1-6-1, Nishiwaseda, Shinjuku-ku, Tokyo 169-8050 JAPAN

Similar documents
DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

12.1 Introduction The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

Problem Set 5. a) In what sense is money neutral? Why is monetary policy useful if money is neutral?

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes

Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs. and. Economic Activity

Supply and Demand in the Market for Money: The Liquidity Preference Framework

The Impact of Surplus Liquidity

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3

Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates When Short-Term Rates Are Close to Zero

Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data

Monetary Policy and Long-term Interest Rates

Kiwi drivers the New Zealand dollar experience AN 2012/ 02

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge

Chronic deflation in Japan 1

Jim Gatheral Scholarship Report. Training in Cointegrated VAR Modeling at the. University of Copenhagen, Denmark

RESEARCH DISCUSSION PAPER

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics

TEMPORAL CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN STOCK MARKET CAPITALIZATION, TRADE OPENNESS AND REAL GDP: EVIDENCE FROM THAILAND

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER PROBLEMS WITHOUT ASTERISKS

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits

The Liquidity Trap and U.S. Interest Rates in the 1930s

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth

Bank of Japan Review. Global correlation among government bond markets and Japanese banks' market risk. February Introduction 2012-E-1

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy

Analyzing the Effect of Change in Money Supply on Stock Prices

The comovement of US and German bond markets

International linkages of Japanese bond markets: an empirical analysis

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Term Structure of Interest Rates

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: The Romer-Romer Method on the Austrian case

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators

Economics 101 Multiple Choice Questions for Final Examination Miller

International Money and Banking: 12. The Term Structure of Interest Rates

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP?

Fiscal and Monetary Policy in Australia: an SVAR Model

Does global liquidity help to forecast US inflation?

QUIZ Principles of Macroeconomics May 19, I. True/False (30 points)

Does Global Liquidity Help to Forecast U.S. Inflation?

A layperson s guide to monetary policy

Bank Loans and the Capital Shock

Monetary Policy and the Economy. Goals of Monetary Policy

Relationship among crude oil prices, share prices and exchange rates

Chapter 12: Aggregate Supply and Phillips Curve

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

Modelling Monetary Policy of the Bank of Russia

WORKING PAPER CENTRAL BANK OF ICELAND. A Variance Decomposition of Index-Linked Bond Returns. No. 57. By Francis Breedon

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

What Drives Natural Gas Prices?

Haruhiko Kuroda: Quantitative and qualitative monetary easing

Empirical Evidence on the Aggregate Effects of Anticipated and. Unanticipated U.S. Tax Policy Shocks

Problem Set #4: Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand Econ 100B: Intermediate Macroeconomics

How Well Does the IS-LM Model Fit in a Developing Economy: The Case of India

Agenda. Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy, Part 1. Exchange Rates. Exchange Rates.

PASS-THROUGH OF EXCHANGE RATES AND IMPORT PRICES TO DOMESTIC INFLATION IN SOME INDUSTRIALISED ECONOMIES

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

in Canada 2 how changes in the Bank of Canada s target 3 why many central banks have adopted 4 how the Bank of Canada s policy of inflation

10/7/2013. Chapter 9: Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Facts about the business cycle. Unemployment. Okun s Law Y Y

The use of projections and forecasts in the ECB s monetary policy

Working Papers. Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market. Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek. No. 2/2012 (68)

Understanding the Effects of a Shock to Government Purchases*

Monetary Policy Bank of Canada

Strategy Document 1/03

Inflation in the GCC: An Analysis of the Causes and Implications for Monetary Policy. Economic Note No. 5

2.If actual investment is greater than planned investment, inventories increase more than planned. TRUE.

Definitions and terminology

Dynamic Relationship between Interest Rate and Stock Price: Empirical Evidence from Colombo Stock Exchange

The global financial crisis which began in the

1. a. Interest-bearing checking accounts make holding money more attractive. This increases the demand for money.

