Standard Essential Patents (SEPs): Costs And Benefits Of Broad Application



Similar documents
Valuing Standard Essential Patents in the Knowledge Economy:

CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2013 (Special Issue)

IPR Policy as Strategy ISBN: December The Battle to Define the Meaning of FRAND

Department of Justice

Observations from the NAS Committee Study on IP Management in SSOs. Keith Maskus Toulouse Conference May 16, 2013

FRAND Commitment - The case against improper antitrust intervention

Present Situation of IP Disputes in Japan

International Patent Litigation and Jurisdiction. Study of Hypothetical Question 1 Under the Hague Draft Convention and Japanese Laws

Economic Analysis and Merger Investigations

Copyfights: The Future of Intellectual Property in the Information Age

January 8, The U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division (DOJ), and the U.S. Patent &

U.S. Litigation (Strategic Preparations and Statistics)

Campaign Information Campaign Name Committee to Elect Les Ponomarchuk Superior Court Judge #10

Legal FAQ: Introduction to Patent Litigation

Norway Advokatfirmaet Grette

GREIF, INC. ANTITRUST/COMPETITION COMPLIANCE POLICY RIGID INDUSTRIAL PACKAGING & SERVICES* FLEXIBLE PRODUCTS & SERVICES

Antitrust Risks in Standard-Setting Organizations

The Dynamics of Disclosure Claims

Case 2:15-cv Document 1 Filed 01/14/15 Page 1 of 14 PageID #: 1

HOW SUSMAN GODFREY REDUCES RISK Columbia Law School January 30, I. The Shrinking Universe of Good Plaintiffs Cases

The Advantages of Annual Patent Patenting

The Benefits of Patent Settlements: New Survey Evidence on Factors Affecting Generic Drug Investment

Bid Protests: When, Where, Why, and Can You Win?

PRACTICAL ADVICE ON THE MOST EFFECTIVE WAY TO SETTLE YOUR CASE WITH THE GOVERNMENT

Representing Yourself In Employment Arbitration: An Employee s Guide

Costa Rica Negotiated M&A Guide

Big Risks and Disadvantages of Arbitration vs. Litigation

We believe it is important to distinguish between white hat and black hat patent monetization:

IN THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY HIGH COURT OF JAPAN. Defendant.

Market Definition Does Not Yield Evidence of Class-Wide Impact

EuroDev BV. How to overcome the barriers in international business

Comments of Verizon Communications on the Draft Convention on Jurisdiction and Foreign Judgments in Civil and Commercial Matters

Qihoo v. Tencent: economic analysis of the first Chinese Supreme Court decision under Anti-Monopoly Law

What is Online Dispute Resolution? Why use Online Dispute Resolution? What are the different types of Online Dispute Resolution?

Recognition. Awards & Top Trademark Law Firm World Trademark Review 1000, U.S. Trademark Case of the Year: In re Bose

LEGAL ISSUES IN WOUND CARE

Efficient alternative dispute resolution (ADR) for intellectual property disputes

Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting. Novak druce centre insights No. 8

IP Litigation in Europe and in Germany

Sample Arbitration Clauses with Comments

Antitrust Law and Patent Pools - A Program Analysis

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB ISSN

Testimony of Peter Allgeier President Coalition of Services Industries (CSI)

Protection of Employees Rights in Insolvency

COST AND FEE ALLOCATION IN CIVIL PROCEDURE

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY CREDENTIALS. Services Summary Brooks Consulting s intellectual property offerings fall into three main categories:

Federal Court Denies Motorola s Motion to Dismiss Apple s Appeal over SEPs

PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS OF DENNIS CARLTON REGARDING PRICE CAPS FOR NEW gtld INTERNET REGISTRIES. March 2009

Dollars For Genes: Revenue Generation by the California Institute for Regenerative Medicine

Testimony of. J. Douglas Richards Partner, Cohen Milstein Sellers & Toll, PLLC

Research Ideas in Antitrust and Consumer Protection: A View from the FTC

Case4:12-cv KAW Document2-1 Filed06/25/12 Page1 of 7 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA, OAKLAND DIVISION

Jury Duty and Selection

Admissibility of Social Science Evidence in Law

AE RISK REVIEW A PUBLICATION FOR DESIGN PROFESSIONALS YOUR RISK MANAGEMENT CONNECTION. Prevailing Opinions on Prevailing Party Contract Clauses

A Citizen s Guide to the Criminal Justice System: From Arraignment to Appeal

If you have been sued as a defendant in a civil case...keep reading.

Antitrust Division CONSOLIDATION IN THE BANKING INDUSTRY: AN ANTITRUST PERSPECTIVE. Address by

CURRICULUM VITAE. Edward H. Pappas

The Divorce Process. What to Expect. Cassandra P. Hicks

Investing in Invention TM

UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT. Case Nos and CON-WAY TRANSPORTATION SERVICES, INC. Appellant No.

