income C1 = First period consumption C2 = Second period consumption with income increase of g C2a = Second period consumption without income increase S = First period saving (Negative S means borrowing) p = Probability that income increases g = Growth rate in real income. The real growth rate = (1+nominal growth rate)/ (1+inflation rate)- 1.0. Example: nominal growth rate=6% or 0.06. Inflation rate = 5% or 0.05. Real growth rate = (1.06/1.05)-1 or 0.95%. In text, this was rounded to 1%. r = Real interest rate (which may be different for saving or borrowing) r=(1+nominal interest rate)/(1+inflation rate)-1. A constant elasticity utility function which is time separable additively is used for intertemporal consumption study: 131

Financial Counseling & Planning, Volume 3, 1992 Equation (5): U = C^{(1-x)} over {(1-x)} where x is the inverse of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption. The consumer's relative risk aversion also is x. To concentrate our study on the relationship between g, p and S, we set x=6 based on extensive literature review and computer simulation (Hanna, 1988; Hanna, Chang & Fan, 1991). The real interest rate r is assumed to be 14.1% for borrowing. This is equivalent to a nominal rate of 19.8% (the typical rate for the largest credit card issuers) if inflation is 5%. It is assumed that the consumer can obtain an interest rate of 1% for saving (e.g., average nominal saving account interest rate of 7.1% with a 5% inflation rate and marginal tax rate of 15%). The results of the analyses are very similar for other plausible values of these parameters. A closed analytical solution could not be obtained, so simulations were used to find the level of saving (or borrowing) which maximized expected utility. References Administrative Office of the U.S. Courts (1991). 1991 Annual Report of the Director, Judicial Business of the U.S. Courts. Canner, G. (1986). Changes in consumer holding and use of credit cards, 1970-1986. Journal of Retail Banking, 10(1), Spring, 13-24. Chang, Y., Fan, X. and Hanna, S. (1992). Relative risk aversion and optimal credit use with uncertain income, American Council on Consumer Interest Proceedings (pp. 14-22). Columbia, Missouri: American Council on Consumer Interest. Dreze, J. and Modigliani, F. (1972). Consumption decision under uncertainty, Journal of Economic Theory, 5(3), 308-335. Eastwood, D. (1985). A re-examination of consumer credit growth, in Karen P. Schnittgrund (Ed.), American Council on Consumer Interests Proceedings (pp.169-174). Columbia, Missouri: American Council on Consumer Interests. Fisher, I.(1930). The Theory of Interest, New York: Macmillian Co. Hanna, S. (1988). Risk aversion and optimal insurance deductibles. American Council on Consumer Interests Proceedings (pp. 141-147). Columbia, Missouri: American Council on Consumer Interest. 132

Optimal Credit Use with Uncertain Income Hanna, S., Chang, Y. and Fan, X. (1991). Prescribing lifecycle savings patterns for households. Paper presented at Academy of Financial Services meeting, Chicago, Illinois, Oct. 1991. (Complete paper available from Hanna.) Herendeen, J. (1975). The role of credit in the theory of the household, The Journal of Consumer Affair, 8, 157-181. Hey, J. (1979). Uncertainty in Microeconomics, New York: New York University Press. Hirshleifer, J. (1970). Investment, Interest and Capital, Englewood Cliffs: New Jersey, Prentice Hall. Leland, H. (1968). Saving and uncertainty: the precautionary demand for saving, Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXXXII(3), 465-473. Levhari, D. and Srinivasan, T. (1969). Optimal savings under uncertainty Review of Economic Studies, 36(106), 153-163. Mirman, L. (1971). Uncertainty and optimal consumption decisions, Econometrica, 39(1), 179-185. Sandmo, A. (1970). The effect of uncertainty on saving decisions, Review of Economic Studies, 37(111), 353-360. Sibley, D.S. (1975). Permanent and transitory income effects in a model of optimal consumption with wage income uncertainty, Journal of Economic Theory, 11(1), 68-82. 133

134 Financial Counseling & Planning, Volume 3, 1992