Do Dictator Games Measure Altruism?



Similar documents
GENDER BASED PRESCRIPTIONS Evidence for altruism

On the Interpretation of Giving in Dictator Games

Abstract. The finding of this thesis should contribute to the charity organizations to modify the fundraising strategy to promote the donors to give.

Peer Effects on Charitable Giving: How Can Social Ties Increase Charitable Giving Through Cognitive Dissonance?

Three Theories of Individual Behavioral Decision-Making

Shareholder Theory (Martin Friedman)

Book Review of Rosenhouse, The Monty Hall Problem. Leslie Burkholder 1

Milgram Activities. Everyone was paid $4.50 and told that they would receive this even if they quit during the study.

Dictator Games: A Meta Study

Is a monetary incentive a feasible solution to some of the UK s most pressing health concerns?

9.916 Altruism and Cooperation

Eye Images Increase Charitable Donations: Evidence From an Opportunistic Field Experiment in a Supermarket

Reply to French and Genone Symposium on Naïve Realism and Illusion The Brains Blog, January Boyd Millar

A. Introducing Social Psychology. Introduction

Charity as a Signal of Trustworthiness

Social Survey Methods and Data Collection

Reminders, payment method and charitable giving: evidence from an online experiment

Behavioral Game Theory on Online Social Networks: Colonel Blotto is on Facebook

Effects of Watching Eyes and Norm Cues on Charitable Giving in a Surreptitious Behavioral Experiment

KEY PERFORMANCE INDICATORS (KPIS): DEFINE AND ACT

Group Membership, Team Preferences, and Expectations

Overview. Triplett (1898) Social Influence - 1. PSYCHOLOGY 305 / 305G Social Psychology. Research in Social Psychology 2005

Principles and standards in Independent Advocacy organisations and groups

Main Point: God gives each of us gifts and abilities. We should use them to glorify Him.

Prospect Theory Ayelet Gneezy & Nicholas Epley

Do you know how your grants are being used?

Critical Analysis o Understanding Ethical Failures in Leadership

Charitable Giving. James Andreoni UCSD and NBER. A. Abigail Payne McMaster University

Favorable Interpretations of Ambiguity and Unstable Preferences for Fairness

Sustaining cooperation in laboratory public goods experiments: a selective survey of the literature

Framing and Free Riding: Emotional Responses and Punishment in Social Dilemma Games

Chapter 9 Overall Outline

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 15: Repeated Games and Cooperation

Why economics needs ethical theory by John Broome, University of Oxford

Explain and critically assess the Singer Solution to Global Poverty

THE MORAL AGENDA OF CITIZENSHIP EDUCATION

Section 1: What is Sociology and How Can I Use It?

Teaching Fellow: Siva Anantham, We ll get a lot of our readings from

Specific learning outcomes (Course: Introduction to experimental research)

STEP 5: Giving Feedback

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 10: Extensive Games: Critiques and Extensions

ANOTHER GENERATION OF GENERAL EDUCATION

Our Code is for all of us

Corporate Fundraising Pack

The role of the line in talent management

HOW TO WRITE A LABORATORY REPORT

So You d Like a Sport Psychology Consultant to Work With Your Team? Three Key Lessons Learned from Olympic Teams

David P. Schmidt, Ph.D. Fairfield University

Chapter 2 Quantitative, Qualitative, and Mixed Research

Ethical Theories ETHICAL THEORIES. presents NOTES:

IN CHARGE 1 GRAMMAR / Definite and Indefinite Articles

MGT 162: NEGOTIATION Winter 2015

Trustworthiness and competitive altruism can also solve the tragedy of the commons $

Honesty, Integrity and Ethics in Public Relations. In the quote above, Mitchell Friedman (n.d.), identifies a core principle of public

psychology the science of psychology CHAPTER third edition Psychology, Third Edition Saundra K. Ciccarelli J. Noland White

Killing And Letting Die

Ethical Conduct in Youth Work

30 Gift economy Arjo Klamer

Double Degree Master Jena - Trento Learning agreement form

Toronto School of Theology Guidelines for the Preparation and Ethics Review of Doctor of Ministry Thesis Projects Involving Human Subjects

User research for information architecture projects

Financial incentives, personal information and dropout rate in online studies

Jesus Came to Earth to Destroy the Works of the Devil JOHN PIPER Why Christmas Happened Jesus Incarnation and Our Regeneration The Great Love of God

Emile Durkheim: Suicide as Social Fact Leslie-Ann Bolden, Michela Bowman, Sarah Kaufman & Danielle Lindemann

Modern Science vs. Ancient Philosophy. Daniel Gilbert s theory of happiness as presented in his book, Stumbling on Happiness,

Augmented reality enhances learning at Manchester School of Medicine

Theories of consumer behavior and methodology applied in research of products with H&N claims