2.5 Monetary policy: Interest rates

Crimea and Punishment: The Impact of Sanctions on Russian and European Economies

ANALYSIS OF EUROPEAN, AMERICAN AND JAPANESE GOVERNMENT BOND YIELDS

Development of the government bond market and public debt management in Singapore

Micro and macroeconomic determinants of net interest margin in the Albanian banking system ( )

An Introduction into the SVAR Methodology: Identification, Interpretation and Limitations of SVAR models

GUIDELINES for the Single State Monetary Policy in 2016 and for 2017 and Moscow

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

Examining the Relationship between ETFS and Their Underlying Assets in Indian Capital Market

Static and dynamic analysis: basic concepts and examples

During the past six years of slow economic growth, economists

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

PROJECTION OF THE FISCAL BALANCE AND PUBLIC DEBT ( ) - SUMMARY

Import Prices and Inflation

The Central Tendency: A Second Factor in Bond Yields

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

In response to continuing weakness in economic activity, the Federal

Practiced Questions. Chapter 20

Chapter Title: The Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Price Shocks: Why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s?

ON THE DEATH OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE William A. Niskanen

Minimum LM Unit Root Test with One Structural Break. Junsoo Lee Department of Economics University of Alabama

The Canadian dollar as a commodity currency: Has the relationship changed?* Monica Mow Supervisor: Dr. Graham Voss

Transcription:

Waseda Economics Working Paper Series Monetary Policy and the Yield Curve in Japan: VAR Approach with Sign Restrictions NAKAZONO, Yoshiyuki Graduate School of Economics Waseda University Graduate School of Economics Waseda University 1-6-1, Nishiwaseda, Shinjuku-ku, Tokyo 169-85 JAPAN

Waseda Economics Working Paper Series Monetary Policy and the Yield Curve in Japan: VAR Approach with Sign Restrictions NAKAZONO, Yoshiyuki Graduate School of Economics Waseda University Number 11-4 March 212 Graduate School of Economics Waseda University 1-6-1, Nishiwaseda, Shinjuku-ku, Tokyo 169-85 JAPAN * All rights are reserved by the author(s). Please do not quote or reproduce any part of the paper without permission of the author(s).

Monetary Policy and the Yield Curve in Japan: VAR Approach with Sign Restrictions Yoshiyuki Nakazono January 3, 212 Abstract We examine the effects of a monetary policy shock to the yield curve in Japan and investigate whether there are any differences of the effects between before and after the introduction of the zero interest rate policy (ZIRP) conducted by the Bank of Japan in February 1999 through VAR with sign restrictions. Our first finding is that long-term interest rates are significantly affected by the monetary policy shock. This result is different from that in Evans and Marshall (1998) which show that long-term rates are virtually unaffected by the shock. Second, the effects of the monetary policy shock on the yield curve are long-lasted for about 1 year. Finally, the responses of the yield curve depend on the samples; a surprise tightening in monetary policy lowers the interest rates before the introduction of the ZIRP, while the shock shifts the yield curve upward during the ZIRP period. JEL Classification: C32; E43; E44; E52 Keywords: monetary policy; term structure of interest rates; VAR with sign restrictions. Waseda University and Research Fellow of the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (E-mail: ynakazono@fuji.waseda.jp). The author thanks Ippei Fujiwara for insightful discussions, especially at the onset of this research project. Thanks also go to Keichiro Kobayashi, Akira Sadahiro, Etsuro Shioji, and Kenichiro Tamaki for discussions and comments. This work was supported by a Grant-in-Aid for JSPS Fellows (No. 11569). 1

