Reassessing Like Products



Similar documents
ENVIRONMENTAL AND PRODUCT SAFETY CASES IN THE WTO WTO Research Center of AGU William J. Davey *

An Analysis of Shrimp/Turtle II: The WTO Makes Room for Environmental Trade Restrictions

TRADE and ENVIRONMENT

General Exceptions of Article XX of the GATT 1994 and Article XIV of the GATS. Juan Ochoa, Postdoctoral Research Fellow

Profiting from Non-Technological Innovation: The Value of Patenting. Novak druce centre insights No. 8

Trade Debates - Liberal Voices Needed

The exemption for legal professional privilege (section 42)

How do companies avoid tax?

)LQDQFLDO$VVXUDQFH,VVXHV RI(QYLURQPHQWDO/LDELOLW\

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

INLAND REVENUE BOARD OF REVIEW DECISIONS. Case No. D23/96

MOST-FAVOURED-NATION TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

Why a Floating Exchange Rate Regime Makes Sense for Canada

THE TRADE SECRETS DIRECTIVE THE NEW COUNCIL PROPOSAL 1 WOUTER PORS. Bird & Bird The Hague. 1. Introduction and general issues

Romanian Economic and Business Review Vol. 3, No. 2 EQUAL PAY THE TIME-BOMB UNDER PAY STRUCTURES IN ROMANIA

AGREEMENT ON THE APPLICATION OF SANITARY AND PHYTOSANITARY MEASURES

Negotiating for Hong Kong

Five years of trademark opposition in Benelux: a review. Nederlandsch Octrooibureau

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS

)UHHWUDGHDQGHQYLURQPHQWDOSURWHFWLRQDUHZKROO\FRPSDWLEOHFRQFHSWVIXOO\ HPEUDFHGE\WKHQHZFRQFHSWRIVXVWDLQDEOHGHYHORSPHQW,QWURGXFWLRQ

Service 2 - IPR analysis and survey mini-guide

OPPOSITION GUIDELINES. Part 3. Unauthorised filing by agents of the TM owner (Art.8(3) CTMR)

EDRi s. January European Digital Rights Rue Belliard 20, 1040 Brussels tel. +32 (0)

CIVIL CODE OF THE RUSSIAN FEDERATION

ESMT BUSINESS BRIEF. Exploitative Abuses. Lars-Hendrik Röller, ESMT. ESMT No. BB ISSN

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION 3.5 GATT 1994

AGREEMENT ON TECHNICAL BARRIERS TO TRADE. Having regard to the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations;

CHAPTER 13: International Law, Norms, and Human Rights

Mr. Thomas Arthur Emory University School of Law, Atlanta, GA Dean. Testimony Mr. Chairman, and Members of the Committee:

11. Process and Production Methods and the Regulation of International Trade

An Optional Common European Sales Law: Advantages and Problems Advice to the UK Government

TACD RECOMMENDATIONS ON HEALTH CARE AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND EUROPEAN COMMISSION SERVICES RESPONSES

PROTECTING HUMAN RIGHTS IN THE UK THE CONSERVATIVES PROPOSALS FOR CHANGING BRITAIN S HUMAN RIGHTS LAWS

ANNUAL 2008 SESSION OF THE PARLIAMENTARY CONFERENCE ON THE WTO Geneva, September 2008

HOW CAN THEY GET AWAY WITH THIS? Some Basic Information. For. Long Term Disability Clients

finding the balance between public and private health the example of australia

PDF security - a brief history of development

IANUS 2014 MODULO JEAN MONNET ISSN

Memorandum by the Association of Investment Companies (AIC)

PUBLIC HEALTH OPTOMETRY ECONOMICS. Kevin D. Frick, PhD

Indemnity Basis of Settlement. Practical Problems in Adjusting Losses. By the CILA Property Special Interest Group

PATENTS ACT Whether patent application GB A relates to a patentable invention DECISION

The Chartered Institute of Patent Attorneys

Decision 131/2008 Mr N and East Ayrshire Council. Tender Documents. Reference No: Decision Date: 7 October 2008

National Energy Policies on Trial at the WTO

TOWARDS MORE COHERENCE BETWEEN INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND THE RIGHTS OF THE CHILD

Response to Department for Business, Enterprise and Regulatory Reform consultation: Legislative options to address illicit P2P file-sharing

RESPONSE TO FCC CONSULTATION. Notice of Proposed Rulemaking on Protecting and Promoting the Open Internet GN Docket No

Sale of t h e C e n t u ry? Proposals for a positive sustainable trade agenda

Public consultation on Draft Advice on customer complaint handling, Reporting and Classification

ON EXTERNAL OBJECTS By Immanuel Kant From Critique of Pure Reason (1781)

Private Health Insurance Consultations

Investment Portfolio Philosophy

TRINIDAD AND TOBBAGO:

Freedom and Open Source

Privilege - pitfalls and obstacles for clients operating in multiple jurisdictions

A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation

Suspend the negotiations for a free trade agreement with the USA no agreement at the expense of workers, consumers or the environment

Information Exchange: what would help developing countries now?

