The "New" Arizona v. California: Practicably Irrigable Acreage and Economic Feasibility



Similar documents
THE WATER QUALITY PROBLEM ON THE COLORADO RIVER

THE IMPORTANCE OF INDIAN WATER RIGHTS SETTLEMENT FUNDING *

Although I concur in my colleagues statement of the law, I cannot do so with

UPPER COLORADO AND SAN JUAN RIVER BASINS ENDANGERED FISH RECOVERY PROGRAMS

Process and Implications of Adjudication through Litigation of CSKT Reserved Water Right Claims vs. Legislative Approval of a Compact

Statement of Basis and Purpose. Rules Governing the Arkansas River Water Bank Pilot Program

WRITING A CRITICAL ARTICLE REVIEW

The Taos Valley lies between the Sangre de Cristo Mountains and the Rio

TORT AND INSURANCE LAW REPORTER. Informal Discovery Interviews Between Defense Attorneys and Plaintiff's Treating Physicians

MEASURING ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF PROJECTS AND PROGRAMS

SAWTOOTH NATIONAL RECREATION AREA AND JERRY PEAK WILDERNESS ADDITIONS ACT

Moving Forward: Agricultural Water Conservation, Productivity, and Water Transfers Workgroup

VII. DIRECT, INDIRECT, AND INDUCED ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF UC SAN DIEGO

CROP SHARE ARRANGEMENTS AND THE FAMILY FARM CORPORATION: PLANNING NEEDED FOR TAX-FREE SEPARATION OF BUSINESS

INDIAN WATER RIGHTS SETTLEMENTS BRINGING CERTAINTY TO UNCERTAIN WATER RESOURCES

Western Area Power Administration Rocky Mountain Region (LAPT) Network Integrated Transmission Service. Designated Network Resources

I. INTRODUCTION. A.3d 685 (Pa. 2012). 2 Id. at Yussen, M.D. v. Med. Care Availability & Reduction of Error Fund, 46

LAWS AND GUIDELINES REGARDING YOUR INVOLVEMENT IN SHAPING HEALTH POLICY

NOTE IN THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT WE TRUST? FEDERAL FUNDING FOR TRIBAL WATER RIGHTS SETTLEMENTS AND THE TAOS PUEBLO INDIAN WATER RIGHTS SETTLEMENT ACT

Agricultural Machinery Custom Hiring Centres (CHC) Model Scheme

FUTURE PERFECT: HOW TENSE AND MOOD WILL HAVE DECLAWED THE CLAW-BACK

COLORADO PLATEAU COOPERATIVE ECOSYSTEM STUDIES UNIT. AMENDMENT THREE TO COOPERATIVE and JOINT VENTURE AGREEMENT. between NAVAJO NATION

The above-captioned matter came before the undersigned Judge of District Court

Public Law th Congress, S September 30, An Act

Distinguished Budget Presentation Awards Program Government Finance Officers Association. Awards Criteria (and explanations of the Criteria)

Econ 202 Section 4 Final Exam


THE COMPTROLLER GENERAL DrECISION!- OF -THE UNITED STATES \C. , */.UW A S H I N G T AD. C. Z 5 4 E8

ED 2205/ August 2015 Original: English. Common Fund for Commodities. 7 th Open Call for Proposals

Chapter 11 Tribal Economies Introduction

ARIZONA WATER SETTLEMENTS ACT

The Sale And Leasing Of Water Rights In Western States: An Update To Mid-2003

The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau Should Rein in Mortgage Servicers Use of Force-Placed Insurance

Question: Are Tribal Courts Different than State and Federal Courts?

STATE OF ARIZONA OFFICE OF THE ATTORNEY GENERAL

UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT

applet-magic.com INTRODUCTION TO COST BENEFIT ANALYSIS

The New Deal and the Great Depression Bill Woolwine Winter Haven Senior High

'PRIVATE' SPLIT-DOLLAR PROVIDES TRANSFER TAX SAVINGS

Case 1:11-cv RC Document 27 Filed 07/30/12 Page 1 of 2 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

Interpretive Letter #835

FILE: WAC Office: CALIFORNIA SERVICE CENTER ~ate:au& )

The CFPB Amends Regulation Z s Credit Card Issuer Ability-to-Pay Requirements

Douglas, Spring 2008 February 21, 2008 PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

Amendments To Accounting Standards For Direct Loans and Loan Guarantees. In Statement of Federal Financial Accounting Standards No.