1 Introduction The relationship between monetary policy and term structure of interest rate is not clear. There are two distinct maintained hypotheses about monetary policy shocks to nominal yield curve. One of them is the liquidity effect hypothesis maintaining that a surprise tightening in monetary policy increases short-term nominal interest rates, and decreases output, prices, and monetary aggregates. The liquidity effect hypothesis reflects the consensus view about how monetary policy affects the economy in the United States 1. The other hypothesis is the costly price adjustment hypothesis maintaining that a contractionary monetary policy shock decreases interest rates, money supply, output and prices. This hypothesis is supported by the implications of monopolistic competition as in Rotemberg (1996), Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999), Ireland (1997), and Aiyagari and Braun (1998). Braun and Shioji (26) find that Japanese data from October 1987 through May 1999 are more consistent with the costly price adjustment hypothesis. Because we have no consensus on how monetary policy affects the yield curve and which hypothesis is better, we are interested in how monetary policy contributes to movements in the yield curve. In order to clarify the relationship between monetary policy and the term structure of interest rates in Japan, we examine the effects of a monetary policy shock to the yield curve. Our motivation in this paper is related to the following three questions. The first question is whether monetary policy can affect the Japanese yield curve, especially longer-term interest rates. Evans and Marshall (1998) show that a contractionary monetary policy shock has the effects on the shorter-term interest rates using the data in the United States. Moreover, Evans and Marshall (1998) report that long-term rates are virtually unaffected by the shock. As for the Japanese data, Braun and Shioji (26) find that a surprise tightening in monetary policy lowers interest rates, although they investigate only the short- and medium-term rates. We do not have enough empirical studies about the effects of a monetary policy shock to interest rates for now, especially longer-term rates. 1 See Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999). 2

The second question is how long the effects of monetary policy can last and how large they are. Evans and Marshall (1998) show that the effects on the shorter-term interest rates have only a transitory effect and are short-lived: the effects of the shock last only for about 6 months. Braun and Shioji (26) find that under the costly price adjustment hypothesis, a surprise tightening in monetary policy lowers interest rates by up to 2 basis points and it pushes down the yield curve below zero significantly for about 1 year. However, neither Evans and Marshall (1998) nor Braun and Shioji (26) investigate the contribution of the shock to longer-term interest rates like 1-year bond. The last question is whether the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates in Japan affects the effects of the shock to interest rates or not. In February 1999, the Bank of Japan introduced the unprecedented monetary policy called as zero interest rates policy (ZIRP), which keeps the overnight call rate almost near zero percent. There are a lot of arguments about the effects of the ZIRP, but what we want to investigate is whether the transmission mechanism of monetary policy to the yield curve has changed or not since the Bank of Japan started to conduct the ZIRP. Braun and Shioji (26) imply that the mechanism of the monetary policy shock to interest rates follows the costly price adjustment hypothesis before the ZIRP started. However, we do not know what has happened during the ZIRP period and whether the transmission mechanism may have changed since the Bank of Japan introduced the unprecedented policy in February 1999. In order to answer the three questions, we use the vector autoregression (VAR) with sign restrictions and find the following three points. First, the monetary policy shock has the significant effects on the interest rates: the shock affects not only the short- and mediumterm interest rates but also the long-term interest rates during both of the pre-zirp and the ZIRP period. Second, we show that the effects of the monetary policy shock are longerlasted for 1 year than as those of Evans and Marshall (1998) and stronger on the shorterterm interest rates than on the longer-term interest rates. Finally, we find that the divided samples, that is, before and after the introduction of the ZIRP, bring us the contrast results; a surprise tightening in monetary policy lowers all of the yield significantly during the pre- 3

ZIRP period, however, the shock shifts the yield curve upward significantly during the ZIRP period. Our main results are supported by the robustness check. In sum, our findings contrast to past studies and interesting. First, Monetary policy unambiguously has some impacts on long-term interest rates. Our estimation results show that not only short-term but also long-term interest rates are significantly affected by the monetary policy shock although literature reports that long-term rates are virtually unaffected. Evans and Marshall (1998) conclude that a contractionary policy shock induces a transitory response in short-term interest rates, with a smaller effect on medium-term rates and almost no effect on long-term rates in the case of the United States. Second, we reveal that the surprise tightening in monetary policy has the longer-lasted effects on all of the yields for about 1 year and the stronger effects especially on the shortand medium-term interest rates. Finally, the transmission mechanism of monetary policy to the yield curve has changed since the Bank of Japan started to conduct the ZIRP. In normal economic situation, our estimation results are consistent with the costly price adjustment hypothesis. In fact, our results show the decline of the yield curve in response to the monetary policy shock during the pre-zirp period as is the case with Braun and Shioji (26). However, once the Japanese economy has fallen into deflation, the responses of the interest rates to the shock are completely different from the costly price adjustment hypothesis: after the introduction of the unprecedented policy in 1999, the responses of nominal yield curve to the unexpected tightening in monetary policy follow the liquidity effect hypothesis rather than the costly price adjustment hypothesis. This paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we provide the VAR framework with sign restrictions to examine the relationship between monetary policy and the term structure of interest rate. In Section 3, we show the estimation results of our model and in Section 4, we discuss the estimation results. Section 5 concludes. 4