Reputation management: Building trust among virtual strangers

The Maryland Guide to Creating Matching Gift Programs

Satir Transformational Systemic Therapy (in Brief)

On Nature and Prosocial Behavior. Prosocial behavior inclinations to share, care, cooperate, and assist is critical

Leadership Training to Retain USA Swimming Officials (Leadership Clinic Material)

The Negative Impact of Rewards and Ineffective Praise on Student Motivation

TIME AND MONEY. The Role of Volunteering in Philanthropy RESEARCH INSIGHTS. Key findings. Among Fidelity Charitable donors in 2014:

News Writing: Lead Paragraphs

2. Argument Structure & Standardization

Ethics in International Business

Excusing Selfishness in Charitable Giving: The Role of Risk

Sports Performance. Credit value: 10 Guided learning hours: 60. Aim and purpose. Unit introduction

Four Pillars of Sales Success. Sales Training for Large Organisations

LESSON TITLE: A Story about Investing. THEME: We should share the love of Jesus! SCRIPTURE: Luke 19:11-27 CHILDREN S DEVOTIONS FOR THE WEEK OF:

100 Ways To Improve Your Sales Success. Some Great Tips To Boost Your Sales

Iceberg Theory of Leadership & Teamwork

Information Sharing, Big Data and the FRS. Rob Wilson, Jyoti Mishra and James Cornford

INTELLECTUAL APPROACHES

HOW TO CHANGE NEGATIVE THINKING

Objections to Friedman s Shareholder/Stockholder Theory

Exploiting moral wiggle room: experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness

Who can benefit from charities?

OBSERVATION FORM. Early Years Service OBSERVING LEARNING, PLAYING AND INTERACTING IN THE EYFS

Free Report. My Top 10 Tips to Betting Like a Pro With Zero Risk

Sweetening the Till: The Use of Candy to Increase Restaurant Tipping. in (2002) Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 32,

1. An overview of local authority communications p3. 2. New National Reputation Project p3. 3. Key aims of the Corporate Communications Strategy p4

Session 2 The Particle Nature of Matter: Solids, Liquids, and Gases

Getting to the Bottom of Values

accel team jobs depend on it

Introducing Social Psychology

Review of Marketing Science

FILMS AND BOOKS ADAPTATIONS

Transcription:

CBESS Discussion Paper 11-15 Do Dictator Games Measure Altruism? by Daniel John Zizzo* * School of Economics and Centre for Behavioural and Experimental Social Science, University of East Anglia Abstract This note paper has been prepared for inclusion as a book chapter in a forthcoming Handbook on the Economics of Philanthropy, Reciprocity and Social Enterprise edited by Luigino Bruni and Stefano Zamagni and to be published by Edward Elgar. Centre for Behavioural and Experimental Social Science University of East Anglia Norwich Research Park Norwich NR4 7TJ United Kingdom www.uea.ac.uk/ssf/cbess

Do Dictator Games Measure Altruism? Daniel John Zizzo* School of Economics and CBESS University of East Anglia Norwich NR4 7TJ United Kingdom d.zizzo@uea.ac.uk August 2011 This note paper has been prepared for inclusion as a book chapter in a forthcoming Handbook on the Economics of Philanthropy, Reciprocity and Social Enterprise edited by Luigino Bruni and Stefano Zamagni and to be published by Edward Elgar. * Phone: +44-1603-593668; fax: +44-1603-456259. In writing this paper, I have benefited from discussions on dictator games with participants to presentations in Erfurt, Heidelberg, Jena, Munich and the XIV Summer School on Economics and Philosophy at the University of the Basque Country, San Sebastian. This paper also benefits from an ongoing collaboration with Piers Fleming, which has been funded by the Nuffield Foundation and by the University of East Anglia. The usual disclaimer applies.

1. Introduction As communism once haunted Europe according to the Communist Manifesto, so does the dictator game haunt the hallways, if not of Europe, of the standard consensus in behavioral and experimental research as developed in the last twenty years or so. Grand claims on the significance of this game for altruism and for the relevance of a wide array of social factors in studying dictator games have been made and developed in what has been a successful cottage industry of academic research in economics; at least, successful in terms of its ability in getting published (e.g., for recent Econometrica and European Economic Review examples, see Andreoni and Berheim, 2009, and Servatka, 2009, respectively). This note paper considers briefly whether dictator games are a good tool to measure altruism. The answer is negative: behavior in dictator games is seriously confounded by what I shall label experimenter demand effects (Zizzo, 2010). Section 2 briefly defines dictator games and reviews some of its purported enduring appeal. Section 3 criticizes dictator games as a measure of altruism and concludes by considering whether a role for dictator games can still be found that may be of relevance for the economics of philanthropy. 2. The Appeal of Dictator Games Dictator games were originally thought of as an elegant way to identify the altruistic component of behavior in the most standard ultimatum games. In the standard ultimatum game (Güth et al., 1982; Camerer, 2003), a first mover receives an amount of money (say, x dollars) and needs to decide how much to offer to give to a second mover (say, y dollars), with him or her retaining the rest (x y dollars). The second mover then decides whether to accept the offer, in which case he or she gets y and the proposer gets x y, or not, in which case neither player gets anything. Different motivations (e.g., not only altruism but also envy and fear of envy) can underlie behavior in ultimatum games, and, in an attempt to identify the role of altruistic preferences by decomposing a key aspect of it, the dictator game was born 2

