Unifying Time-to-Build Theory



Similar documents
VI. Real Business Cycles Models

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Real Business Cycle Theory

Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model

Real Business Cycle Models

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle?

Economic Growth: Lectures 6 and 7, Neoclassical Growth

Hello, my name is Olga Michasova and I present the work The generalized model of economic growth with human capital accumulation.

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February Ellen R. McGrattan

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Real Business Cycle Theory

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

Real Business Cycle Models

Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Intertemporal approach to current account: small open economy

NUMERICAL ANALYSIS OF TWO COUPLED KALDOR-KALE KALDOR-KALECKI MODELS WITH DELAY

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Investment

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

Cash in advance model

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge

A Three-Sector Model of Structural Transformation and Economic Development

Economic Growth: Theory and Empirics (2012) Problem set I

Advanced Macroeconomics (ECON 402) Lecture 8 Real Business Cycle Theory

15 Kuhn -Tucker conditions

HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS AND AGGREGATE UNCERTAINTY. Daniel Harenberg University of Mannheim. Econ 714,

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Chapters 7 and 8 Solow Growth Model Basics

2007/8. The problem of non-renewable energy resources in the production of physical capital. Agustin Pérez-Barahona

Optimal Insurance Coverage of a Durable Consumption Good with a Premium Loading in a Continuous Time Economy

Advanced Macroeconomics (2)

Graduate Macroeconomics 2

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix

Fixed Point Theorems

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth

The Optimal Growth Problem

Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data. joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia

Supplement to Call Centers with Delay Information: Models and Insights

Fat Tailed Uncertainty and Learning - A Case Study

A Progress Report on Business Cycle Models

External Debt and Stabilizing Macroeconomic Policies

welfare costs of business cycles

Government Debt Management: the Long and the Short of it

A Theory of Capital Controls As Dynamic Terms of Trade Manipulation

Lecture 13 Linear quadratic Lyapunov theory

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine

1 The EOQ and Extensions

Understanding Poles and Zeros

Real Business Cycle Theory-A Systematic Review

Zero Nominal Interest Rates: Why They re Good and How to Get Them

Online Appendix: Corporate Cash Holdings and Credit Line Usage

Introduction to Money

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3: The Solow Growth Model

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM WITH BANKS AND THE FACTOR-INTENSITY CONDITION

Understanding the Impact of Weights Constraints in Portfolio Theory

Risk Aversion, Investor Information, and Stock Market Volatility

Optimal Taxation in a Limited Commitment Economy

The Evaluation of Barrier Option Prices Under Stochastic Volatility. BFS 2010 Hilton, Toronto June 24, 2010

Dynamics of current account in a small open economy

Sovereign Defaults. Iskander Karibzhanov. October 14, 2014

Nonlinear Systems of Ordinary Differential Equations

1 A simple two period model

The Solow Model. Savings and Leakages from Per Capita Capital. (n+d)k. sk^alpha. k*: steady state Per Capita Capital, k

Charles Jones: US Economic Growth in a World of Ideas and other Jones Papers. January 22, 2014

Lecture 21 and 22: The Prime Number Theorem

A characterization of trace zero symmetric nonnegative 5x5 matrices

REAL BUSINESS CYCLE THEORY METHODOLOGY AND TOOLS

SUSTAINABLE PLANS AND DEBT

Real Business Cycle Theory

Math Assignment 6

Moisă ALTĂR Ciprian NECULA Gabriel BOBEICĂ

Instability of Sunspot Equilibria in Real Business Cycle Models Under Adaptive Learning

Yangon, Myanmar February 16 27, Jan Gottschalk. IMF-TAOLAM training activities are supported by funding of the Government of Japan

Discrete Dynamic Optimization: Six Examples

Unemployment Insurance Savings Accounts in a life-cycle model with job search

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Using Dynare

Back to the past: option pricing using realized volatility

INDIRECT INFERENCE (prepared for: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition)

3. Regression & Exponential Smoothing

RISK SHARING AND EFFICIENCY IMPLICATIONS

Cash-in-Advance Model

Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land).

Lecture L3 - Vectors, Matrices and Coordinate Transformations

Transcription:

Unifying Time-to-Build Theory M. Bambi, and F. Gori speaker: M. Bambi (University of York, U.K.) OFCE-SKEMA, Nice, 2010

Time to Build Time to Build (TtB) means that capital takes time to becomes productive. Jevons: A vineyard is unproductive for at least three years before it is thoroughly fit for use. In gold mining there is often a long delay, sometimes even of five or six years, before gold is reached.

Business cycle literature Kydland and Prescott (Econometrica 1982), Rouwenhorst (JME 1991) - RBC models with time to build - Increase in the persistence of the business cycle more recently, Gomme et al. (JPE 2001), Casares (JME 2006), and Edge (JME 2007) Time-to-Build in a discrete time framework

Growth literature Kalecki (Econometrica 1935), Asea and Zak (JEDC 1999), and Bambi (JEDC 2008) - Capital accumulation equation K(t) = F (K(t J)) C(t) - Optimal path of capital is oscillatory: infinite number of conjugate complex eigenvalues; example with C(t) = (1 s)y (t), linear technology, and no depreciation: K(t) = sak(t J) h(λ) = λ sae Jλ = 0 Time-to-Build in a continuous time framework BUT delay in production at discrete time intervals

This Paper Attempt to unify these 2 streams of the Time-to-Build literature, continuous Vs discrete time How to do that? Step 1: Construct the continuous counterpart of the (deterministic) Kydland and Prescott discrete time model. Step 2: Compare the short run and long run dynamics induced by the 2 formulations.