2 Estimation 2.1 Data A set of monthly data consists of seven endogenous and five exogenous variables. The endogenous variables include industrial production (ip), the year-on-year rate of change in the CPI excluding perishables (p), uncollateralized overnight call rate (call), and exchange rate for the yen against the dollar as macroeconomic variables (fx) as a set of macroeconomic variables Y and Japanese Government Bond yields of 1-year (y1), 5-year (y5), 1-year (y1) as a set of interest rates, R. The exogenous variables include industrial production in the United States (ip us ) and oil price in terms of the dollar (oil) as a set of macroeconomic variables in foreign sector, X and Treasury yields of 1-year (us1), 5-year (us5), 1-year (us1) as a set of interest rates in foreign sector, Z. The endogenous and exogenous variables are all expressed by the change rates of levels with the exception of R and Z. In sum, Y, R, X, and Z are the following vectors: ip t y1 t p Y t t, R t y5 t call t, y1 t fx t X t ip us t oil t, and Z t us1 t us5 t us1 t. Our model uses the foreign exchange rate instead of the monetary base. The economic growth of Japan s economy highly depends on the performance of the export sector which is strongly affected by the exchange rate. On the other hand, the monetary base has played a less role on the Japanese economy according to Miyao (25) reporting that the linkage between the money supply and income or prices has largely disappeared since the late 199s 2. 2 Miyao (25) suggests that nonperforming loans problems and restructuring may be root causes of his findings and says that the Bank of Japan has reported the money supply forecast since the late 197s, but it has never been used formally as an intermediate target. 5

We use the following structural vector autoregression framework for our analysis: a b Y t = A(L) B(L) Y t 1 c 1 R t C(L) D(L) R t 1 + E(L) F (L) X t + σ εy t, G(L) H(L) where a is a 4 x 4 matrix with ones on the diagonal; b is 4 x 3 matrix; c is a 3 x 4 matrix; A(L), B(L), C(L), D(L), E(L), F (L), G(L), and H(L) are matrix polynomials in the lag operator L. The shock [ε Y t ε R t ] is an i.i.d, vector of mutually and serially uncorrelated structural shocks whose variance is the identity matrix. As we follow the strategy of Evans and Marshall (1998), we maintain the assumptions Z t ε R t that b = B(L) = F (L) = G(L) = : a Y t = A(L) Y t 1 c 1 R t C(L) D(L) R t 1 + E(L) X t + σ H(L) Z t εy t ε R t, (1) indicating that while Y t is affected only by its own lagged variables and X t, a set of interest rates, R, responds contemporaneously to the all endogenous variables and is affected by a set of lagged interest rates in the United States. In addition, we impose another assumption on this structural VAR in order to construct a parsimonious model. We exclude the lagged variables of call rate (call) whose lags are longer than one, that is, Y t and R t are not affect by call t n for n 2. In order to impose sign restrictions on impulse responses similarly to Uhlig (25), our main estimation strategy includes bootstrapping method to generate resampled data 3. First, we estimate equation(1) and acquire residuals. Then, we reorder them randomly and generate resampled data with estimated parameters and reordered residuals. Finally, we reestimate equation(1) using the resampled data. We continue this process until we acquire 3 See, Evans and Marshall (1998), Mittnik and Zadrozny (1993), Kilian (1998a), Kilian (1998b). 6