(Forsythe et al., 1994). In the dictator game, the first mover (the dictator ) decides again how much money to give the receiver (x) but this time the split he or she decides gets implemented automatically, without the second mover being able to decide whether to accept it or not. As such, any giving should only be attributable to altruism or so is the usual claim. More recently, the dictator game has been used in combination with trust game settings to putatively identify the role of altruism in those games. The dictator game has been immensely popular as a way to measure altruism and to study social factors affecting pro-social behavior (see, e.g., Engel, 2011 and Camerer, 2003). There are three reasons for this. First, it is a deceptively simple game, and economists like simple things because they give the promise of the greatest interpretability, even when, as will be shown in section 2, the promise is not fulfilled. Second, it provides seemingly very good value for money: the very reason the terminology dictator game is a misnomer for it is not really a game but an individual choice problem also implies that it is possible to collect a lot of independent observations for comparatively little money. Third, seemingly intriguing results can be obtained comparatively easily, and academic journals like to publish statistically significant results. Fourth, once the literature got kick-started for all of these reasons, it has been a case in which everyone keeps producing dictator game experiments because everyone else has, and has produced papers to show for it. None of these are good reasons to keep investing limited time and resources on dictator game experiments if dictator games cannot deliver a good measurement of altruism or other such pro-social motivations. And, as discussed next, it turns out they do not. 2. Do Dictator Games Work? In coming to the experimental laboratory, or answering questions to the experimenter in the field, a subject needs to make sense of the decision environment to identify what he or she is expected to do. Problems of experimental control arising from this can be classified under 3

the label of experimenter demand effects (Zizzo, 2010; EDE for short) and have been, at least in part, previously analyzed in the psychological literature (e.g., Orne, 1962, and Rosnow and Rosenthal, 1997). They come into two guises. Purely cognitive EDE derive from the cognitive dimension of identifying the task at hand and behaving accordingly, by employing cues about what constitutes behavior that is appropriate to the task. In addition to the cognitive dimension, social EDE reflect the perceived social pressure that the experimenter, as an authority, explicitly or implicitly puts on a subject through instructions and cues; in the light of this, the subject forms beliefs about the experimental objectives and his or her actions can be played out in the direction most congruent to such objectives. Now imagine that you come to the lab and you are given a random bunch of money and asked to consider giving some to a random stranger. This is an unfamiliar environment (as Smith, 2010, p. 9 puts it in describing this situation, the Gods must be crazy! ) with an inbuilt obvious cognitive demand to give some money and to follow whatever other cue can be read by the decision environment. This is precisely what happens. Significant amounts of money are given to strangers in a way that is rarely done in the real world (Schram, 2005; Bardsley, 2008), and dictator games are sensitive to cues whatever they are in a way that other more natural economic settings are not, such as changes in deservingness (e.g., Ruffle, 1998), the availability of a picture of the recipient (Burnham, 2003), other information provided on the recipients (Branas Garza, 2006) and awareness of observation (Haley and Fessler, 2005). Behavior changes dramatically as a result: e.g., only around 10% of the subjects gave money in treatments by Hoffman et al. (1994, 1996) and Koch and Normann (2008), but over 95% did so in a treatment by Aguiar et al. (2008) and Branas Garza (2006). By their unusual nature, dictator games are typically done only once, although withintreatment manipulations are sometimes made (as in Andreoni and Miller, 2002) which lead to 4