Mineral rights ownership what is it and why is it so unique in the USA?

Case5:11-cv LHK Document52 Filed05/18/11 Page1 of 6

Alex Okuliar. Profile. Practices. Education. Clerkships. Partner Antitrust & Competition. Washington, D.C. (202)

Locating Practice Materials

Government Contracts. Practice Overview

The What to Expect Series FINRA s Dispute Resolution Process 1

The Enforceability of Mediated Settlement Agreements. By: Thomas J. Smith The Law Offices of Thomas J. Smith San Antonio, Texas

U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE/FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION WORKSHOP AND COMMENT PROCEEDING ON PATENT ASSERTION ENTITIES

Family Law Dispute Resolution Options

January 9, The Self Help Legal Center. Southern Illinois University School Of Law Carbondale, IL (618)

DISPUTE RESOLUTION TERMS

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT WESTERN DISTRICT OF WASHINGTON AT SEATTLE ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) )

The Importance of Clearing Trademarks

Winning The Settlement Keys to Negotiation Strategy

Choosing a divorce lawyer

THE ROLE OF AN EXPERT WITNESS

ETSI Guidelines for Antitrust Compliance Version adopted by Board #81 on 27 January 2011

Advice Note. An overview of civil proceedings in England. Introduction

CANADA PROVINCE OF QUEBEC ENFORCEMENT OF FOREIGN JUDGMENT

LTE Standard Essential Patents Now and in the Future

The purpose of this report is to present research findings on the nature and type of writing that occurs in composing legal business contracts.

Executive summary and overview of the national report for Denmark

patent enforcement, inaccessible. In other words, in some cases, nobody wins. However, there are alternatives to these costly practices.

Lessons From Omnicare Settlement In 'Swapping' Cases

Intellectual Property Consulting

What Is Small Claims Court? What Types Of Cases Can Be Filed In Small Claims Court? Should I Sue? Do I Have the Defendant s Address?

Defining relevant market(s) product (parties overlapping products and close substitutes) and geographic (local, regional, national or global?

cost of taking on an interference proceeding under the old first-to-invent system, which cost around $2 million.

How To Defend Yourself In A Tax Court

Case 1:16-cv Document 1 Filed 06/10/16 Page 1 of 8

GAO DHS IMMIGRATION ATTORNEYS. Workload Analysis and Workforce Planning Efforts Lack Data and Documentation

Inspections and Access to Evidence in

questions fees payable under the new process?

IN THE SUPREME COURT OF BRITISH COLUMBIA

Antitrust Issues for Associations

Resolving IP and Technology Disputes Through WIPO ADR. Getting back to business

ANALYSIS OF COMPETITION LAW AND ENFORCEMENT ACROSS COUNTRIES:

BLAKE INGLISH, CPA, ABV, CFE, CFF, CGMA Managing Director, Intellectual Property

Transcription:

Standard Essential Patents (SEPs): Costs And Benefits Of Broad Application Articles Standard Essential Patents (SEPs): Costs And Benefits Of Broad Application has been updated. Thursday, February 20, 2014 07:50 Cornerstone Research Matthew R. Lynde The Editor interviews Matthew R. Lynde, Vice President of Cornerstone Research. Editor: Please tell us about your background. Lynde: I am an economist with a doctorate from UC Berkeley with over 30 years experience working for the federal government, in academia, and in consulting. I am now a Vice President at Cornerstone Research, where we specialize in economic and Matthew R. Lynde financial consulting, including the support of expert testimony. I consult on intellectual property portfolio valuation and have served as an expert witness around the world, including in intellectual property infringement matters and in high profile cases involving standard essential patents (SEPs). Prior to this, I was a partner at PricewaterhouseCoopers. Before that, I was a professor of economics at the City University of New York. My background in economics is related to policy; my undergraduate background is in electrical engineering at UC Berkeley. Editor: Please define SEPs. What is the standard setting organization (SSO) that identifies them? Lynde: There are actually many standard setting organizations. Many of these SSOs have subcommittees that set particular standards. These subcommittees require contributing engineers to disclose whether they have patents or patent applications that may be essential to the standard, i.e., you would be infringing the patent if you implemented the standard. Only the courts can determine if a patent is actually essential, and since that is an extensive process, few make it all the way to a determination of legal essentiality. Editor: Why is it important for in house counsel and patent managers to understand that this state of the law is in flux and should be followed closely? Lynde: There has been a rapid evolution of the case law relative to damages in the federal courts, the ITC, and internationally. Supreme Court decisions will have dramatic impacts on http://www.metrocorpcounsel.com/articles/27639/standard-essential-patents-seps-costs-and-benefits-broad-application 1/5

