LIFE-CYCLE PORTFOLIOS AS GOVERNMENT POLICY ROBERT J. SHILLER COWLES FOUNDATION PAPER NO. 1182



Similar documents
Policy Brief. Social Security. Portfolio Theory, Life-Cycle Investing, and Retirement Income. Introduction. Portfolio Theory

Economic Brief. Investing over the Life Cycle: One Size Doesn t Fit All

TOOLS FOR FINANCIAL INNOVATION: NEOCLASSICAL VERSUS BEHAVIORAL FINANCE ROBERT J. SHILLER COWLES FOUNDATION PAPER NO. 1180

Peer Reviewed. Abstract

The Economists Voice

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Personal Accounts and Social Security Reform

Managing Home Equity to Build Wealth By Ray Meadows CPA, CFA, MBA

Basic Truths About Portfolio Management: A Consensus View Among the Experts By William Reichenstein

The Economists Voice

Thank you very much. I am honored to follow one of my heroes

Your Future On The Market

Are Managed-Payout Funds Better than Annuities?

Individual Savings Behavior: Lessons from Economic Research and Implications for Public Policy

Insights. Investment strategy design for defined contribution pension plans. An Asset-Liability Risk Management Challenge

A Better Approach to Target Date Strategies

An Improved Measure of Risk Aversion

Investment Company Institute and the Securities Industry Association. Equity Ownership

How Much Should I Save for Retirement? By Massi De Santis, PhD and Marlena Lee, PhD Research

The Economists Voice

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE RETIREMENT

Raising the Bar: Pumping Up Retirement Savings

Why Did House Prices Drop So Quickly?

Defined Contribution Plans for Passive Investors

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Household Finance. Household Finance, JF August 2006

Life-cycle Finance and the Dimensional Managed DC Solution By Wade Pfau May 22, 2012

Interest Rates and Inflation: How They Might Affect Managed Futures

The Economists Voice

Diversification Across Time

Global Demographic Trends and their Implications for Employment

Draft. This article challenges two features of. Calculating Asset Allocation WILLIAM REICHENSTEIN

Investment Return Assumptions for Public Funds

Mutual Fund Investing Exam Study Guide

Conventional wisdom tells us that stocks tend to outperform

Sustainable Withdrawal Rates From Your Retirement Portfolio

HERE S THE FLOOR PLAN FOR PROTECTION, PARTIAL PRIVATIZATION OF SOCIAL SECURITY. By: Carol Caruthers, M.S.P.A., E.A.

THE RESPONSIBILITY TO SAVE AND CONTRIBUTE TO

Investment Section INVESTMENT FALLACIES 2014

TIAA-CREF INSTITUTE: TRENDS AND ISSUES

The actual financing costs of English higher education student loans

Our Interview with William F. Sharpe

Public Pension Crisis and Investment Risk Taking: Underfunding, Fiscal Constraints, Public Accounting, and Policy Implications

Al l o c at i o n St r at e g i e s f o r Ret i r e m e n t Sav i n g:

It s Time to Save for Retirement. The Benefit of Saving Early and the Cost of Delay

Is a 30-Year Mortgage Preferable to a 15-Year Mortgage?

<A>Introduction<A> The U.S. retirement system has experienced a substantial transformation in recent years.

Stock Prices and Business Investment

Mental-accounting portfolio

Testimony for the ERISA Advisory Council on Ways to Help Participants Make Better Decisions in Risk-Transfer Transactions

Retirement Savings: Choosing a Withdrawal Rate That Is Sustainable

Flash!A Financial Guide for Friends and Alumni of Pomona College (800)

Modelling Corporate Bonds

Using Behavioral Economics to Improve Diversification in 401(k) Plans: Solving the Company Stock Problem

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Individual Retirement Accounts and Saving

The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral

A RETIREMENT DATE IS NOT A COMPLETE STRATEGY Target Date Funds are only Part of the Solution

Estimating the True Cost of Retirement

Cost-of-Living-Adjusted Annuities vs. Fixed Income Alternatives

For Better or For Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Savings Behavior

Retirement Planning Software and Post-Retirement Risks: Highlights Report

Stock Market Fluctuations and Retiree Incomes: An Update

An International Perspective on Safe Withdrawal Rates from Retirement Savings: The Demise of the 4 Percent Rule?

