Cost implications of no-fault automobile insurance. By: Joseph E. Johnson, George B. Flanigan, and Daniel T. Winkler



Similar documents
CHAPTER 2 THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN NO-FAULT INSURANCE AND DRIVER BEHAVIOR

Chapter 11 Auto Insurance in the United States (continued)

The Florida Senate POTENTIAL IMPACT OF MANDATING BODILY INJURY LIABILITY INSURANCE FOR MOTOR VEHICLES. Interim Project Summary November 1998

Will No-Fault Insurance Cost More Or Less?

AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE: THE MINNESOTA NO-FAULT AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE LAW

Empirical Comparisons of the Contributory versus Comparative Negligence Rules. Michelle J. White

Office of Insurance Regulation

No-Fault Automobile Insurance

Florida No-Fault Auto Insurance: A Historical Primer

Car Insurance: Is No-Fault the Answer? Ryan C. Hayward The College of New Jersey

By: Daniel T. Winkler, Ph.D., George B. Flanigan, Ph.D., CPCU, and Joseph E. Johnson, DBA, CPCU

The key conclusions of this report are:

No-Fault Automobile Insurance in the United States

NO-FAULT INSURANCE IN OTHER STATES

Changing Tort Reform In Kentucky Christel Siglock. By changing its current No-Fault and Tort law options, Kentucky could; 1) Reduce the

The Relationship Between Auto Insurance Rate Regulation and Insured Loss Costs: An Empirical Analysis

FORECASTING DEPOSIT GROWTH: Forecasting BIF and SAIF Assessable and Insured Deposits

THE EFFECT OF NO-FAULT ON FATAL ACCIDENT RATES

THE TOP 10 QUESTIONS YOU SHOULD ASK YOUR CAR ACCIDENT LAWYER

NAIC. No-Fault Auto Insurance: A Survey. National Association of Insurance Commissioners PROPERTY & CASUALTY INSURANCE (C) COMMITTEE

Motorcyclists and the Michigan No-Fault Law

The Incentive Effects of No Fault Automobile Insurance

No Fault/PIP/First Party Medical States

Motorists and insurers have been deeply concerned about rising auto insurance costs

No-Fault Auto Insurance

Moral Hazard in the French Workers Compensation System

We understand also that Temple University, through the Ford Foundation. studied this system and plans to issue a report in August, 1966.

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE AND ACCIDENT LIABILITY LAWS ON TRAFFIC FATALITIES. Alma Cohen Rajeev Dehejia

COST DIFFERENCES OF DISTRIBUTION SYSTEMS BY LINE IN THE PROPERTY AND LIABILITY INSURANCE INDUSTRY. Abstract. Introduction

RISK RESPONSIBILITY REALITY APPENDIX D AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE IN CANADA

This is Multirisk Management Contracts: Auto, chapter 14 from the book Enterprise and Individual Risk Management (index.html) (v. 1.0).

Introduction to Regression and Data Analysis

State of Colorado. Auto Insurance/Trauma System Study. Final Report. February 18, Prepared for

Chapter 5: Analysis of The National Education Longitudinal Study (NELS:88)

16 : Demand Forecasting

THE RELATION BETWEEN TORT LAW ENVIRONMENT AND AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COSTS American Risk and Insurance Association annual meeting

The Effects of No Fault on Automobile Insurance

Before the recent passage of CRS , claims for subrogation

RIGHT Lawyers. Stacy Rocheleau, Esq. Gary Thompson, Esq.

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Buyer Beware. Things To Know About Buying Car Insurance In Washington State. By Christopher M. Davis, Attorney at Law

New York Car Accident Lawyers

LOUISIANA PERSONAL INJURY ACCIDENT BASICS

New Jersey Car Insurance Checklist

Testing The Quantity Theory of Money in Greece: A Note

SUMMARY OF PENNSYLVANIA AUTO INSURANCE LAW

Auto Insurance. No-Fault: Michigan's Unique Auto Insurance Law. Personal Injury Protection (PIP)

FIXED EFFECTS AND RELATED ESTIMATORS FOR CORRELATED RANDOM COEFFICIENT AND TREATMENT EFFECT PANEL DATA MODELS

NEW YORK STATE BAR ASSOCIATION. LEGALEase. If You Have An Auto Accident SAMPLE

Exploratory Analysis of Marketing Data: Trees vs. Regression

Percent change. Rank Most expensive states Average expenditure Rank Least expensive states Average expenditure

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications

How To Get Insurance In Kentucky

Prepared by: Barton L. Slavin, Esq Web site:

How do Labor Market Conditions Affect the Demand for Law School? January Jeffrey Greenbaum. Massachusetts Institute of Technology

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF STATE LEGISLATION IN MITIGATING MORAL HAZARD: EVIDENCE FROM AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE* DAVID B. MUSTARD, University of Georgia.