RESUME. SCOTT BOWNE McELROY Attorney at Law

State of Arkansas Construction Assistance Revolving Loan Fund Program

STATE OF ARIZONA OFFICE OF THE ATTORNEY GENERAL

International Accounting Standard 16 (IAS 16), Property, Plant and Equipment

Understanding budgets and the budgeting process R. L. Smathers

DIMENSIONS OF SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT Vol. I - Human Capital for Sustainable Economic Develpment - G. Edward Schuh

Federal Agencies Subject to the Data Quality Act. by Susan M. Bisong Modrall, Sperling, Roehl, Harris & Sisk, P.A.

Public Authority Debt Structure and New York s Future Generations

Chicago-Style Citation Quick Guide for Government Documents

The dispute is about the sale of a payment protection insurance (PPI) policy in connection with a credit card account with the firm in April 2007.

Dodd-Frank Act Changes Affecting Private Fund Managers and Other Investment Advisers By Adam Gale and Garrett Lynam

The Natural Resource Content of United States Foreign Trade

CONTENTS ABSTRACT. KEYWORDS:. Forest ownership, forest conversion.

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

State of Arkansas Construction Assistance Revolving Loan Fund Program

Mortgages and Loans. Huonville: 8/16 Main St, Huonville 7109 DX 70754, Huonville PO Box 239, Huonville 7109 Ph:

In The Supreme Court of the United States

Sample Size and Power in Clinical Trials

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

Key Concepts and Skills. Net Present Value and Other Investment Rules. rwjch5v3overview.pdf.

EMERGENCY MANAGEMENT PLANS AND DEFICIENT DAMS (INTERNATIONAL BEST PRACTICE OR A HOME- GROWN APPROACH?)

A Note on the Optimal Supply of Public Goods and the Distortionary Cost of Taxation

DOT REGULATIONS AS TO PASSENGER DELAYS AND RIGHTS, AND THEIR RAMIFICATIONS Katherine A. Staton, Esq. Partner, Jackson Walker L.L.P.

A Brief Analysis of the Impact of NAFTA on the United States and Mexico. Animesh Singh Professor P. Dasgupta Saint Peter s College November 15, 2011.

Federal Discount Rate FY 2003

City of Sacramento Long-Term Liability Report

Funds Provided to American Indians/Alaska Natives that are Excluded by Law

TESTIMONY OF RONNIE LUPE, TRIBAL CHAIRMAN THE WHITE MOUNTAIN APACHE TRIBE FORT APACHE INDIAN RESERVATION, ARIZONA SENATE COMMITTEE ON INDIAN AFFAIRS

SAMPLE ACCEPTABLE APPELLANT'S OPENING BRIEF DOMESTIC RELATIONS CASE

Chapter 3 Planning Issues, Opportunities, and Constraints

Feasibility Study Proposal & Report Guide. Industrial Optimization Program

Application by Fleet National Bank, Providence, Rhode Island, to establish Fleet Life Insurance Company and Fleet Insurance Company: 98-ML

WHAT IS ECONOMICS. MODULE - 1 Understanding Economics OBJECTIVES 1.1 MEANING OF ECONOMICS. Notes

COMMERCIAL LOAN SUBSIDY AGREEMENT. THIS AGREEMENT, by and between the COMMUNITY REDEVELOPMENT

There are essentially five rules in Arkansas

6. Debt Valuation and the Cost of Capital

FROM: Tammye Treviño (Signed by Tammye Treviño) Administrator Housing and Community Facilities Programs

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

United States General Accounting Office GAO. High-Risk Series. February Farm Loan Programs GAO/HR-95-9

1. Fill in the blanks for the following sentence: A rise in taxes on households will shift AD to the, this will push.

a) State and Local Taxes Bankruptcy Code 346, 728 and 1146.

Chapter 10 Fiscal Policy Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

TIPS. Performance Monitoring and Evaluation BUILDING A RESULTS FRAMEWORK. What Is a Results Framework? What Functions Does a Results Framework Serve?

OPINION NO (October 17, 1990)

HELP Interest Rate Options: Equity and Costs

So let s go back in time, revisit and discuss the assumptions and hypothesis of our esteemed predecessors.