patent values and business strategies focused on protecting intellectual property. Editor: What industries are most commonly associated with SEPs? What industries may adopt them in the future? Lynde: These are industries where technical interoperability is key for commercial success telecommunications, computing related industries, and others. Such products are useful to the public because they must agree with each other, which is made possible by compliance with the same protocol. Economists recognized long ago that industries where so called network effects were important can benefit from some cooperation between suppliers to agree on a common standard. This cooperation is pro competitive and benefits consumers, such as having one wall socket voltage, or all telephones able to interpret communications codes. The public hugely benefits from this standardization. The Department of Justice (DOJ)/Federal Trade Commission (FTC) IP licensing guidelines set forth such pro competitive conditions, allowing competitors to contribute complementary assets to a standard. Editor: Would you explain the rules by which SEPs are licensed? Lynde: There is no one set of rules, but one policy common to all SSO agreements is that you promise to license your standard related technology to all comers on FRAND (fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory) or RAND (reasonable and nondiscriminatory) terms. The purpose is to prevent hold up that is, ex post opportunistic behavior extracting more value than the intrinsic value of the patented technology thereby inappropriately taking advantage of the fact of standardization per se. These terms are, however, never really defined in the typical SSO agreement. It s easier to agree if the terms are vague. So after the fact we are left trying to determine what reasonable means. Parties may differ on this. One approach economists have taken is to consider comparable patent pool rates. As these, ideally, can indicate approximate multilateral ex ante negotiated rates, they can give objective measures of value without hold up (ex ante value takes care of that, as only intrinsic value is bid before a technology is adopted into a standard), and accounting for stacking (everyone contributing needs to agree that the total royalty stack makes sense commercially). Another objective approach the courts have taken is apportioning value based on the smallest saleable unit that embodies the invention (Cornell v. HP); while this is susceptible to arguments about downstream complementary value of the technology, it can be useful in appropriate circumstances. Both these approaches have been used in recent landmark RAND cases. Editor: Has the meaning of the RAND or FRAND commitment been clearly defined? Lynde: I do not think so, and it may never be, as SSOs can t be very explicit. Any ex post determinations are just that after the fact. Antitrust authorities in the U.S. have been talking to many of the world s SSOs, asking them to be clearer about what they mean by it. As economists, we are clear we do not want these organizations to facilitate any form of anticompetitive collusion or downstream opportunism that would not benefit the public. But as a matter of economics, we only have a theoretical framework of pro competitive, RANDcompliant rates; in practice, what can be used as a benchmark? Any actual bilateral agreement, whether reached in settlement of litigation or not, may be tainted with hold up. http://www.metrocorpcounsel.com/articles/27639/standard-essential-patents-seps-costs-and-benefits-broad-application 2/5

As an empirical matter, we can t measure that. Theoretically, bargaining theory suggests that patent pools might provide an appropriate benchmark. But the literature points out that practical pool arrangements have a number of imperfections that make their adoption as a benchmark difficult in certain circumstances, even if those arrangements might apply well in others. Various court decisions are beginning to sketch out what RAND means, e.g., Microsoft v. Motorola, now on appeal; Ericsson v. D Link; and Innovatio v. Cisco. My testimony on Microsoft was the basis of a RAND ruling based on pool benchmarks; the court in Ericsson adjusted post jury verdict rates to a similar range; and the court in Innovatio adjusted smallest saleable unit metrics to a similar range for the same standard (802.11). Courts are just beginning to rule on this, and appeals are in process. Editor: Do SEPs have economic value materially different from the economic value of ordinary patents? Lynde: It's hard to generalize because to have a patent in a standard is itself highly valuable. Many ideas are of little value unless incorporated into a widespread interoperability standard. For patents of average value, the effect on economic value could go either way. On the one hand, the standard might involve a large number of units, so that the aggregate value could be very large even if the per unit value is small. On the other hand, the RAND promise, which attaches to the SEP, is an encumbrance in the sense that a claim for value should not reach the level of hold up i.e., claiming part of the value of the standard itself as opposed to the intrinsic value of the patent at least as far as economic policy is concerned. The extraordinary intrinsic value of some rare patents for which there is truly no substitute at the standard formation stage would remain but hard to distinguish from hold up value. Editor: From an economist s perspective, would it be useful to impose a fee scale on the amount owing in royalties by the appropriate SSO? Lynde: Economists are leery of that. We don t want to risk any collusion in downstream excessive price coordination. Even if the IP license guidelines carve out a safe harbor, it's a delicate issue except for royalty free, which all standards allow as de facto RAND compliant. Even though some SSOs allow parties to disclose what non zero royalties they plan to charge, most parties do not wish to disclose what they consider reasonable, which is not conducive to promoting the proper level of coordination and cooperation required for a RANDcompliant royalty ex post facto. Hence the practical problems we face in RAND licensing. Editor: Why would a company want to join an SSO if it could ask for large royalties on its own? Lynde: If a company is not participating in the SSO, it is unable to discuss the technical merits of the standard and whether its technology should be part of it. Most engineers definitely prefer to be part of the process. If you are waiting and hoping that the standard goes in a particular direction, in all likelihood you will be out of luck for receiving royalties. If you do participate and your technology is adopted, even if the rate is modest on a per unit basis, the numbers of units sold may be so huge as to be extremely beneficial. In the case of the 802.11 Wi Fi standard, for example, the count next year should be in excess of 350 billion units. http://www.metrocorpcounsel.com/articles/27639/standard-essential-patents-seps-costs-and-benefits-broad-application 3/5