Simple Linear Regression Inference

Employer-Provided Health Insurance and Labor Supply of Married Women

MEASURING FRAUD IN INSURANCE INDUSTRY: THE CASE OF AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE IN TAIWAN

SENATE STAFF ANALYSIS AND ECONOMIC IMPACT STATEMENT

Background Paper 79-5 PRODUCT LIABILITY

NEW JERSEY AUTO INSURANCE BUYER S GUIDE

SYSTEMS OF REGRESSION EQUATIONS

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS

Financial Risk Management Exam Sample Questions/Answers

Auto Insurance. No-Fault: Michigan's Unique Auto Insurance Law. Personal Injury Protection (PIP)

* the definition and nature of personal injury protection (PIP) benefits; * the difference between coordinated and uncoordinated policies; and

Supreme Court of Florida

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE MIDDLE DISTRICT OF GEORGIA VALDOSTA DIVISION. Plaintiff, Civil Action No. 7:12-CV-148 (HL) ORDER

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF CONNECTICUT. Israel : : v. : No. 3:98cv302(JBA) : State Farm Mutual Automobile : Insurance Company et al.

THE SWEDISH TRAFFIC DAMAGE ACT. A short introduction Warsaw 21 March 2011

Auto Insurance Buyers Guide

How To Know If A Motor Vehicle Is Uninsured

MARYLAND AUTO INSURANCE

SENATE STAFF ANALYSIS AND ECONOMIC IMPACT STATEMENT. This bill substantially amends the following section of the Florida Statutes:

The Michigan Auto Insurance Report

NEW YORK STATE INSURANCE DEPARTMENT REGULATION NO. 153 (11 NYCRR 163) FLEXIBLE RATING FOR NONBUSINESS AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE POLICIES

PROTECTED? By George T. Sinas

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

CANAL INSURANCE COMPANY INDEMNITY COMPANY

Medical Costs of No-Fault Automobile Insurance

Table of Contents. 1. What should I do when the other driver s insurance company contacts me?... 1

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Your Quick Reference for Florida Auto Accident Law

WRONGFUL DISCLAIMERS OF UM and UIM COVERAGE UNDER BUSINESS AUTO POLICIES

****************************************************** The officially released date that appears near the beginning of each opinion is the date the

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

DEMAND FOR AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE IN THE UNITED STATES

An Analysis of Automobile Insurance Choice in Pennsylvania

Plaintiff moves the Court for judgment in the amount of. The question before the Court is whether the

How To Understand The History Of No Fault Insurance In Michigan

QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS ABOUT ILLINOIS AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE AND ACCIDENTS

FLORIDA PERSONAL INJURY PROTECTION

Chapter 10: Basic Linear Unobserved Effects Panel Data. Models:

IN THE COURT OF COMMON PLEAS FIRST JUDICIAL DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA TRIAL DIVISION CIVIL SECTION

International Comparisons of Litigation Costs. Europe, the United States and Canada

U.S Producer Price Index for Property and Casualty Insurance. Deanna Eggleston U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics

Transcription:

