The Equity Premium in India

Similar documents
Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Models of Risk and Return

PERSPECTIVES. Reasonable Expectations for the Long-Run U.S.Equity Risk Premium. Roger G. Clarke, Ph.D and Harindra de Silva, Ph.D.

Futures Price d,f $ 0.65 = (1.05) (1.04)

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Answers to Concepts in Review

Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet

Rethinking Fixed Income

Chapter 1 The Investment Setting

1. CFI Holdings is a conglomerate listed on the Zimbabwe Stock Exchange (ZSE) and has three operating divisions as follows:

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Cost of Capital, Valuation and Strategic Financial Decision Making

The Long-Run Performance of the New Zealand Stock Markets:

THE LOW-VOLATILITY ANOMALY: Does It Work In Practice?

The Equity Risk Premium and the Cost of Capital

BS2551 Money Banking and Finance. Institutional Investors

ON THE RISK ADJUSTED DISCOUNT RATE FOR DETERMINING LIFE OFFICE APPRAISAL VALUES BY M. SHERRIS B.A., M.B.A., F.I.A., F.I.A.A. 1.

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS

The Investment Performance of Rare U.S. Coins By: Raymond E. Lombra, Ph.D.

Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*:

A Basic Introduction to the Methodology Used to Determine a Discount Rate

Assessing Risk Tolerance for Asset Allocation

Mutual Fund Investing Exam Study Guide

CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS

Wel Dlp Portfolio And Risk Management

The problems of being passive

Fundamentals Level Skills Module, Paper F9

Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests. Aswath Damodaran

Computing the optimal portfolio policy of an investor facing capital gains tax is a challenging problem:

How To Understand The Value Of A Mutual Fund

Final Exam Practice Set and Solutions

How To Understand The Theory Of Finance

Navigating through flexible bond funds

VALUING BANKING STOCKS

Embedded Tax Liabilities & Portfolio Choice

Chapter 9 The Cost of Capital ANSWERS TO SELEECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Key Concepts and Skills

Economic Brief. Investing over the Life Cycle: One Size Doesn t Fit All

Bonds, Preferred Stock, and Common Stock

Estimating the Market Risk Premium for Australia using a Benchmark Approach

Mental-accounting portfolio

Low-Volatility Investing: Expect the Unexpected

VANDERBILT AVENUE ASSET MANAGEMENT

Sustainable Withdrawal Rates From Your Retirement Portfolio

Finance Homework p. 65 (3, 4), p (1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 12, 14), p. 107 (2), p. 109 (3,4)

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales

Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

RETURN ON CURRENT ASSETS, WORKING CAPITAL AND REQUIRED RATE OF RETURN ON EQUITY

Market timing at home and abroad

Glossary of Investment Terms

Instructor s Manual Chapter 12 Page 144

Chapter component of the convertible can be estimated as =

Final Exam MØA 155 Financial Economics Fall 2009 Permitted Material: Calculator

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION, BACKGROUND, AND MOTIVATION. Over the last decades, risk analysis and corporate risk management activities have

Risk and Return Models: Equity and Debt. Aswath Damodaran 1

READING 14: LIFETIME FINANCIAL ADVICE: HUMAN CAPITAL, ASSET ALLOCATION, AND INSURANCE

Practice Set #4 and Solutions.

Average Debt and Equity Returns: Puzzling?

Additional Practice Questions for Midterm I

What is the fair market

What can property offer an institutional investor?

Modified dividend payout ratio =

A Study on Consumer Perception Regarding Birla Sun Life Mutual Fund, Jalandhar

CHAPTER 15 INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIO INVESTMENT SUGGESTED ANSWERS AND SOLUTIONS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS

INSURANCE. Life Insurance. as an. Asset Class

ANALYSIS AND MANAGEMENT

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

Global Investment Trends Survey May A study into global investment trends and saver intentions in 2015

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible

RISKS IN MUTUAL FUND INVESTMENTS

Equity Valuation. Lecture Notes # 8. 3 Choice of the Appropriate Discount Rate 2. 4 Future Cash Flows: the Dividend Discount Model (DDM) 3

Seeking a More Efficient Fixed Income Portfolio with Asia Bonds

Educational Determinants of Stock Market Participation In College

Optimal Portfolio Allocation in a World Without Treasury Securities

1 (a) Calculation of net present value (NPV) Year $000 $000 $000 $000 $000 $000 Sales revenue 1,600 1,600 1,600 1,600 1,600