SEA Europe input on future EU-US Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership

Expert Evidence In Professional Negligence Claims

The Debt Crisis and the Future of International Bank Lending. H. Robert Heller. Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

THE HON JULIA GILLARD MP DEPUTY PRIME MINISTER Minister for Education Minister for Employment and Workplace Relations Minister for Social Inclusion

Training Professionals in Trade Policy Development Advocacy and Negotiation - The Training Challenge in Commercial Diplomacy

apest Practices and Advantages of Using a Novel Proposal

How To Understand A Rent Review Clause

OFFER BY WPP GROUP PLC ("WPP")

L esaurimento comunitario del marchio

CCBE POSITION WITH RESPECT TO THE FREE CHOICE OF A LAWYER IN RELATION TO LEGAL EXPENSES INSURANCE

INTRODUCTION TO TRADE MARKS INTRODUCTION TO TRADE MARKS

Promoting Cross Border Data Flows Priorities for the Business Community

CALL FOR PROPOSALS. PEOPLE s RIGHT TO WATER WHEN FACING EXTRACTIVE ACTIVITIES

The Product/Process Distinction An Illusory Basis for Disciplining Unilateralism in Trade Policy

Modernising Powers, Deterrents and Safeguards Working with Tax Agents

Freedom of information guidance Exemptions guidance Section 41 Information provided in confidence

Opinion Statement of the CFE. on the proposed Directive. on the fight against fraud to the EU s financial interests. by means of criminal law

SETTLING DISPUTES. The priority is to settle disputes, not to pass judgement. 1. A unique contribution. Chapter 3

Critical Study David Benatar. Better Never To Have Been: The Harm of Coming into Existence (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006)

PREPARED STATEMENT OF J. HOWARD BEALES III

Yearbook. Building IP value in the 21st century. Beyond the unitary patent: nothing new under the sun?

International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights

Response of the Association of Costs Lawyers to the consultation on the impact of the Jackson reforms on costs and case management

Eurodoc Recommendations on the entry and residence of third-country nationals for the purpose of research

ATLANTA DECLARATION AND PLAN OF ACTION FOR THE ADVANCEMENT OF THE RIGHT OF ACCESS TO INFORMATION

Market entry strategy and distribution channels

PROCEDURES AND COSTS FOR PATENTS

Response by Swedish authorities to the European Commission s public consultation on short selling

GOVERNANCE IN "CYBERSPACE' Access and Public Interest in Global Communications

Cooperative compliance and the Litigation and Settlement Strategy; results from a survey. Judith Freedman, Francis Ng and John Vella May 15, 2014

IN THE MATTER OF AN ARBITRATION UNDER CHAPTER 11 OF THE NORTH AMERICAN FREE TRADE AGREEMENT AND THE UNCITRAL ARBITRATION RULES

Integrated Water Resources Management

GENERAL TERMS AND CONDITIONS

CLIENT MEMORANDUM. I. The Basics. June 18, 2013

The Balance of Payments, the Exchange Rate, and Trade

Cloud Computing specialized commission. Report summary

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF CLOUD COMPUTING. Cloud computing refers to the aggregation of data storage and processing power in

FINANCIAL REPORTING STANDARDS FRS 9

IMPROVING TRANSFER OPERATIONS. A variety of bad practices and external threats have been identified with regard to transfer operations.

Fee Waivers INTRODUCTION CONTENTS FEES: THE RATIONALE

Briefi ng 15:02 THE EU JOBS MYTH. By Ryan Bourne March 2015

Transcription:

Reassessing Like Products Konrad von Moltke, Senior Fellow, IISD Paper presented at the Chatham House Conference Trade, Investment and the Environment, 29 & 30 October 1998. Introduction The issue of process and production methods (PPMs) in the trade regime has vexed the environmental community since the first tuna dolphin panel claimed that distinctions between products based on their production methods were not permitted under GATT. The reason for its distress is straightforward: an open trading system, which does not provide for distinctions between products produced sustainably and those produced unsustainably, is unacceptable from an environmental perspective. Unless the issue of PPMs is resolved reasonably, the environmental community will ultimately oppose trade liberalization. It is up to those interested in trade policy to decide whether they are willing to pursue their goals against environmental opposition; in essence whether they can persuade voters in democratic societies that the economic benefits they promise outweigh not only the inevitable economic costs to those who do not enjoy comparative advantage, but also the risks to the environment, and to communities. Like Products in WTO dispute settlement Before addressing possible solutions to the issue of PPMs within the trading system, it is necessary to dispose of the myth that no such distinctions are possible, either because this is contrary to fundamental principles of the trading system or simply because the current text of GATT forbids it. Frequent repetition of this error, including repetition by those responsible for managing the trading system and by many eminent commentators, makes it no more correct than it was to begin with. The issue of PPMs in the GATT/WTO revolves around the interpretation of the word like, as in like products. The concept of like products is in many ways the linchpin of the GATT/WTO system. Its two central principles, most-favoured nation treatment (MFN) and national treatment are critically dependent on this concept. The key passages in GATT read as follows: any advantage, favour, privilege or immunity granted by any contracting party to any product originating in or destined for any other country shall be accorded immediately and unconditionally to the like product originating in or destined for the territories of all other contracting parties. (Article I.1).