Evaluating Costs anti Benefits in Health Care

Legal Memorandum Format Sample

The following text represents the notes on which Mr. Parry based his remarks. 1998: Issues in Monetary Policymaking

x = %ΔX = rate of change of spending m = %ΔM = rate of change of the money supply v = %ΔV = rate of change of the velocity of money

Econ 202 Section 2 Midterm 2

) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) )

Update on Clean Renewable Energy Bonds. by Doug Lamb. Introduction & Background

Medicare, Workers Compensation, and Liability Insurance

Maps A Primer for Content & Production of Topographic Base Maps For Design Presented by SurvBase, LLC

Transcription:

Comments on Current Issues Editor's Note In addition to being outstanding scholars in their fields, the authors of this paper have served as expert witnesses for the United States and/or Indian Tribes in a number of Indian water rights cases. Given the importance of the issues raised here for the on-going development of water law, the Journal is planning a later issue which will more fully develop the debate as to how one "appropriately" measures economic feasibility, involving scholars who have considered this problem from divergent points of view. H. S. Burness,* R. G. Cummings,* W. D. Gorman,** and R. R. Lansford** The "New" Arizona v. California: Practicably Irrigable Acreage and Economic Feasibility I. INTRODUCTION The Arizona v. California case was reopened for the purpose of adjudicating water rights for omitted and boundary lands on the several Indian Reservations. The Master's Report in this case has been submitted to the U.S. Supreme Court.I While the Court has yet to act on specific recommendations in the Master's Report, principles for interpreting the practicably irrigable acreage rule for quantifying the Indian's reserved (Winters) water rights adopted by the Master are of interest given their potential for establishing important precedent in water rights law. In this regard, and briefly stated, the Master concludes that: "For present purposes, a finding that annual benefits exceed costs will suffice for afinding of practicable irrigability (emphasis added)." 2 Thus, economic feasibility is established as the means for demonstrating practicably irrigable acreage 3 which, in turn, serves to quantify water reserved to the tribes. In setting this standard, the Special Master dem- *Department of Economics, University of New Mexico. **Department of Agricultural Economics, New Mexico State University. 1. In the Supreme Court of the United States, October Term, 1981, Arizona v. California et al, Report of Elbert P. Tuttle, Special Master, February 22, 1982 (hereinafter referred to as Master's Report 1982). 2. Id. at 100; See also 94-100. 3. "... practicably irrigable... very nearly means economically feasible;" id. at 94.

NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [Vol. 22 onstrated (in our view) a remarkable facility in grasping the subtlety of relevant economic concepts in his analysis of testimony. Regretably, however, testimony from only one economic expert 4 precluded his consideration of at least three important and controversial aspects of benefitcost studies (most commonly used for measuring economic feasibility) which will surely be at issue in later cases. These aspects may be critical in choosing the structure of a benefit-cost study that will provide measures for economic feasibility which "... most nearly adhere to the law... " and include: the distinction between economic feasibility and financial feasibility; criteria which determine the scope of included benefits and costs; and criteria for discounting methods. In what follows we provide the reader with a brief sketch of issues relevant for those topics. II. FINANCIAL VERSUS ECONOMIC FEASIBILITY The Special Master had little trouble in recognizing the general distinction between economic and financial feasibility; thus, we have but a few clarifying comments to offer. Among his several observations in this regard, 6 in discussing the interest rate the Master concludes: "Because this was an economic analysis, the goal was not to determine the interest rate at which money could actually be borrowed. The United States, I believe, chose the correct approach, because the question of practicable irrigability turns upon economic rather than financial analysis." 7 Thus, in looking to economic feasibility-as opposed to financial feasibility which centers on the repayment issue-as indicative of a "practical" irrigation project, the Master follows the long-established precedent in U.S. reclamation policy wherein the assessment of a project's economic feasibility is an issue separate from (and first in priority to) issues related to repayment. 8 Thus, Leavitt Act provisions (for Indian projects) and "excess" power revenues (for non-indian projects) are relevant for repayment considerations but are not relevant for the assessment of economic feasibility. 9 Unfortunately, our earlier exposition concerning the appropriate role of Leavitt Act provisions in feasibility analysis" was seemingly unclear, leading the Master to conclude that our theme sug- 4. Id. at 141. 5. Id. at 95. 6. See, e.g., id. at 95-96 and 141. 7. Id. at 167. 8. This point is developed in 3 of Bumess, Cummings, Gorman, and Lansford, U.S. Reclamation Policy and Indian Water Rights, 20 NAT. RES. J. 807-26 (1980) (hereinafter Burness): "..it was clear that reimbursement was not to be used as a criterion for project feasibility" at 814. 9. See the Master's rejection of the use of subsidies for purposes of demonstrating economic feasibility in Master's Report 1982, supra note 1, at 95-96. 10. Burness, supra note 8, at 824.