Our time-tested approach to investing is very straightforward. And we re ready to make it work for you.

New Research: Reverse Mortgages, SPIAs and Retirement Income

Generational Aspects of Medicare. David M. Cutler and Louise Sheiner * Abstract

Retirement Investing: Analyzing the Roth Conversion Option*

WHOLE OF LIFE SUPERANNUATION

advisory & Brokerage consulting services Make Your Retirement Savings Last a Lifetime

In this article, we go back to basics, but

Insights. Did we spot a black swan? Stochastic modelling in wealth management

Rethinking Fixed Income

Geoff Considine, Ph.D.

TRENDS AND ISSUES Tax-Efficient Sequencing Of Accounts to Tap in Retirement

Estimating the effect of projected changes in the driving population on collision claim frequency

Your model to successful individual retirement investment plans

May Missing out: How much employer 401(k) matching contributions do employees leave on the table?

National Savings Rate Guidelines for Individuals. Executive Summary

New Research: Reverse Mortgages, SPIAs and Retirement Income

To Have and to Hold: An Analysis of Young Adult Debt

Instructor s Manual Chapter 12 Page 144

Today s Research on Aging P ROGRAM AND P OLICY I MPLICATIONS Issue 3, May 2007

The Illusion of Precision. Glidepaths STEPHEN SEXAUER CHIEF INVESTMENT OFFICER ALLIANZ GLOBAL INVESTORS SOLUTIONS

Should Americans Be Insuring Their Retirement Income?

Financial Planning in a Low Interest Rate Environment: The Good, the Bad and the Potentially Ugly

An Analysis of Investment Advice to Retirement Plan Participants ABSTRACT

Reality Retirement Planning: A New Paradigm for an Old Science by Ty Bernicke, CFP

Better Guidance on Matters of Life and Death

401(k) Plan Asset Allocation, Account Balances, and Loan Activity in 2011

Zero Estate Tax Strategy

Pension Funds Investing in Hedge Funds

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Perspectives on the Economics of Aging

@%C+DE !"#$%&'( 1)*L4=#*+.C+2))3)& .)$)&+/&#0* /4&)$5+67"' 87)9+:%;#*'%*

Life-Cycle Investing and Leverage: Buying Stock on Margin Can Reduce Retirement Risk

Geoff Considine, Ph.D.

MANAGED FUTURES AND HEDGE FUNDS: A MATCH MADE IN HEAVEN

SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM: work incentives ISSUE BRIEF NO. 6. Issue Brief No. 6. work incentives

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

MEETING THE FINANCIAL NEEDS OF RETIREES: a layering approach to building retirement income portfolios

Help in Defined Contribution Plans: 2006 Through 2010

Transcription:

LIFE-CYCLE PORTFOLIOS AS GOVERNMENT POLICY BY ROBERT J. SHILLER COWLES FOUNDATION PAPER NO. 1182 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 2006 http://cowles.econ.yale.edu/

The Economists Voice Volume 2, Issue 1 2005 Article 14 A Special Issue on Social Security Life-Cycle Portfolios as Government Policy Robert J. Shiller Summary A life-cycle portfolio for personal accounts within Social Security, such as President George Bush has proposed, would adjust risk exposure as a function of the worker s age. This would involve the government in making complex dynamic portfolio decisions for individuals. The conventional rule of thumb that workers should invest a percentage of their portfolio equal to roughly 100 minus their age in stocks appears to be far from optimal. Choosing the optimal portfolio requires considering issues of behavioral economics such as why people do not already invest optimally and what kinds of people will sign up for the life-cycle portfolio. KEYWORDS: Social Security, personal accounts, private accounts, lifetime portfolio allocation Yale University Copyright c 2005 by the authors. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior written permission of the publisher, bepress, which has been given certain exclusive rights by the author. The Economists Voice is produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress). http://www.bepress.com/ev