The products of the territory of any contracting party imported into the territory of any other contracting party shall not be subject, directly or indirectly, to internal taxes or other internal charges of any kind in excess of those applied, directly or indirectly, to the like domestic products. (Article III.2). The English word like has no perfect counterpart in French or Spanish. The French version of GATT speaks of equivalent, which actually expresses something different again since it derives from value rather than focusing, as the word like does, on the inherent characteristics of a product. Consequently, equivalent expresses more clearly the valuation of products, and of distinctions between products, by certain economic actors. The drafters of the original GATT text (in practice those drafting the Havana Charter) were presumably well aware of the ambiguities of the term like and of the inherent dangers in using such an ambiguous term in passages so critical to the text. They chose the word like precisely because its ambiguities reflected a problem in the real world. Some products are equivalent but not like (for example, whisky and sake). Some products are like but not equivalent (for example, wild caught salmon and the ranched version). In the modern trading system, some products are identical but not alike (for example, genetic and branded pharmaceuticals). In short, the term like requires careful interpretation to ensure that GATT does not produce unacceptable results. Given its importance it is reasonable to expect extensive analysis of the concept of like products in dispute-settlement proceedings of GATT and in the general literature. In fact, not much is to be found, presumably because the significance of the ambiguity appeared intuitively obvious and because, surprisingly, countries have rarely attempted to use criteria viewed as spurious by other countries to distinguish between otherwise like products. The most important dispute to date revolving around interpretation of like concerned liquor taxes in Japan. The dispute panel struggled hard with the problem, not least because the equivalence of sake and many liquors imported to Japan was intuitively obvious, but also because the protectionist intent of Japanese tax rules was hard to overlook. Even still, it was difficult to develop an argument that was free from internal contradictions and did not open the door to a Pandora s box of other problems. The Appellate Body, reviewing the panel report on appeal, was seduced by the outlandish view that Article III.1 should be read as a chapeau to the entire Article III, possibly because a more obvious distinction between Article III.1 and III.2 seemed unpalatable since it opened the door wide to PPMs, including PPMs in other countries: that Article III.1 deals with production while Article III.2 addresses products in trade. At the very least it should be clear that GATT contains no explicit prohibition on the use of PPMs in general. This view is the result of a process of interpretation, which sometimes resembles the rule-making committee of a club rather than that of an international body with global responsibilities. There is, however, a more direct way in which to approach

the issue of PPMs in the trading system. To prove that PPMs are possible within GATT, it is sufficient to show that they are currently being utilized. Like products and intellectual property rights It may come as a surprise to some observers that in several areas GATT handles PPMs without apparent difficulty. The most dramatic application of PPMs in the GATT/WTO to date is in the field of intellectual property rights. The Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement) is in effect an agreement on PPMs. It distinguishes between products in trade, not based on their inherent characteristics, but on whether certain rules have been observed in the production process namely, whether the rights of the holders of intellectual property have been respected. A compact disc with a pirated version of music, a film or computer software is indistinguishable from a disc with the same (not like!) materials: otherwise as often as not it would not function properly. A generic pharmaceutical product can be identical with its branded equivalent; sometimes it is legally required to be identical so as not to endanger the health of users. Indeed, some generic pharmaceuticals are manufactured on the same machines as their branded equivalents, yet they are clearly distinguished in the trade regime. The difference between PPMs arising from intellectual property rights and those needed for environmental purposes is that the former benefit the most powerful interests in the global economy while the latter appear to benefit nobody in particular, merely the environment. The economic effect of intellectual property rights (IPRs) is to assign a temporary monopoly to the holder of these rights. Most of these monopolies are of course worthless because there is no market demand for the vast majority of patents, manuscripts, recordings or software. When such demand exists, however, the profits can be staggering and many major multinational corporations derive a significant proportion of their income from IPRs, most dramatically companies like Microsoft, Philips or Toyota. It is interesting to note that only one environmental dispute has arisen concerning the products of producers such as these: the dispute over CAFE standards and the gas-guzzler tax, which pitted Daimler-Benz and BMW against the U.S. automobile industry, one of the more unusual GATT disputes in terms of its outcome. The vast majority of environmental disputes in the GATT/WTO concern commodities; that is products, which are produced and traded to a non-proprietary standard: tuna, shrimp, forest products, fish, gasoline, soy beans, beef. The environmental concern for PPMs focuses primarily on the need to segment commodity markets in such a manner that the environmental impact of the extraction process becomes transparent to subsequent users and the environmental costs can be successfully internalized. One way to test the free trade fervour of those who deny the possibility of introducing necessary environmental PPM distinctions is to suggest that all products currently being traded with IPR protection should be traded as commodities, that is to a single, universally accepted specification.