A Test Of The M&M Capital Structure Theories Richard H. Fosberg, William Paterson University, USA

MBA 8230 Corporation Finance (Part II) Practice Final Exam #2

Better Guidance on Matters of Life and Death

TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II + III

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY

CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION

Traditionally, venturing outside the United States has involved two investments:

Chapter 11 The Cost of Capital ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

The Lipper Leader Rating System

Journal of Financial and Economic Practice

Popular and controversial banking products for households in Norway

CHAPTER 20: OPTIONS MARKETS: INTRODUCTION

NIKE Case Study Solutions

The general relationship between stocks and bonds is widely recognized. Stock dividends and interest

DUKE UNIVERSITY Fuqua School of Business. FINANCE CORPORATE FINANCE Problem Set #7 Prof. Simon Gervais Fall 2011 Term 2.

Economia Aziendale online 2000 Web International Business and Management Review

Transcription:

The Equity Premium in India Rajnish Mehra University of California, Santa Barbara and National Bureau of Economic Research January 06 Prepared for the Oxford Companion to Economics in India edited by Kaushik Basu

2 The equity premium is the return earned by a risky security, such as a stock, in excess of that earned by a risk free security, such as a Treasury Bill. It is a crucial input into financial decisions such as asset allocation, capital budgeting and planning for retirement. Historical data provide a wealth of evidence documenting that over long periods of time, stock returns have been considerably higher than returns for T-bills. As Table 1 shows, the average annual real return (that is, the inflation-adjusted return) on the U.S. stock market for the past 115 years has been about 7.5 percent. In the same period, the real return on a relatively riskless security was a paltry 1.0 percent. Table 1. U.S. Returns, 1802 2004 Mean Real Return Relatively Riskless Period Market Index Security Risk Premium 1802 2004 6.9% 2.9% 4.0% 1889 2004 7.5 1.0 6.5 1926 2004 8.0 0.7 7.3 1947 2000 7.5 0.5 7.0 The difference between these two returns, 6.5 percentage points, is the equity premium. This statistical difference has been even more pronounced in the post-world War II period. Data on U.S. stock and bond returns going back to 1802 reveal a similar, although somewhat smaller, premium for the past 200 years.

3 Furthermore, this pattern of excess returns to equity holdings is not unique to U.S. capital markets. Table 2 documents that equity returns in other developed countries also exhibit this historical regularity when compared with the return to riskless debt holdings. Table 2 Returns for Selected Developed Countries Mean Real Return Relatively Riskless Country Period Market Index Security Risk Premium United Kingdom 1947 1999 5.7% 1.1% 4.6% Japan 1970 1999 4.7 1.4 3.3 Germany 1978 1997 9.8 3.2 6.6 France 1973 1998 9.0 2.7 6.3 Sweden 1919-2003 11.1 5.6 5.5 Australia 1900-2000 13.3 4.6 8.7 The annual return on the U.K. stock market, for example, was 5.7 percent in the post-wwii period, an impressive 4.6% premium over the average bond return of 1.1 percent. Similar statistical differences have been documented for France, Germany, and Japan. And together, the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan, Germany, and France account for more than 85 percent of capitalized global equity value. Table 3 details the equity premium for India for the post liberalization period, using both the BSE 100 and the Sensex index as a proxy for the return on equity. Since

4 participation in the T-bill market was highly regulated before 2000, we report the equity premium relative to the Bank Deposit Rate, using the later as a proxy for the return on a risk free security. Table 3 India Returns, 1991-2004 Relatively Riskless Security BSE 100 Equity Premium (BSE 100) Equity Premium (Sensex) Sensex Mean Real Return % 1.28 12.6 11.3 11.0 9.7 Standard Deviation % 1.73 37.2 37.7 32.6 33.2 For the period prior to 1991 reliable data on dividend yields is not available. In Table 4, we report the equity premium using the average annual stock price index as documented and reported by the Reserve Bank of India. Table 4 India Returns, 1984-1991 Relatively Riskless Security BSE 100 Equity Premium (BSE 100) Mean Real Return % 1.13 22.4 21.3 Standard Deviation % 0.74 28.1 27.9