Shiller: Life-Cycle Portfolios as Government Policy 1 Academic economists, financial planners, and the designers of President George W. Bush s Social Security reform plan all seem to agree that investors should take a life-cycle approach to their portfolios in planning for retirement so that the portfolio changes with the investor s age to accord with changing risk exposures and preferences. This raises two issues, though. One is how to account for the human limits in managing portfolios that prevent many from dynamically adjusting their portfolios or from doing so well. The second issue is deciding what dynamic portfolio makes the most sense for the most people. The Bush plan for personal accounts in Social Security has something of an answer to the first problem which is to allow individuals to choose a life-cycle portfolio managed by the government for their personal account and to make such a plan the default for workers aged 47 and older unless the worker and spouse both sign a waiver indicating that they understand the risks of failing to follow a life-cycle plan. Since the life-cycle portfolio by itself (without mixing any of the other portfolios) is recommended as a solution to the portfolio management problem, and since the plan defaults all workers into the life-cycle account, one may conclude that the life-cycle plan is the centerpiece of the President s Social Security plan. It is the most important original idea in the President s plan. The second problem is more nettlesome. In fact, no one knows what the optimal portfolio is. Here I will report some disturbing findings. Using U.S. history as a guide, those who opt for the life-cycle portfolios that are common on Wall Street in lieu of ordinary social security benefits should expect no bonanza: expected returns would not be consistently more than the 3.0 percent per year offset that the worker must pay. 1 How can we evaluate and further develop the President s proposal and others like it? It will take some work. We must study the life-cycle options, consider the economic theory of lifetime portfolio management, and consider lessons from behavioral economics as well. Can the government really design a life-cycle portfolio that is a good approximation to the optimal dynamic portfolio for workers who choose the plan? President Bush has not yet specified the design for the life-cycle portfolio. Assuming that there is a significant chance that some variation on the Bush 1 To avoid depleting the Trust Fund, the President s Plan requires that the amounts diverted into personal accounts be cumulated at a 3% real interest rate, deducted from the personal account, and paid into the System by the worker upon retirement. Produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press, 2006

2 The Economists' Voice Vol. 2 [2005], No. 1, Article 14 proposal will eventually be adopted in the U.S. or another country, this is a time when economists have an unusually important role to play in policy formulation. The Modest Returns of Conventional Life-Cycle Portfolios The conventional wisdom or rule of thumb is that the percentage allocation of portfolios to stocks should be 100 minus age in years. Several commercially-offered life-cycle mutual funds follow approximately this rule. The Vanguard 2045 Fund, intended for people who plan to retire around 2045, invests nearly 90% in the stock market today, but the stock allocation will eventually scale down to correspond to that of their Vanguard Target Retirement Income Fund, which today has only about 20% in the stock market. The T Rowe Price 2040 fund, for people who plan to retire around 2040, has a target of 90% in stocks today, but this allocation will be eventually reduced until it matches that in their Retirement Income Fund, roughly 40% in stocks. President Bush has been promoting his personal accounts to the broad public substantially by extolling the high returns that people can expect to get from these funds. Often it seems that he is referring to the historically high returns in the stock market. But the life-cycle portfolio, not the 100% stocks portfolio, is the centerpiece of the plan. A life-cycle plan that makes the percent allocated to stocks something akin to the privately-offered life-cycle plans may do much worse than a 100% stocks portfolio since young people have relatively little income when compared to older workers. There is a hump-shaped age-earnings profile, with earnings peaking in middle years. The life-cycle portfolio would be heavily in the stock market (in the early years) only for a relatively small amount of money, and would pull most of the portfolio out of the stock market in the very years when earnings are highest. I have done a simulation study that investigates the outcomes of several life-cycle plans based on U.S. financial data 1871-2004. I used a long historical sample period to avoid relying on recent stock market data, which have shown abnormally high returns (over nine percent real on the Standard & Poor Composite over the last 25 years). In each simulation, I considered a typical individual contributing out of earnings to the personal accounts starting at age 21 and continuing until age 65, assuming that this individual s earnings follow the hump-shaped life-cycle pattern of the scaled medium earner defined by the Social Security Actuaries in their calculations. Using the data from 1871 to 2004, I extracted 91 44-year periods of data on stock market and bond market returns, http://www.bepress.com/ev/vol2/iss1/art14