Cost implications of no-fault automobile insurance By: Joseph E. Johnson, George B. Flanigan, and Daniel T. Winkler Johnson, J. E., G. B. Flanigan, and D. T. Winkler. "Cost Implications of No-Fault Automobile Insurance," The Journal of Risk and Insurance, March 1992, pp. 116-123. Made available courtesy of Blackwell Publishing: http://www.wiley.com/bw/journal.asp?ref=0022-4367 The definitive version is available at www.blackwell-synergy.com Abstract: No fault advocates commonly predict automobile insurance cost savings for consumers in states adopting no-faults statutes in place of a tort system. For states implementing no-fault, the cost results have been mixed. This study compares the loss costs of no-fault from 1974 through 1985. Not surprisingly, the findings suggest that the bodily injury liability loss costs were lower on average in no-fault states than in tort states after controlling for the influence of wages, population density, and the presence of comparative negligence. However, total bodily injury related costs were not significantly lower on average in no-fault states, and they were significantly higher in states with compulsory add-on laws and to a lesser extent in states with high tort thresholds. Whether the lack of estimated cost savings on average in no-fault states in attributable to selection bias or not, the causes of this result are important issues for further research. Article: No fault has again become a subject of debate following several years of inactivity. Leading advocates of the adoption of new no-fault law, or modification of current statutes to further restrict tort remedy, are predominantly insurance companies and some consumer groups. Opponents of no-fault reform are principally members of the trial bar. Over the period of 1971 to 1987, 24 states plus the District of Columbia and Puerto Rico adopted forms of no-fault. Very little movement towards no-fault took place after the mid 1970s aside from a few states changing their tort thresholds and Pennsylvania moving from low thresholds no-fault toward a compulsory add-on-no-fault.(1) The question of whether no-fault laws reduce the cost of automobile insurance remains unsettled. A report by the Department of Transportation (1985) suggests that cost savings result from nofault, and compulsory add-on results in higher cost than no tort or no-fault. The DOT study, however, did not control for some important causal factors. Johnson, Flanigan and Weeks (1983) found that cost savings were not present under no-fault. They failed to differentiate between certain types of no-fault and did not control for individual state effects. A recent study by Smith (1989) compares the projected cost of automobile reparations for no-faults states had they remained fault and argues that some no-fault laws have produced significant cost savings. Smith relies upon opinions of what a claim would have been under different assumptions. Problems and limitations of this approach are discussed by Todd (1976).

The purpose of this study is to measure average automobile insurance costs under different automobile reparations systems. This study employs actual insurance loss cost data over the period 1974 to 1985 in a multi-variate context. Analysis of loss cost data does not support the hypothesis that no-fault systems have had lower costs than fault systems when all automobile insurance costs for bodily injury are included. The possibility of selection bias is briefly discussed in the concluding section. Research Methods and Data Total system (i.e. bodily injury related) loss costs for automobile reparations consists of losses covered by bodily injury liability, medical payments, uninsured motorist, and personal injury protection insurance. The loss of concept incorporates both frequency and severity. The database is constructed from annual data compiled by the Insurance Service Office (ISO) for both voluntary and residual markets. The data are incurred losses, including loss adjustment expenses, on an earned car year basis. Forty seven of the 50 states are included for the period 1974 through 1985 (Massachusettes, South Carolina, and Texas did not report to the ISO). Reparations systems were categorized into six classes: verbal threshold, high threshold, low threshold, optional add-on no-fault, compulsory add-on no-fault and tort states. Each classification is briefly described below: 1. Verbal: Injured party actions are barred except when permanent injury, death, or disfigurement results or when economic losses are uncompensated. No-fault advocates allege that verbal is the least cost alternative (Smith, 1989). 2. High threshold: Injured party actions are barred except when the dollar amount of their economic losses exceeds a relatively high specified amount. Thresholds of more than $1,000 are considered high.(2) 3. Low threshold: Injured party actions are barred except when the dollar amount of economic losses exceeds a relatively low specified amount. Thresholds of less than or equal to $1,000 are considered low. 4. Compulsory add-on: The tort system is retained but no-fault benefits are compulsorily included. 5. Optional add-on" Policy holders must be offered the opportunity to purchase optional add-on no-fault benefits with no changes in the underlying tort liability system. 6. Tort: No limitations on the right to seek recovery in tort and no compulsory or optional addon no-fault benefits. The analysis considers 12 years of loss experience by state as classified above beginning in 1974. The tested hypothesis is that no-fault systems have lower average per car loss costs than does the tort system. No-fault systems would be less expensive if the total system loss costs were lower under no-fault than tort, controlling for extraneous influences. Regression Analysis Multiple regression is used to compare the cost of each no-fault classification to the cost of tort holding constant independent factors. The independent variables are contributory negligence or comparative negligence, population per square mile, and manufacturing wages.