This brief discussion is not the occasion to discuss the role of commodity markets in pricing the environment or in promoting (or obstructing) the internalization of environmental costs in products traded on international markets. This is a matter requiring much more research and public debate than it has received to date. Taking the debate forward Since like products are at the heart of the GATT/WTO system, changing the definition of what will be recognized as valid distinctions between otherwise like products is a matter of great concern to those responsible for managing the trading system. In particular, it raises the spectre of disguised forms of protectionism, precisely because it relates to the central principles of the regime designed to keep protectionists at bay. What worries many proponents of trade liberalization is the prospect of disguised forms of protection, which are particularly insidious when wedded to seemingly legitimate environmental goals, such as protecting dolphins, improving air quality, or strengthening the ecological management of forests alliances which David Vogel has called baptist bootlegger coalitions. It is important for those concerned primarily with the environment to recognize the legitimacy of such fears. Indeed, the shrimp turtle dispute is the only one where I am unaware of any significant commercial interest allied with the surface environmental concern. On the other hand, the existence of some protectionist effect of a measure must not in and of itself invalidate it. Sometimes the environmental need clearly outweighs the economic costs of protectionism. It seems to me that it is in the interests of everyone concerned that we move beyond the absurd debate about PPMs, as if they were some form of original sin in the trade regime. We must seek a way to ensure that the use of environmental PPMs occurs in a rule-based manner. That, after all, is what the trading system is supposed to be about. So the correct question relative to environmental PPMs is not whether they are permissible but whether they are needed, and if they are needed what rules should apply. The importance of PPMs for attaining sustainability has not yet been conclusively demonstrated. The significance of PPMs in this context is highly intuitive; nevertheless it resides on a critical notion related to the characteristics of commodity markets, namely that without certain PPMs producers of commodities will be confronted with an invidious choice: degrade the environment or lose market share. This is a restatement of one of the most persistent of all ideas in the environment trade debate, namely that rules are required to avoid the creation of pollution havens. No clear evidence has yet been adduced to show that pollution havens exist. In part that is attributable to the fact that researchers have been asking the wrong question: Is there any risk of a general move of production from high-regulation to low-regulation jurisdictions. Enterprises with significant profit margins, in particular those benefiting from IPRs, will not make location decisions based on the cost of environmental protection. The reasons are complex, ranging

from the modest cost of environmental measures relative to other factors of production, to the importance of proximity to major markets, to the need to protect a brand's image. On the other hand some evidence suggests that the production of commodities, and to a lesser degree the production of certain commodity manufactures, has shifted away from high-regulation jurisdictions to those with lower regulation. The reasons are again complex, ranging from the availability of higher-value uses of scarce environmental resources in locations close to the value-added centres of the world, to the resistance of highly urbanized societies in Europe and Japan to further destruction of the landscape, and to the availability of cheap labour for labour-intensive phases of the product chain. With these few observations we are again in the relatively unexplored area of commodity production and the environment, which also happens to be the prime domain for environmental PPMs. Interestingly, viewing the TRIPS Agreement for what it is an agreement on the application of certain PPMs provides some guidelines on how to address PPMs in the trading system. It is true that national environmental protection measures are the first step toward any international structure. It is also so obvious as to be trite that national measures alone cannot suffice. Consequently, the GATT/WTO needs an agreement on how to develop and apply environmental PPMs at all levels where they are needed: local, regional, national, international and global. This is not a task for the GATT/WTO. Just as the TRIPS Agreement rests on a broad base of preparatory work undertaken by those whose concern is the development of IPRs, so an environmental PPMs Agreement must originate with those whose primary concern is the environment. They must specify what is needed, and how they plan to go about putting it in place. The role of GATT is then to insert such an agreement into the rule-based structure of the trading system in a manner that respects the needs of both those concerned with the environment and those whose focus is trade liberalization. That sounds simple. It is not. But it is straightforward and may contribute to shortening a debate that seems to be going nowhere even while the underlying issues get more urgent with every environmentally related trade dispute.