Editor: Please discuss recent case law on this issue. Lynde: For many years, in the area of SEPs we have not had any objective benchmarks to define the meaning of RAND compliant reasonable, and in my opinion a lot of mischief has followed from that ambiguity. But recently, we have had several cases that address the issue forthrightly. In Microsoft v. Motorola, a landmark case, Judge Robart wrote a bench opinion on what a RAND compliant range of royalties would be for two sets of SEPs. Critical pieces of evidence he considered were comparable patent pool arrangements that I had set out in my testimony. A jury found that Motorola s initial demands of over $4 billion per year were so much greater than the RAND range that they constituted breaches of contract with regard to the relevant SSOs. A more equitable solution would be a couple of million dollars per year. In another important recent case, Innovatio v. Cisco et al. (where I also testified), Judge Holderman determined a RAND compliant rate based on RAND specific evidence, as opposed to ignoring the RAND obligation as in a regular patent damages determination of reasonable royalties. Plaintiff s counsel in this case sent demand letters to Starbucks and mom and pop coffee shops, alike, for infringing their Wi Fi patents. This, along with other similar cases, has almost every state attorney general, and Congress, up in arms about the issue of NPEs. Major OEMs intervened, and the plaintiff claimed a reasonable royalty of over $1 billion for their Wi Fi SEPs. The judge ruled instead in favor of pennies per unit, RAND royalties consistent with testimony of the defendant s economists. Editor: From an economic expert s point of view, what are the challenges in litigating internationally, since there are many different standards being set in Europe and Asia? Lynde: Most standards of interest are international. The ITU in Geneva sets many worldwide telecommunications standards. Actually, most standards have international implications. The challenge is twofold. The venue may be geographically in the U.S., Europe, or Asia, but the damages scope is limited to the country of the patents in suit; and all parties always want a universal resolution. Litigation is usually in the U.S., occasionally in Germany and Tokyo District Court. International arbitration is more frequent if the venue is not a U.S. court, but the same question of international impact is relevant for ultimate settlement. I have testified by translated written submission in Tokyo District Court. My French has come in handy in international arbitrations in Paris and Geneva. Editor: Please tell our readers about your recent conference with the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research (SIEPR). Lynde: Cornerstone Research cosponsored a conference with SIEPR because we are seeing interest from our clients at the intersection of intellectual property and competition policy. Attendees included key players from Washington and some of the most prominent economists at Berkeley and Stanford addressing this intersection. Mark Lemley of Stanford Law, Richard Taffet of Bingham McCutchen, and I had a lively discussion on competition and standard essential patents. Aviv Nevo, Deputy Assistant Attorney General for Economic Analysis, discussed his perspective on merger policy. Economists Hal Varian of Berkeley and Susan Athey of Stanford spoke about platform competition issues. Tim Bresnahan of Stanford moderated a panel of in house counsel discussing international enforcement issues faced by companies like Cisco, HP, and Google. Renata Hesse, Deputy Assistant Attorney General for http://www.metrocorpcounsel.com/articles/27639/standard-essential-patents-seps-costs-and-benefits-broad-application 4/5

Criminal and Civil Operations at the Antitrust Division at the DOJ, delivered the closing remarks. The discussions explored topics facing high technology and other industries in the areas of intellectual property and antitrust. The views expressed in this article are solely those of the authors, who are responsible for the content, and do not necessarily represent the views of Cornerstone Research. Please email the interviewee at mlynde@cornerstone.com with questions about this interview. Disclaimer Privacy The Metropolitan Corporate Counsel, Inc. 1180 Wychwood Road, Mountainside, NJ 07092. Contact us at info@metrocorpcounsel.com 2014The Metropolitan Corporate Counsel, Inc. All rights reserved. http://www.metrocorpcounsel.com/articles/27639/standard-essential-patents-seps-costs-and-benefits-broad-application 5/5