1, impulse responses using the following sign-restrictions method. We impose sign restrictions on impulse responses in order to ensure that our estimation results are consistent with economic theory 4. Economic theory suggests that the contractionary monetary policy shocks has negative impacts on output for a certain period N. In our case, N is set to 6 because past empirical studies generally assume that N should be about 6 5. It means that the responses of industrial production are all negative in the first 6 months following the arrival of a contractionary monetary policy shock. In order to investigate whether there are any differences of the effects of monetary policy shocks between the pre-zirp period and the ZIRP period, we divide the sample period into two: sub-period 1 and sub-period 2. The sub-period 1 and sub-period 2 cover the pre- ZIRP period from July 1985 to December 1998 and the ZIRP period from January 1999 to December 29, respectively. We estimate the model using two sub-samples separately and compare two estimation results. 3 Estimation Results In this section, we show our impulse responses acquired by the sign restrictions. 3.1 Main Result We estimate structural VAR using the two sample: sub-period 1 and sub-period 2. Figure 1 and 2 show impulse responses to a contractionary monetary policy shock. 4 For example, Braun and Shioji (26), Canova and Nicoló (22), Faust (1998), Mountford (25), and Uhlig (25) analyze monetary policy utilizing the sign-restrictions method. 5 Applications of the sign-restrictions method have been growing. For example, Uhlig (25) uses the sign restriction approach with N = 6 and suggests that the assumption is reasonable in that the estimation results confirm conventional economic principles. Braun and Shioji (26) also impose the sign restrictions on VAR analyzing the Japanese data and they set N to 6 or 7. In Braun and Shioji (26), N = 6 when the restrictions are imposed on monetary base and interest rates, and N = 7 when the restrictions are imposed on price and output. 7

Figure 1 illustrates the responses of interest rates to monetary policy shock and shows two points. First, the left panel in Figure 1 shows negative responses to the contractionary monetary policy shock for about 1 year, while the right panel presents positive responses to the shock for about 1 year. In sub-period 1, a contractionary monetary policy shock decreases all of yields, 1-year, 5-year, and even 1-year interest rates, significantly. The dashed lines, presenting one sigma fluctuations fall below zero in the left panel. In contrast to the sub-period-1, the right panel shows positive responses to the shock. All of the yields increase initially in response to the contractionary monetary policy shock. These responses are a little weaker than those of the left panel, but they all are positive significantly. The results are clearly opposite between two periods. Second, there are larger responses of shorter-term interest rates than that of longer-term interest rate in both periods. In both panels, the bottoms and peaks are larger in 1-year and 5-year yields than those of 1-year yield. The left panel shows that responses of short- and middle-term interest rates drop below -.1% in forth month, while that of long-term interest rate does not reach at -.1% on average. Similarly, in sub-period 2 the shorter-term yields move positively more than the longer-term interest rate in response to the initial shock. The monetary policy shock affects the shorter-term yields more than the longer-term yield in the both periods. In Figure 2, we illustrate the impulse responses of macroeconomic variables to monetary policy shock and find three things. First, the responses of output to contractionary monetary policy shock decrease significantly in both panels. While the response in the left panel is a little weak, the dashed lines fall below zero significantly. Second, there is a difference in price change to monetary policy shock between two panels. The left panel illustrates the initial drop of the response of price to the shock, while the right one shows that price positively responds to the shock. The important finding is that during the pre-zirp period, price falls sticky along with the decline of output. Finally, Figure 2 shows that the call rates are downward-sloping. The responses of the call rate are initially positive and decay over time. The response in sub-period 2 is weak, but 8

it decreases gradually like that of the left panel, indicating that the monetary policy shocks in both panels are well identified. 3.2 Robustness Check The robustness to our estimation results is checked and our estimation results are supported by the robustness check. Figure 3 and 4 show the responses to the monetary policy shock when exogenous variables, X and Z, are excluded from our model. The left panel in Figure 3 presents the responses during the pre-zirp period and shows that all of interest rates fall in response to the contractionary monetary policy shock, which is similar to those in Figure 1 6. In the right panel showing the responses during the ZIRP period, all of the responses of 1-year, 5-year, and 1-year yields are significantly affected by the shock in the right panel. These contrast results are similar to those of the model with exogenous variables in Figure 1. The impulse responses in Figure 4 are also similar to those in Figure 2. Output responds negatively in the both periods, while that of the left panel is weaker than that of the right one. Price drops significantly only in the left panel, indicating that monetary policy shock decreases price during the pre-zirp period. 4 Discussion Our estimation results clearly contrast between the pre-zirp and the ZIRP period. It is interesting to see that the divided samples bring us the contrast results; a surprise tightening in monetary policy lowers both of the shorter- and the longer-term interest rates significantly in sub-period 1, while the shock shifts the yield curve rates upward significantly in subperiod 2. In other words, the results during the pre-zirp period are consistent with the 6 The response of 1-year bond in the left panel is significantly positive in one year after the shock. However, the 1-year interest rate is initially pushed down below zero by the contractionary shock as is the case with the shorter-term bond yields. 9