5 We illustrate the dramatic investment implications of the differential rates of return in Tables 5 and 6. Table 5 shows the enormous disparity in capital appreciation of $1 invested in different assets in the U.S for various time periods. 1 Table 6 displays a similar analysis for India Investment Period Table 5. Real Terminal Value of $1 Invested Stocks T-Bills Ratio 1889 2004 $4092.36 $3.14 1,303.30 1926 2004 $407.56 $1.67 244.05 1947-2004 $61.70 $1.33 46.39 Investment Period Table 6. Real Terminal Value of Rs 1 Invested Stocks (BSE 100) Bank Deposit Ratio 1984 2004 Rs 19.25 Rs 1.28 15.04 1991 2004 Rs 4.68 Rs 1.18 3.97 One can gain additional insights by examining what these differential rates imply for the time it takes to double one s money. Using rates in India over the 1991-2004 period, the doubling period for investments in stocks is about 6 years compared to about 1 The calculations in Table 5 assume that all payments to the underlying asset, such as dividend payments to stocks and interest payments to bonds, were reinvested and that no taxes were paid.

6 55 years for investments in a risk free asset. This kind of long-term perspective underscores the remarkable wealth-building potential of the equity premium and highlights why it is of central importance in portfolio allocation decisions, in making estimates of the cost of capital, and in the current debate about the advantages of investing Social Security Trust or retirement funds in the stock market. A Premium for Bearing Risk? Why has the rate of return on stocks in India and other countries been significantly higher than the rate of return on relatively risk free assets? An intuitive answer is that stocks are riskier than bonds and investors require a premium for bearing this additional risk. Indeed, the standard deviation of the returns to stocks in India (about 30 percent a year historically) is larger than that of the returns to T-bills (about 2 percent a year), so obviously, stocks are considerably riskier than bills. But are they? Figure 1 illustrates the variability in the annual real rate of return on the BSE 100 Index while Figure 2 shows the variability of a relatively risk free security over the 1991 2004 period.

7

8

9 To enhance and deepen our understanding of the risk-return trade-off in the pricing of financial assets, we make a detour into modern asset pricing theory and look at why different assets yield different rates of return. The deux ex machina of this theory is that assets are priced such that, ex-ante, the loss in marginal utility incurred by sacrificing current consumption and buying an asset at a certain price is equal to the expected gain in marginal utility contingent on the anticipated increase in consumption when the asset pays off in the future. The operative emphasis here is the incremental loss or gain in well being due to incremental consumption, which must be differentiated from the incremental consumption itself. This is because the same amount of incremental consumption may result in different degrees of well-being at different times. A five-course dinner after a heavy lunch, for example, yields considerably less satisfaction than a similar dinner when one is hungry! As a consequence, assets that pay off when times are good and consumption levels are high, i.e. when the incremental value of additional consumption is low, are less desirable than those that pay off an equivalent amount when times are bad and additional consumption is both desirable and more highly valued. Let us illustrate this principle in the context of the standard, popular paradigm, the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). This model postulates a linear relationship between an asset s beta, a measure of systematic risk, and expected return. Thus, high

10 beta stocks yield a high-expected rate of return. That is so because in the CAPM, good times and bad times are captured by the return on the market. The performance of the market as captured by a broad based index acts as a surrogate indicator for the relevant state of the economy. A high beta security tends to pay off more when the market return is high, that is, when times are good and consumption is plentiful; as discussed earlier, such a security provides less incremental utility than a security that pays off when consumption is low, is less valuable to investors and consequently sells for less. Thus assets that pay off in states of low marginal utility will sell for a lower price than similar assets that pay off in states of high marginal utility. Since rates of return are inversely proportional to asset prices, the latter class of assets will, on average, give a lower rate of return than the former. Another perspective on asset pricing emphasizes that economic agents prefer to smooth patterns of consumption over time. Assets that pay off a relatively larger amount at times when consumption is already high, destabilize these patterns of consumption, whereas assets that pay off when consumption levels are low, smooth out consumption. Naturally, the latter are more valuable and thus require a lower rate of return to induce investors to hold these assets. (Insurance policies are a classic example of assets that smooth consumption. Individuals willingly purchase and hold them, in spite of their very low rates of return.) To return to the original question: are stocks so much more riskier than bills so as to justify a 7% differential in their rates of return as observed in the U.S?