Shiller: Life-Cycle Portfolios as Government Policy 3 and used each of these periods as an example of the possible investment performance for the 44 years that a future 21-year-old worker would work until retirement at 65. I found that with my baseline life-cycle portfolio that begins with 85% in stocks until age 30, then declining linearly to 20% in stocks at age 60, flat at 20% thereafter, the median internal rate of return on the portfolio is only 3.4%, hardly more than the 3% offset rate called for in the President s plan. Not surprisingly, 32% of the time the plan loses money after accounting for the offset: the worker is worse off at retirement from having chosen to participate in the life-cycle personal account. Worse yet, ten percent of the time the internal rate of return is less than 2.4%, and, accounting for the offset, the typical earner loses at least $21,000 (in present value of future benefits) upon retirement after the offset for having chosen the plan. In fact, however, the situation is probably even worse than that. The United States has been the most conspicuously successful economy in the world in the last century and more. A better assumption, then, is that the U.S. will experience something like the median world experience, and not its own remarkable success of the past. In an alternative simulation, I adjusted the stock market returns downward by 2.2 percentage points each year so that the geometric mean return 1871-2004 corresponded to median real stock market returns for 15 countries 1900-2000 found in Dimson, Marsh and Staunton [2002]. When the simulation was rerun with these data, the median internal rate of return on the baseline life-cycle portfolio was only 2.6%, which was less than the 3% offset rate. The investor loses money after the offset 71% of the time. The return is less than 1.4% ten percent of the time, far less than the 3% offset, thereby leaving the typical worker $45,000 behind upon retirement for having participated in the lifecycle plan. For some workers with little other resources in retirement, there would be substantial hardship. The fact that the life-cycle portfolio does so poorly so often suggests that the conventional rule is not optimal. The President may feel bound by conventional financial authority to use some already-established rule of thumb for the life-cycle plans, but if a strong enough case can be made for another plan, perhaps eventually such a plan could be offered. Produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press, 2006

4 The Economists' Voice Vol. 2 [2005], No. 1, Article 14 Would Other Life-Cycle Plans be Better? The median internal rate of return for a 100% stock portfolio with U.S. historical data was 5.9% (compared with 3.4% on the life-cycle portfolio) and it loses money with respect to the 3% offset only two percent of the time (compared with 32% of the time on the life-cycle portfolio). With the more realistic data adjusted for the entire world, the internal rate of return of a 100% stock portfolio was 3.7% (compared with 2.6% on the life-cycle portfolio with the same adjusted data), and it loses money 33% of the time (compared with 71% of the time on the life-cycle portfolio). The worst of the 91 outcomes is still worse for the 100% stocks portfolio than for the life-cycle portfolio, but still the overall advantages of stocks suggests that the baseline life-cycle portfolio is not aggressive enough. With these risky opportunities, it might seem that the optimal life-cycle portfolio would stay heavily in the stock market for longer than the rule of thumb suggests, allowing young and middle-aged people to partake of these opportunities. But maybe we would not counsel people in the last of their working years to be 100% in stocks. And, are we taking all factors into account in making such simple intuitive judgments? What, then, is the optimal life-cycle portfolio? Attention to economic theory suggests some interesting perspectives. In a celebrated 1969 paper, Paul Samuelson argued from theory that under plausible assumptions in the absence of labor income, the optimal life-cycle portfolio would not change the allocation to stocks through time. But Samuelson s paper led to other papers that pointed out that the labor income plays a critical role in the specification of a life-cycle portfolio (see Bodie, Merton and Samuelson [1992] and Campbell and Viceira [2002]). Younger people have a large proportion of their wealth in human capital, and we might consider this as part of their true portfolio, of which the portfolio invested in financial assets is only a part. Unfortunately, economists have no consensus about the implications of labor income for life-cycle portfolios. Modeling the stochastic properties of labor income in relation to financial markets involves a number of assumptions, and results vary substantially depending on these assumptions. Given that human capital is a large part of the portfolio of young people, and assuming that the high past returns on the stock market can be extrapolated into the future, it might seem that the life-cycle portfolio for young people should be invested far over 100% in the stock market. Luis Viceira [2001] found that for plausible parameter values, young individuals should place 300% or more of their investable portfolio into stocks. Doing this would mean borrowing far more http://www.bepress.com/ev/vol2/iss1/art14