costly price adjustment hypothesis, while the results during the ZIRP period are consistent with the liquidity effect hypothesis. More interestingly, in both periods, the long-term interest rates are significantly affected by the shock of monetary policy. In response to a contractionary monetary policy shock, the yield on 1-year significantly decreases for about 1 year during the pre-zirp period and significantly increases for about 1 year during the ZIRP period. These results are different from those in Evans and Marshall (1998), which report that long-term rates are virtually unaffected by the shock and the liquidity effects are short-lived and last for only 6 months. Then, why are the estimation results clearly opposite between the two periods? Our answer to this question comes from the change of the perception of market participants about the monetary policy shock. As we mentioned above, in sub-period 1, a surprise tightening in monetary policy decreases all of the yields significantly as bond investors believe that the shock lowers interest rates, lowers output, and lowers prices. However, the yields on 1-year, 5-year, and 1-year subsequently rise significantly during the ZIRP period as bond investors become more optimistic about economic growth in response to the monetary policy shock. In other words, while based on the costly price adjustment hypothesis the unexpected rise in the policy rate drop all of the yields significantly during the pre-zirp period, market participants may consider the contractionary monetary policy shock as the positive signal to the economic recovery of Japan during the ZIRP period. This change of the perception of market participants about the shock of monetary policy contributes to explaining the reason why the responses of all yields to the shock are significantly positive in sub-period 2. 5 Conclusion We examine the effects of a monetary policy shock to the yield curve and whether there are any differences of the effects during the pre-zirp and the ZIRP period in Japan through the vector autoregression with sign restrictions. Our contributions to the literature are the following three points. First, during both periods, long-term interest rates are significantly 1

affected by the shock of monetary policy in response to a contractionary monetary policy shock and these results are different from those in Evans and Marshall (1998), which report that long-term rates are virtually unaffected by the shock. Second, the effects of the monetary policy shock are long-lasted for about 1 year and stronger effects on the short- and medium term interest rates than the long-term interest rate. Finally, we find that the divided samples bring us the contrast results; a surprise tightening in monetary policy lowers shorter- and longer-term interest rates significantly during the pre-zirp period, while the shock shifts the yield curve upward significantly during the ZIRP period. We reveal the contributions of monetary policy to the yield curve and find the interesting results. Yet, there are some questions left. For example, why has the transmission mechanism of monetary policy to the yield curve changed over time? It is likely to say that the reason why the transmission mechanism has changed is partly because bond investors have changed their expectations on the future path of short-term interest rates after the introduction of the unprecedented ZIRP. We have not investigated the structural reason behind this question. Structural understanding of this is left for our future research. 11

References Aiyagari, S. Rao, and R. Anton Braun (1998), Some Models to Guide Monetary Policymakers. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 48, pp.1 42. Braun, R. Anton and Etsuro Shioji (26), Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates in Japan, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 38(1), pp.141 162. Canova, Fabio. and Gianni De Nicoló (22), Monetary Disturbances Matter for Business Fluctuations in the G-7, Journal of Monetary Economics, 49, pp.1131 1159. Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans (1999), Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and to What End? In Handbook of Macroeconomics, 1A, edited by John Taylor. Evans, Charles L. and David A. Marshall (1998), Monetary policy and the term structure of nominal interest rates: evidence and theory, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 49, pp.53 111. Faust, Jon (1998), The Robustness of Identified VAR Conclusions about Money, Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, 49, pp.27-244. Ireland, Peter N. (1997), A Small, Structural, Quarterly Model for Monetary Policy Evaluation. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 47, pp.83 18. Kilian, Lutz (1998a), Small-Sample Confidence Intervals for Impulse Response Functions, Review of Economics and Statistics, 8(2), pp.218 23. Kilian, Lutz (1998b), Impulse Response Intervals under Departures from Normality, Econometric Reviews, 17(1), pp.1 29. Mittnik, Stefan and Peter A. Zadrozny (1993), Asymptotic Distributions of Impulse Responses, Step Responses and Variance Decompositions of Estimated Linear Dynamic Models, Econometrica, 61(4), pp.857 87. 12