further questions as this may, e.g., induce more behavior which is more consistent or cuesensitive across tasks (as discussed in Zizzo, 2010). Direct evidence for the impact of EDE on dictator game behavior has come in experimental work by List (2007), Bardsley (2008) and Zizzo and Fleming (2011). For example, Zizzo and Fleming (2011) find that behavior in a dictator game is connected to a standard questionnaire measure of sensitivity to social pressure (Stöber, 2001). They also find that, when a dictator game and a symmetrical back to back money burning game in which the first mover can simply destroy money of the second mover are played, there is a positive rather than negative relationship between giving and destroying, which is not compatible with a preference based explanation of giving but is predicted by an experimenter demand explanation. There has been a recent attempt to reconfigure the objective of dictator game experiments as one aimed to identify social norms (Guala and Mittone, 2010) rather than measuring altruism or social preferences. However, this objective would predict actions that work in the same direction as the EDE confound, and, as the identified social norms would normally be claimed to generalize beyond the dictator game environment, it is not a satisfactory solution for reinterpreting dictator game results. Overall, one can forgive Oechssler (2010, p. 66) for recently imploring please, not another dictator game!. And yet there may be still some scope for some experiments employing dictator games. Obviously, if the focus of the experiment is to look at experimenter demand and associated vertical social pressure, and the sensitivity of subjects to it, the dictator game can be a suitable game. In the context of the economics of philanthropy, if the focus of the experiment is to look at how social pressure (e.g., by the means of phone calls to ask for charitable giving) practically affects giving, it may be possible to use the experimenter demand effect as a way to mirror in the lab what is otherwise possible in the 5

real world. This may be considered an example of what Zizzo (2010) labels the magnifying glass argument against EDE: an EDE would be a tool used in the same way in which a scientist may use a magnifying glass or a microscope; specifically, to better, if artificially, identify effects of comparable social pressure on inducing greater charitable giving which otherwise may not be observable. Fong and Luttmer (2011) and Reinstein and Reiner (2011) provide examples of dictator game experiments that may receive some justification in this way. References Aguiar, F., Branas-Garza, P. and Millar, L.M. (2008), Moral distance in dictator games, Judgment and Decision Making, 3, 344-354. Andreoni, J. and Bernheim, B.D. (2009), Social image and the 50-50 norm: A theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects, Econometrica, 77, 1607-1636. Andreoni, J. and Miller, J. (2002), Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism, Econometrica, 70, 737-753. Bardsley, N. (2008), Dictator game giving: Altruism or artefact? Experimental Economics, 11, 122-133. Branas-Garza, P. (2006), Poverty in dictator games: Awakening solidarity, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 60, 306-320. Burnham, T.C. (2003), Engineering altruism: A theoretical and experimental investigation of anonymity and gift giving, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 50, 133-144. Camerer, C.F. (2003), Behavioral game theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Engel, C. (2011), Dictator games: A meta study. Experimental Economics, in press. 6

Fong, C.M. and Luttmer, E.F.P. (2011), Do fairness and race matter in generosity? Evidence from a nationally representative charity experiment, Journal of Public Economics, 95, 372-394. Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J.L., Savin, N.E. and Sefton, M. (1994), Fairness in simple bargaining experiments, Games and Economic Behavior, 6, 347-369. Guala, F. and Mittone, L., (2010), Paradigmatic experiments: The dictator game, Journal of Socio-Economics, 39, 578-584. Güth, W., Schmittberger, R. and Schwarze, B. (1982), An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, 367-388. Haley, K. J. and Fessler, D.M.T. (2005), Nobody s watching? Subtle cues affecting generosity in an anonymous economic game, Evolution and Human Behavior, 26, 245-256. Hoffman, E., K.A. McCabe and Smith, V.L. (1996), On expectations and the monetary stakes in ultimatum games, International Journal of Game Theory, 25, 289-302. Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K. and Smith, V.L. (1994), Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games, Games and Economic Behavior, 7, 346-380. Koch, A. and Normann, H.-T. (2008), Giving in dictator games: Regard for others or regard by others?, Southern Economic Journal, 75, 223-231. List, J.A. (2007), On the interpretation of giving in dictator games, Journal of Political Economy, 115, 482-493. Oechssler, J. (2010), Searching beyond the lamppost: Let s focus on economically relevant questions, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 73, 65-67. Orne, M.T. (1962), On the social psychology of the psychological experiment: With particular reference to demand characteristics and their implications, American Psychologist, 17, 776-783. 7

Reinstein, D. and Riener, G. (2011), Reputation and influence in charitable giving: An experiment, Theory and Decision, in press. Rosnow, R.L. and Rosenthal, R. (1997), People Studying People: Artifacts and Ethics in Behavioral Research. New York: Freeman. Ruffle, B. (1998), More is better but fair is fair: Tipping in dictator and ultimatum games, Games and Economic Behavior, 23, 247-265. Schram, A. (2005), Artificiality: The tension between internal and external validity in economic experiments, Journal of Economic Methodology, 12, 225-237. Servatka, M. (2009), Separating reputation, social influence, and identification effects in a dictator game, European Economic Review, 53, 197-209. Smith, V.L. (2010), Theory and experiments: What are the questions?, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 73, 3-15. Zizzo, D.J. (2010), Experimenter demand effects in economic experiments, Experimental Economics, 13, 75-98. Zizzo, D.J. and Fleming, P. (2011), Can experimental measures of sensitivity to social pressure predict public good contribution?, Economics Letters, 111, 239-242. 8