Flanigan, et. al. (1989) found that comparative negligence states have higher loss costs than contributory negligence states because plaintiffs are able to recover when partially at fault. The plaintiff must be free of fault in contributory negligence states. Population per square mile captures the effects of greater vehicular traffic congestion and consequent accidents. Manufacturing wages are used as a proxy for wage and price level difference among states. Automobile loss costs are influenced by many components which clearly differ among states and over time. For example, medical care costs, disability income loss, the cost of processing claims, and legal fees influence loss costs. A consumer price index by state is not available. The use of this proxy is supported by the fact of mobility in the labor force calibrating wages with the cost of living over time.(3) The regression analysis applies a covariance model and an error components model (Fuller and Battese, 1974) which are commonly used regression techniques for time-series-cross-sectional data analysis.(4) The findings are reported utilizing both models. Results Table 1 presents the OLS, covariance, and Fuller-Battese error components model regression with the dependent variable BI (bodily injury costs) and independent variables for no-fault system, negligence system, population density, and wages.(5) The discussion will focus on the covariance and error-components model findings. Both models report substantively similar results in this study. TABULAR DATA OMITTED] The results indicate that for verbal, low threshold, and high threshold no-fault systems, auto insurance costs were on average significantly lower than tort when only bodily injury liability costs are considered. The estimate for verbal thresholds is $14.79 lower than tort and that for low threshold states is $14.77 less than tort, per earned car year. The high threshold states have estimated costs on average of $7.87 less than tort. The finding of lower costs under low- versus high-threshold systems is unanticipated. There is considerable heterogeneity within each class. Special provisions in "out-of-balance" no-fault law might result in particular no-fault benefits in high threshold states exceeding the benefits in lowthreshold states, despite the higher threshold.(6) Estimated costs for optional add-on and compulsory add-on are greater than the tort system, although the differences are not statistically significant. The covariance model shows somewhat larger savings for each of the no-fault systems. The relative ranking is consistent with the error components model. These findings are as predicted, since the nature of no-fault is to preclude lawsuits. The second stage of the analysis includes all bodily injury related costs including bodily injury liability, medical payments, uninsured motorist, and personal injury protection. These results are presented in Table 2. The OLS findings show considerably higher estimated costs in verbal, high threshold, optional add-on and compulsory add-on states than in tort. However, the apparent cost

differentials associated with OLS disappear under the covariance and error components analyses. The covariance and error components results indicate that although no-fault systems have higher estimated costs than tort, only the estimate for compulsory add-on is highly significant, with an estimated cost of $35.73 to $53.90 higher than tort. The estimated coefficient for high threshold using error components suggests a higher cost of $12.37 compared with the tort system, and is significant at the.10 level. The covariance estimate of $6.49, however, is not statistically significant. Conclusions This study considers the magnitude of automobile insurance losses under various reparations systems. The findings show that states with verbal, low threshold, and high threshold no-fault law have lower bodily injury liability loss costs. Consistent with conventional wisdom, states with the least expensive bodily injury liability costs are those with verbal threshold no-fault laws. When total bodily injury related loss costs are considered, the cost advantage of no-fault systems disappears. After controlling for extraneous influences, total bodily injury related loss costs on average were not less under no-fault systems than the tort system. These results suggests increase in first-party personal injury protection costs under no-fault on average were large enough to offset the reduction in liability costs, even in states with high monetary and verbal thresholds. Compulsory add-on, which combines higher costs of first-party insurance with unrestricted tort liability, appears to have been the most expensive system. These results must be interpreted with some caution given the possibility of selection bias. Some states could have changed from a tort to a no-fault system to curb escalating insurance costs. If states adopting no-fault had higher costs prior to no-fault adoption which cannot be explained by comparative negligence, wages, or population density, the omitted factors will influence the coefficient estimates of the no-fault dummy variables. To provide come insight into this issue, models also were estimated for the percentage change in bodily injury or total costs as the dependent variable. The independent variables were percentage change in hourly wages, population density, no-fault and comparative negligence dummies; an additional variable captured the possible transition effects during the year that no-fault was adopted or changed. Neither the bodily injury nor total cost regression had very much explanatory power, and the results provided no evidence that growth rates in loss costs were lower in no-fault states. Nonetheless, the possibility of selection bias remains a concern which future research might resolve. Finally, the models estimated are admittedly simple. While this might increase the likelihood of omitted variable bias, the inclusion of additional control variables to reflect numerous factors that might effect costs could raise endogeneity issues and increase the likelihood of problems with multicollinearity. (1) A table indicating the month and year of tort and no-fault system changes for the 50 states is available for review by interested researchers. The data analyzed in this study are also available upon request. (2) The $1,000 threshold is concern with Smith (1989). Although the threshold level would appear to be a continuous variable, the threshold level normally remains unchanged for several or more years. (3) A number of possible independent variables were considered and rejected due to unavailability of data. Some alternative independent variables were tested. For example, daily hospital costs (to the hospital) was substituted for manufacturing wages in the cost regressions to test the model's robustness. The qualitative implications remain unchanged;