July 1982] THE "NEW" ARIZONA V. CALIFORNIA gested the use of Leavitt Act deferment provisions as social benefits to offset project costs." It is important that this issue be clarified. Use of Leavitt Act provisions (or "excess" power revenues) in an assessment of economic feasibility has no foundation in theory or precedent, 2 "...such assessment is independent of repayment considerations."' III. THE SCOPE OF BENEFITS AND COSTS In terms of the scope of benefits and costs to be included in a study of economic feasibility, the most important issue is whether or not "secondary" benefits (and, it is to be understood, costs) are to be included. As distinguished from "primary" benefits (also called "direct" and/or National Economic Development, NED, benefits), usually measured as the increase in net farm income attributable to the irrigation project, secondary benefits are the increases in income and employment in other sectors of the economy that result from (for example) the increase in the project farmer's purchases of household items as well as machinery, equipment, fertilizers, etc. As long as the economy is not fully employed, such "secondary" increases in income that are induced by primary benefits may be regarded as every bit as much a social benefit as primary benefits and, properly measured, are included in the analysis of economic feasibility. Obviously, if the economy is fully employed, the project farmer's purchase of, for example, a tractor would not result in the economy's production of another tractor-the farmer's purchase would simply displace (at a likely cost in inflation) some other farmer's purchase of a tractor. In the case of full employment neither secondary nor primary (in many cases) 3 benefits would attend the project-resources would simply be shifted from one use to another with no net gain in employment or incomes. Secondary benefits were apparently not included in measures for economic feasibility put before the Master in the new Arizona v. California case, and the rationale for their exclusion involves an interesting issue for Indian water rights cases. Prior to 1973, direct and secondary benefits were used in all economic feasibility studies for reclamation projects. On the average, secondary benefits accounted for some 40% of agricultural benefits claimed for BuRec projects during this period. " Referring to Table 1, only six of the 28 projects built during this period in the Rocky 11. Master's Report 1982, supra note 1, at 96 n. 17. 12. Burness, supra note 8, at 824. 13. Primary and secondary benefits can result in the full employment case when resources are shifted to higher valued uses, as in the case of primary benefits where land is put under irrigation. In a strictly technical sense, this would not be the full-employment case inasmuch as some resourceswater-were not fully employed. 14. Burness, supra note 8, at 819, Table 2.

NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [Vol. 22 TABLE 1 Historical Measures for Benefit-Cost Ratios Direct Agricultural Direct and Project Benefits Only Secondary Benefits Angostura.36.90 Bluff.45 1.45 Boysen.77.78 Canyon Ferry.59 1.46 Crow Creek.34.76 East Branch.95 1.93 Eden.53 1.17 Ft. Clark.41.73 Garrison 1.15 2.26 Glendo 1.51 1.47 Hanover.43 1.74 Heart Butte.61 1.42 Helena Valley.59 1.42 Lyman.60.79 Navajo.31 1.03 Oahe 1.32 2.20 Owl Creek.49.94 Preston Bench.34.34 Provo River 1.08 1.88 Rapid Valley.32 1.58 San Felipe 1.87 2.71 San Juan-Chama.55 1.02 Seedskadee.52 1.54 Shadehill.57 1.11 Shoshone.39 1.34 Vale 1.80 2.33 Weber.96 1.50 Yellowtail.51.92 AVERAGE.72 1.38 (Number of Projects) (28) (28) RANGE:.31-1.87.34-2.71 Source: Data from studies prepared by the Bureau of Reclamation; values in these studies are adjusted to constant 1978 dollars.