Shiller: Life-Cycle Portfolios as Government Policy 5 heavily to buy stocks than current margin requirements allow, and would suggest that young people should be far more aggressive than the rule of thumb calls for. On the other hand, authors, who make different assumptions than Viceira about the correlation of portfolio returns with earned income, find that young people might be best to invest only 20% in stocks, and that portfolio allocations to stocks should rise with age, not fall with age as is commonly assumed (see Benzoni, Dufresne and Goldstein [2004] or Lynch and Tan [2004]). An important issue is the assumption of the persistence through time in the correlation of labor income with stock market returns; if the correlation is highly persistent, then investing in stocks can be highly risky for young people. The Importance of Behavioral Economics Life-cycle plans also raise fundamental issues of behavioral economics. President Bush s plan offers an example of the impact of behavioral economics, since it chooses to default people into the life-cycle portfolio starting at age 47. They will be automatically in the plan if they do nothing. This design feature is up-to-date with recent findings in behavioral economics (see Johnson and Goldstein [2003] and Choi [2005]). If we want to allow those people who plan carefully to make their active choices and to prevent people who do not plan carefully from making mistakes, it is best to make the default option appropriate for those who do not plan, and create a little trouble to deviate from the default option. Presumably, many of the people who make the effort to deviate from the default are people who think that they know what they are doing. There will also be some people who will sign the waiver even though they don t know what they are doing, and they will be protected by making the riskiest portfolio option not too risky, and by prohibiting leverage and short sales. The President s plan shows real attention to behavioral economics. But further reflection indicates that much more research in behavioral economics would need to be done to make a really attractive proposal for lifecycle accounts. If all individuals had solved the optimal life-time portfolio problem and were implementing it, then there would be no need for a personal account proposal for Social Security. People would already be investing in the optimal portfolio outside of the Social Security System, and would already be taking into account how financial markets interact with the social insurance implicit in the existing mandatory pay-as-you-go Social Security System as explained by Geanakoplos, Mitchell and Zeldes [2000]. The personal accounts Produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press, 2006

6 The Economists' Voice Vol. 2 [2005], No. 1, Article 14 plan makes sense only if people are not doing that, and if we think the government should make them do that, then we had better understand their errors. Consider people who have saved adequately over the life-cycle, but who are excessively fearful about risky investments like the stock market. They have invested their savings in excessively conservative investments. A design for a lifecycle account would then be to create an addition to their portfolio that corrects for the timidity of their portfolio, the personal account representing the difference between their actual portfolio and the optimal portfolio for them. Such a portfolio might well be much more heavily than 100% in the stock market for young people. Alternatively, consider people who have taken on excessively risky investments, as by participating in stock market or real estate bubbles. Recent years reveal many such people. A life-cycle portfolio designed for them would ideally correct for their excessive risk taking, underweighting or hedging the risky assets that they already have in their portfolio. Yet again, we must consider people who have not saved anything at all, and for whom Social Security is the only source of retirement income. One thing appears clear: if the President s plan is implemented with baseline life-cycle personal accounts, these no-savings people will be facing a substantial risk of financial hardship in their retirement. Since these might be the predominant group who will choose the life-cycle accounts, we must study these people. We must learn how their labor income and private insurance needs and choices differ from those of the general population. Consideration of the potential dangers to specific groups of people who might sign up in large numbers for the life-cycle accounts is a serious matter. Even if there is a relatively small group of people who will suffer extreme outcomes by signing up for a life-cycle portfolio that dramatically amplifies their mistakes, then the portfolio may come to be regarded in future decades as having a fatal flaw, and jeopardize the public s long-term commitment to the reformed Social Security System. Taking both rational-optimizing models and behavioral issues into account in designing the life-cycle portfolio will involve substantial work. Unless there is convincing economic research, it will be hard to deflect government planners from something close to the conventional rule of thumb that the percentage of stocks in the portfolio should be 100 minus age. Given the interest among legislators in implementing a life-cycle portfolio, designing a structure that will http://www.bepress.com/ev/vol2/iss1/art14