Why concentrate on TtB models? 3 main reasons: TtB theories are important in replicating several stylized facts in the business cycle literature. The comparison between discrete and continuous time systems is much more challenging (and quite interesting) in the TtB context because the former are finite-dimensioned systems and the latter infinite-dimensioned. Computational interest related to a quantitative evaluation of the differences.

Playing with Time Let s consider the deterministic version of the Kydland and Prescott model with pure investment lag in production, J; time period length equals to h = 1 m with m N ; time measure equals to sh with s N {0}; beginning of time sets exogenously at t R + {0}. A sequences of relevant dates have the form t + sh. Standard KP model: t = 0, h = 1, and s time measure.

Social planner problem becomes: subject to max ( ) 1 1 + ρh } {{ } β h s=1 s 1 [u(c t+sh ) + ν(l t+sh )]h K t+j+sh+h = A hf (K t+sh, L t+sh ) + (1 δh)k t+j+sh hc t+sh and initial conditions K i, with i = t, t + h, t + 2h,..., t + nh = t + J Investment, consumption, and output as well as the depreciation rate of capital and the preference discount rate are re- scaled uniformly by h.

Optimal Equilibrium Path An optimal equilibrium path of the economy is any sequence {C t+sh } s=1,{l t+sh} s=1, and {K t+sh+j } s=1, which satisfies K t+j+sh+h = A hf (K t+sh, L t+sh ) + (1 δh)k t+j+sh hc t+sh ν L (L t+sh ) u C (C t+sh ) = AF L (K t+sh, L t+sh ) u C (C t+sh ) u C (C t+sh+h ) ] = β h [β J u h C (C t+j+sh+h ) h u C (C t+sh+h ) AhF K (K t+sh+j, L t+sh+j ) + 1 δh plus the initial history of capital and the transversality condition lim sh µ t+sh k t+sh = 0 for any choice of s N, and any t R + {0}.

Continuous time h 0 K(t + J) = A F (K(t), L(t)) δk(t + J) C(t) t R + {0} ν L (L(t)) u C (C(t)) = AF L (K(t), L(t)) t R + {0} while the continuous version of the Euler equation is Ċ(t) C(t) = u [ ] C (C(t)) uc (C(t + J)) AF K (K(t + J), L(t + J))e ρj δ ρ u CC (C(t))C(t) u C (C(t)) again t R + {0}.

Remark: The Euler equation so obtained, is exactly the same equation which can be deduced by solving the optimal growth problem: subject to max 0 [u(c(t)) + ν(l(t))]e ρt dt K(t + J) = AF (K(t), L(t)) δk(t + J) C(t) given the initial condition K (t) = K 0 (t) for t [0, J].

Result after the Game When h shrinks to zero, the stock of capital becomes K(t) = t+j I (s)e δ(s t J) ds which is exactly the same relation used in Asea and Zak, and Bambi. Gestation lags as defined by Kalecki, can be easily exploited by calling I (t) = L(t + J) + U = K(t + J) + δk(t + J). The Kydland and Prescott model with period length h, contains all the developed specifications of time to build.

However the passage from discrete time to continuous time in a TtB framework is NOT innocuous! Different dimensionality of the two systems describing the economy. What are the economic consequences of this difference? Long run: negligible differences from a qualitative/quantitative point of view... Short run: comparison is less straightforward.

Discrete time Assumption: indivisible labor supply c t = c 0 z1 t k t = c 0 Ψz1 t + 2 2 r2j t [ x 2j cos tw 2j ỹ 2j sin tw 2j ] J 1 j=1 (J is odd) J 2 unique monotonic convergence of capital and consumption. 2 J J unique oscillatory convergence of capital and unique monotonic convergence of consumption. J > J local instability.

Continuous time Assumption: indivisible labor supply c(t) = âe zt k(t) = 1 (â, Φ 1,v )e z ṽ t + 2 [ 2 (â, Φ 1,v ) cos y v t 3 (â, Φ 2,v ) sin y v t] e xv t v ṽ 0 < J < J unique oscillatory convergence of capital and unique monotonic convergence of consumption. J = J cycle through a Hopf bifurcation. J > J local instability.

Quantitative Comparison after Calibration The parameters in these simulations are chosen in line with Kydland and Prescott quarterly calibration with J = 4. (continuous case) Impossible to compute all the roots: Lambert function computes the 2m + 1 closest roots to the imaginary axis. We have checked our results for m = 100, and its robustness by choosing m = 10, 150, 300, 1000.

2 x 10-4 1 0-1 -2-3 -4-5 -6 0 2J 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Figure: Continuous vs Discrete: differences in capital level

6.2% 6% 5.8% m=10 m=100 m=150 m=300 m=1000 5.6% 5.4% 5.2% 5% J J+1 J+2 J+3 2J Figure: Continuous vs Discrete: capital percentage differences for different choices of m

Results: 1. Main difference in the first 40 periods. 2. Volatility around the trend may be 6% higher in continuous time. 3. Change in stability: J = 35 = J.