bodily injury costs remain less expensive under low threshold, high threshold and verbal nofault, however these cost savings are not present when total system costs are incorporated in the analysis. However, both verbal and high threshold systems appear more expensive than tort with this model. The daily hospitals costs coefficient was positive and highly significant in both regressions. (4) A covariance model treats loss costs as a function of the particular state (class) and the level of each of exogenous variable, where the data transformed into differences from the unit mean and least squares is applied to the transformed data without an intercept term. Because the wage variable effectively captures the trend in costs (by state) overtime, the simultaneous inclusion of these time dummies and wages generates excessive collinearity problems. In addition to the covariance model, the cost findings using the Fuller and Battese (1974) (crosssection and time effects) error components model are reported. If the random effects are normally distributed, the error components model can be shown to be more efficient than the covariance model, while giving unbiased and consistent parameter estimates provided that the random effects are uncorrelated with the other regressors (Pindyck and Rubinfield, 1981). The covariance and error components models imply different assumptions. The covariance model applies if inferences are made about specific cross-sectional units in a study (Hsiao, 1986). The error components model pertains if the inferences are made about the population of all classes. The two models sometimes produce substantially different empirical results (Hsiao, 1986). To allow for serial correlation in the disturbances in the covariance models, the parameter estimates were obtained assuming a first-order autoregressive process. First, the individual unit mean was subtracted from each observation for both the dependent and independent variables. Next, the autocorrelation coefficient was determined for each cross-sectional unit using GLS, and the serial correlation was eliminated. The covariance method was then applied to the transformed model (see Hsiao, 1986). The error components model assumes that the correlation of successive residuals is constant and independent of the period of time between disturbance terms (Pindyck and Rubinfield, 1981). (5) The Pearson correlation coefficients of the independent variables indicate that the independent regressors appear free of significant collinearity problems. Regressions with fewer no-fault dummy variables yield comparable results to those reported in Tables 1 and 2. The full correlation results are available from the authors. (6) For example, Georgia and Kansas are both low threshold states with $500 thresholds (during the analysis period). However, Georgia limits benefits to $5,000 and Kansas has an overall limit of $28,925. On the other hand, Utah's threshold was $3,000 (unit 7/86) and is classified as a high threshold state even though its overall benefit limit was $14,180 in 1987. Reference Compilation, Automobile Liability Experience, 1971-1985, (New York: Insurance Services Office). Flanigan, George B., Joseph E. Johnson, Daniel T. Winkler, and William Ferguson, 1989, Experience from Early Tort Reform: Comparative Negligence Since 1974, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 56: 525-34. Fuller, Wayne A. and George E. Battese, 1974, Estimation of Linear Models with Crossed-Error Structure, Journal of Econometrics, 2: 67-78.

Harrington, Scott, 1987, A Note on the Impact of Auto Insurance Rate Regulation, The Review of Economics and Statistics, March: 166-70. Hsiao, Cheng, 1986, Analysis of Panel Data, Econometric Society monographs no. 11, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). J ohnson, Joseph E., George B. Flanigan, and James K. Weeks, 1983, An Empirical Investigation of the Cost of Adopting No-Fault Insurance Systems, Journal of Insurance Regulation, 2: 168-75. Kimball, Spencer L., 1985, The Context of ~No-Fault,' Journal of Risk and Insurance, 52: 663-66. O'Connell, Jeffrey and Robert H. Joost, 1986, Giving Motorists a Choice Between Fault and No- Fault Insurance, Virginia Law Review, 72: 61-89. Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel L. Rubinfield, 1981, Econometric Models and Economic Forecasts, (New York: McGraw-Hill Inc.). Smith, Brian W., 1989, Reexamining the Cost Benefits of No-Fault, CPCU Journal, March: 28-36. Todd, Jerry D., 1976, The Costing of No-Fault Automobile Insurance, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 43: 432-43. U.S. Dept. of Transportation, 1985, Compensating Auto Accident Victims: A Followup Report on No-Fault Auto Insurance Experience, 18.