Shiller: Life-Cycle Portfolios as Government Policy 7 stand the test of time ought to be a major undertaking for the economics profession today. Robert J. Shiller is a professor of economics at Yale University and is widely read both inside and outside academia. Most recently, he is the author of Irrational Exuberance, 2 nd Edition, 2005. References and Further Reading Benzoni, Luca, Pierre Collin-Dufresne and Robert S. Goldstein, Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle in the Presence of Trickle-Down Labor Income, unpublished paper, University of California at Berkeley, 2004. Bodie, Zvi, Robert C. Merton and William F. Samuelson, Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Choice in a Life-Cycle Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16:427-49, 1992. Campbell, John Y. and Luis Viceira, Strategic Asset Allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long-Term Investors, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. Choi, James J., David Laibson, Brigitte Madrian, and Andrew Metrick, Optimal Defaults and Active Decisions NBER Working Paper No. 11074, January 2005 (documenting that when a company switched from requiring new employees to fill out a form indicating their decision to enroll in a 401(k) plan to inviting employees to call a telephone number when they were ready to decide, the percent enrolling by three months after employment fell from 69% to 41%.) Dimson, Elroy, Paul Marsh and Mike Staunton, Triumph of the Optimists: 101 Years of Global Investment Returns, Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ and Oxford, 2002. Geanakoplos, John, Olivia S. Mitchell, and Stephen P. Zeldes, Social Security Money s Worth Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1005, 2000. Johnson, Eric J. and Daniel Goldstein, Do Defaults Save Lives?, Science 302(5649) 1338-1339, November 21, 2003 (documenting that countries that make organ donation a default option have much higher availability of donated organs than those for which donation is an option but not the default) Produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press, 2006

8 The Economists' Voice Vol. 2 [2005], No. 1, Article 14 Lynch, Anthony, and Sinan Tan, Labor Income Dynamics at Business-Cycle Frequencies: Implications for Portfolio Choice, unpublished paper, Stern School of Business, New York University, November 2004. Merton, Robert C., An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model, Econometrica 41:867-80, 1973. Office of the Press Secretary, The White House, Background Press Briefing on Social Security, February 2, 2005 (a)., Strengthening Social Security for the 21 st Century, February 2005 (b). Samuelson, Paul A., Lifetime Portfolio Selection by Dynamic Stochastic Programming, Review of Economics and Statistics 51:239-46, 1969, reprinted in Joseph Stiglitz, editor, The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume 3, MIT Press, pp. 883-90, 1972. Shiller, Robert J., The Life-Cycle Personal Accounts Proposal for Social Security: An Evaluation, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 11300, May 2005, see also http://www.irrationalexuberance.com, 2005. Shiller, Robert J., Irrational Exuberance, 2 nd Edition, Princeton University Press, 2005. Siegel, Jeremy, Stocks for the Long Run, 3 rd Edition, McGraw-Hill, 2002. Viceira, Luis, Optimal Portfolio Choice for Long-Horizon Returns with Non- Tradable Labor Income, Journal of Finance, 56:433-70, 2001. http://www.bepress.com/ev/vol2/iss1/art14