July 1982] THE "NEW" ARIZONA V. CALIFORNIA Mountain and Pick-Sloan regions would have passed the Master's test for practicable irrigability without the inclusion of secondary benefits. 5 In 1973 the Water Resources Council (WRC) published its principles and standards for analyzing the economic feasibility of water and land-related projects,' 6 and the general policy of the United States attorneys has been that prevailing WRC guidelines are to be followed in preparing measures for economic feasibility. Secondary benefits are not included in benefitcost measures under the WRC's 1973 (and later amended) 7 guidelines and, therefore, were not included in measures put before the Master in this case. The exclusion of secondary benefits from WRC-mandated benefit-cost measures results from a critical assumption-recognized by the WRC as "somewhat arbitrary"' -required by the WRC for benefit-cost studies, viz., one must assume that the economy is fully employed.' 9 The relevance of the above for the rule by which economic feasibility implies practicably irrigable acreage is then immediately apparent: what scope of benefits is appropriate for demonstrating economic feasibility? Prior to 1973, during which the bulk of Western waters were developed, full employment was not assumed and economic feasibility encompassed secondary benefits; between 1973-1982, full employment became a required planning assumption and secondary benefits were excluded from measures of economic feasibility. Oddly enough, the economy was more fully employed during the 1960-1973 period, when the average unemployment rate was 4.9%, than after the time at which the full employment assumption was required-the average unemployment rate between 1973 and 1980 was 6.8%. With the planned dismantling of the WRC, 2 planning standards for 1982 and the future may or may not require the full employment assumption; at this point, standards are simply unclear. Given, as shown above, that planning standards change from time to time, and that the effects of such changes vis-a-vis the substance of benefitcost measures may not be trivial, 2 ' the equity implications of measuring the feasibility of a right which is "reserved" through time with standards 15. Of the 28 constructed projects, eight fail the test with secondary benefits when values are adjusted to 1978 dollars; in current dollars, however, most projects had benefit-cost ratios greater than I when secondary benefits are included. 16. Economic Feasibility Standards, 38 Fed. Reg. 24, 777 (1973). 17. Amendments to Economic Feasibility Standards, 45 Fed. Reg. Part 11, Sec. 711.61 (1980). 18. Id. at 64,384; see response to Comment No. 202 at 64384. 19. 38 Fed. Reg., supra note 16, and 45 Fed. Reg., supra note 17; see particularly WRC response to Comment No. 127, at 64379. 20. 47 Fed. Reg. 12,296 (1982). 21. This point is forcefully made by comparing pre-1973 and post-1973 benefit-cost measures given in Table I.

NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL [Vol. 22 extant at a particular moment in time 22 pose an (as yet) unanswered challenge in water rights law. IV. DISCOUNTING METHODS There is probably no topic in economics about which more has been written, and less understood, than the question as to how one chooses an appropriate rate of discount. In the case at hand, the United States' economist is reported to have stated that the federal discount rate is commonly used for economic analyses. 23 The term "federal discount rate" is ambiguous 24 and may refer to the Federal Reserve's discount rate, the OMB-mandated discount or, most likely, the discount rate required by the WRC which is, for obvious reasons, the rate commonly used for assessing federal projects. The fact that the WRC discount rate is commonly used for federal reclamation projects (indeed, its use for such purposes is mandated by Congress) 25 does not, however, make its use unequivocally appropriate for determining practicably irrigable acreage. Given the space allowed here, we can only touch on this extraordinarily complex issue; we hope to give the subject more comprehensive treatment in a later work. However, the following are a few of the major issues relevant for considerations regarding an "appropriate" discount rate. (a) the discount rate must be a real, inflation-free rate; as recognized by the WRC, 26 the WRC rate (used in the new Arizona v. California) is not a real rate. (b) in cases where streams of benefit/costs affecting future needs across multiple, future generations are involved in an analysis of economic feasibility, serious questions arise as to the ethical implications of discounting. 27 (c) widely different ranges for "appropriate" social discount rates depend on one's assumptions as to whether consumption or investment is displaced by the project. 22. The WRC's 1973 standards made explicit that such standards were subject to change as the WRC determines that "... experience, research, and planning conditions dictate," 45 Fed. Reg., supra note 17, at 716.6. 23. Master's Report 1982, supra note I, at 167. 24. It is likely, and understandable, that the U.S. economist's precise jargon was slightly altered in the Master's Report. 25. Act of August 4, 1939, Pub. L. No. 76-260, 53 Stat. 1187 (1939). 26. U.S. WATER RESOURCES COUNCIL, OPTIONS FOR THE DISCOUNT RATE 15 (Nov. 1975). 27. As one example, see Schulze, Brookshire, and Sandier, The Social Role of Discount for Nuclear Waste Storage: Economics or Ethics?, 21 NAT. RES. J. 811-32 (1981). Indeed, the "future needs" dimension of reserved rights raises questions as to the appropriateness of benefit/cost analysis per se as a means for demonstrating feasibility.

July 1982] THE "NEW" ARIZONA V. CALIFORNIA 523 (d) computational issues raise a host of other conceptual problems, not the least of which are those associated with the question as to how risk and taxes are to be treated in the selection of a social discount rate.