Miyao, Ryuzo (25), Use of Money Supply in the Conduct of Japan s Monetary Policy: Reexamining the Time Series Evidence, Japanese Economic Review, 56(2), pp.165 187. Mountford, Andrew (2f5), Leaning into the Wind: A Structural VAR Investigation of UK Monetary Policy, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 67, pp.597 621. Rotemberg, Julio J. (1996), Prices, Output, and Hours: An Empirical Analysis Based on a Sticky Price Model. Journal of Monetary Economics, 37, pp.55 533. Uhlig, Harald (25), What are the effects of monetary policy on output? Results from an agnostic identification procedure, Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, pp.381 419. 13

Figure 1: Responses of interest rates to monetary policy shocks. The left panel covers the pre- ZIRP period and the right one covers the ZIRP period from 1996 to 29..1.1 Sub period 1 from 1985 to 1998 MP shock ==> 1 year bond.2.2 1 2 MP shock ==> 1 year bond.2.1.1 Sub period 2 from 1999 to 29.2 1 2 MP shock ==> 5 year bond.2.1.1.2 1 2 MP shock ==> 5 year bond.2.1.1.2 1 2 MP shock ==> 1 year bond.2.1.1 MP shock ==> 1 year bond.2.1.1.2 1 2.2 1 2 14

Figure 2: Responses of macroeconomic variables to monetary policy shocks. The left panel covers the pre-zirp period and the right one covers the ZIRP period from 1996 to 29. Sub period 1 from 1985 to 1998 Sub period 2 from 1999 to 29.2 MP shock ==> IP.2 MP shock ==> IP.2.2.4 1 2.1.1 MP shock ==> Price 1 2.4 1 2.1.1 MP shock ==> Price 1 2 MP shock ==> Call Rate.3.2.1 1 2 MP shock ==> Call Rate.3.2.1 1 2 MP shock ==> FX 1.5.5 1 1 2 MP shock ==> FX 1.5.5 1 1 2 15

Figure 3: Responses of interest rates to monetary policy shocks in the model without exogenous variables. The left panel covers the pre-zirp period and the right one covers the ZIRP period from 1996 to 29..3.2.1.1.2 Sub period 1 from 1985 to 1998 MP shock ==> 1 year bond.3 1 2.3.2.1.1.2 Sub period 2 from 1999 to 29 MP shock ==> 1 year bond.3 1 2.3.2.1.1.2 MP shock ==> 5 year bond.3 1 2.3.2.1.1.2 MP shock ==> 5 year bond.3 1 2.3.2.1.1.2 MP shock ==> 1 year bond.3 1 2.3.2.1.1.2 MP shock ==> 1 year bond.3 1 2 16

Figure 4: Responses of macroeconomic variables to monetary policy shocks in the model without exogenous variables. The left panel covers the pre-zirp period and the right one covers the ZIRP period from 1996 to 29. Sub period 1 from 1985 to 1998 Sub period 2 from 1999 to 29.5 MP shock ==> IP.5 MP shock ==> IP.5.5 1 1 2 1 1 2.2 MP shock ==> Price.2 MP shock ==> Price.2.2.4 1 2 MP shock ==> Call Rate.3.2.1 1 2 MP shock ==> FX 1 1 1 2.4 1 2 MP shock ==> Call Rate.3.2.1 1 2 MP shock ==> FX 1 1 1 2 17