11 What came as a surprise to many economists and researchers in finance was the conclusion of a research paper that Edward Prescott and I wrote in 1979. Stocks and bonds pay off in approximately the same states of nature or economic scenarios and hence, as argued earlier, they should command approximately the same rate of return. In fact, using standard theory to estimate risk-adjusted returns, we found that stocks in the U.S on average should command, at most, a 1% return premium over bills. Since, for as long as we had reliable data, (about a hundred years), the mean premium on stocks over bills was considerably and consistently higher, we realized that we had a puzzle on our hands. It took us six more years to convince a skeptical profession and for our paper The Equity Premium: A Puzzle to be published. (Mehra and Prescott (1985)). For the purpose of this article, I have done a similar analysis for India using the data in Table 6, which contains the sample statistics for the Indian economy for the 1991 2004 period. Table 6 Indian Economy Sample Statistics, 1991 2004 Statistic Value Risk-free rate, R f 1.0128 Mean return on equity, E (R e ) 1.126 Mean growth rate of consumption, E (x) 1.0227 Standard deviation of growth rate of consumption, σ(x) 0.0224 Mean equity premium, E (R e ) R f 0.113

12 I find that the theoretical equity premium should be in the range 0.02% to 0.16% if the coefficient of risk aversion is varied from 2 to 10. Since the observed risk premium in India is an order of magnitude more, we have a puzzle with respect to Indian data as well. I want to emphasize that the equity premium puzzle is a quantitative puzzle. Standard theory is qualitatively consistent with our notion of risk: stocks do, on average, return more than bonds in the theoretical model. The puzzle arises from the fact that the quantitative predictions of the theory are an order of magnitude different from what has been historically documented. The puzzle cannot be dismissed lightly because much of our economic intuition and policy directives are based on the very class of models that fall short so dramatically when confronted with financial data. It underscores the failure of paradigms central to financial and economic modeling to capture the characteristic that appears to make stocks comparatively so risky. Hence, the viability of using this class of models for any quantitative assessment for example, to gauge the welfare implications of alternative stabilization policies is thrown open to question. For this reason, over the past 20 years or so, attempts to resolve the puzzle have become a major research impetus in finance and economics. Several generalizations of key features of the Mehra Prescott (1985) model have been proposed to reconcile observations with theory, including alternative assumptions about preferences, modified probability distributions to admit rare but disastrous events, survivorship bias,

13 incomplete markets, and market imperfections. None have satisfactorily resolved the puzzle. Recently some researchers and analysts that ex-ante equity premium is likely to be low. The data used to document the equity premium (over the past 100 years in some instances) represents as reliable an economic data set as analysts have, and 100 years is long series when it comes to economic data. Before the equity premium is dismissed, not only do researchers need to understand the observed phenomena, but they also need a plausible explanation as to why the future is likely to be any different from the past. Demographic shifts and changes in participation in equity markets will, of course, impact on the equity premium in India over time. For instance, greater stock market participation in particular by the younger generation is likely to reduce the equity premium. However, before these demographic effects play a role, on the basis of what is currently known, I make the following assertion: the equity premium in the future is likely to be similar to what it has been in the past and returns to investment in equity will continue to substantially dominate returns to investment in T-bills for investors with long planning horizons. Further Reading: Two introductory articles are Cochrane (1997) and Mehra (2003). Kocherlakota (1996) and Mehra and Prescott (2003) provide comprehensive surveys of the literature, while Constantinides (2002) and Mehra (2006) is aimed at researchers.

14 References Cochrane, J.H. 1997. Where Is the Market Going? Uncertain Facts and Novel Theories. Economic Perspectives, vol. 21, no. 6 (November):3 37. Constantinides G.M. 2002. Rational Asset Prices. Journal of Finance, vol. 57, no. 4 (August):1567 91. Kocherlakota, N.R. 1996. The Equity Premium: It s Still a Puzzle. Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 34, no. 1 (March):42 71. Mehra, R., and E.C. Prescott. 1985. The Equity Premium: A Puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 15, no. 2 (March):145 161. Mehra, R. 2003. The Equity Premium: Why Is It A Puzzle? Financial Analysts Journal, January /February, pp 54-69 Mehra, R., and E.C. Prescott. 2003. The Equity Premium in Retrospect. In Handbook of the Economics of Finance. Edited by G.M. Constantinides, M. Harris, and R. Stulz. Amsterdam, Netherlands: North-Holland,. Mehra, R. 2006 Handbook of Investments: Equity Risk Premium North Holland, Amsterdam (Forthcoming).