Compensation and Risk Incentives in Banking



Similar documents
Incentive Compensation in the Banking Industry:

COMMENTARY ON THE RESTRICTIONS ON PROPRIETARY TRADING BY INSURED DEPOSITARY INSTITUTIONS. By Paul A. Volcker

Introduction to Health Care Accounting. What Is Financial Management?

CONTRACTS FOR DIFFERENCE

Market Linked Certificates of Deposit

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

Ch 19 Deposit Insurance Overview

the actions of the party who is insured. These actions cannot be fully observed or verified by the insurance (hidden action).

How To Calculate Financial Leverage Ratio

Incentive Compensation for Risk Managers when Effort is Unobservable

3/22/2010. Chapter 11. Eight Categories of Bank Regulation. Economic Analysis of. Regulation Lecture 1. Asymmetric Information and Bank Regulation

Chapter 12: Options and Executive Pay. Economics 136 Julian Betts Note: You are not responsible for the appendix.

Overview of assets, liabilities and capital of financial intermediaries and regulatory supervision of them

Web. Chapter FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND MARKETS

American Bankers Association. Sample Glossary of Collective Investment Fund Terms for Disclosures to Retirement Plan Participants

Lecture Notes on MONEY, BANKING, AND FINANCIAL MARKETS. Peter N. Ireland Department of Economics Boston College.

AN EMPIRICAL EXAMINATION OF DEPOSIT INSURANCE DECISIONS. Ei-Run Dga - Intro. University of Nebraska, 1984

Homework Assignment #5: Answer Key

4. The minimum amount of owners' equity in a bank mandated by regulators is called a requirement. A) reserve B) margin C) liquidity D) capital

Chapter 1 The Investment Setting

Asset Quality Section 219

CHAPTER 9: BANKING DOING BUSINESS IN GREATER PHOENIX, U.S.A. 9.1: THE U.S. BANKING SYSTEM 9.2: ESTABLISHING A U.S. BANK ACCOUNT

What s on a bank s balance sheet?

Compensation Committee Checklist for Assessing Incentives and Risk

Financial Terms & Calculations

Incentives and Conflicts of Interests in Corporate Bankruptcy and Bank Insolvency: A Note Robert R. Bliss * 19 August 2005

Lecture Notes on MONEY, BANKING, AND FINANCIAL MARKETS. Peter N. Ireland Department of Economics Boston College.

Understanding a Firm s Different Financing Options. A Closer Look at Equity vs. Debt

Assessing the Risks of Mortgage REITs. By Sabrina R. Pellerin, David A. Price, Steven J. Sabol, and John R. Walter

Subordinated Debt and the Quality of Market Discipline in Banking by Mark Levonian Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Chapter 17. Financial Management and Institutions

Client Update Compensation Practices at Financial Institutions Targeted: Proposed Incentive Compensation Rules Aim to Curb Excessive Risk-Taking

Final Guidance on Sound Incentive Compensation Policies Applicable to Banking Organizations

Balanced fund: A mutual fund with a mix of stocks and bonds. It offers safety of principal, regular income and modest growth.

The Relationship between Capital, Liquidity and Risk in Commercial Banks. by Tamara Kochubey and Dorota Kowalczyk. Comments by Ricardo Lago

1. State and explain two reasons why short-maturity loans are safer (meaning lower credit risk) to the lender than long-maturity loans (10 points).

Chapter 2. Practice Problems. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Information as of 10/19/08. FDIC Temporary Liquidity Guarantee Program What is It and What Does It Mean to Community Banks?

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Finding the Right Financing Mix: The Capital Structure Decision. Aswath Damodaran 1

PROPERTY/CASUALTY INSURANCE AND SYSTEMIC RISK

Chapter 1 The Scope of Corporate Finance

INCREASING GLOBAL FINANCIAL INTEGRITY: THE ROLES OF MARKET DISCIPLINE, REGULATION, AND SUPERVISION

Performance Review for Electricity Now

The Business Case For SBA 7a Lending For Community Banks

A Closer Look The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act

Inside and outside liquidity provision

An overview from. Report 3 in the Payday Lending in America series Payday Lending in America: Policy Solutions. Oct 2013

These days, many jobs are not life long careers. In case you get laid off, EI may not be enough to cover your lifestyle. Or you might want to re

CHAPTER 20: OPTIONS MARKETS: INTRODUCTION

30-1. CHAPTER 30 Financial Distress. Multiple Choice Questions: I. DEFINITIONS

How To Understand The Financial Philosophy Of A Firm

What Should the Recovery, Resolution and Crisis Management Processes Be? John F. Bovenzi June 16, 2016

I. Introduction. II. Financial Markets (Direct Finance) A. How the Financial Market Works. B. The Debt Market (Bond Market)

COMPUTERSHARE TRUST COMPANY OF CANADA BASEL III PILLAR 3 DISCLOSURES

POLICY POSITION PAPER ON THE PRUDENTIAL TREATMENT OF CAPITALISED EXPENSES

Financial-Institutions Management. Solutions 5. Chapter 18: Liability and Liquidity Management Reserve Requirements

Stocks: An Introduction

Net revenue , , , Tax payable (235 58) (516 32) (1,511 56) (1,002 20)

Liberia Leasing Investment Forum

Chapter 11. Economic Analysis of Banking Regulation

Markets, Investments, and Financial Management FIFTEENTH EDITION

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION. on remuneration policies in the financial services sector

Ch. 18: Taxes + Bankruptcy cost

MODULE 3 THE NEXT BIG THING

Consumer Protection and Regulatory Changes in the Dodd-Frank Bill

Chapter 13 Money and Banking

RIT Capital Partners plc Shareholder Disclosure Document January 2015

The Effects of Funding Costs and Risk on Banks Lending Rates

Re: Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking Regarding Authority to Require Supervision and Regulation of Certain Nonbank Financial Companies

Taiwan Life Insurance Report 2011

Regulatory Practice Letter October 2011 RPL 11-23

When Your Home is on The Line:

New York Education Objectives Personal Finance Course

DSF POLICY BRIEFS No. 1/ February 2011

CHAPTER 27 PRINCIPLES OF WORKING CAPITAL MANAGEMENT

EFRAG Short Discussion Series THE USE OF INFORMATION BY CAPITAL PROVIDERS IMPLICATIONS FOR STANDARD SETTING

The cost of capital. A reading prepared by Pamela Peterson Drake. 1. Introduction

Deposit Insurance. Seminar for Sr. Bank Supervisors. F. Montes-Negret, Sector Manager, LCSFF The World Bank, Oct. 24, 2002

Prof Kevin Davis Melbourne Centre for Financial Studies. Current Issues in Bank Capital Planning. Session 4.4

Describe the functions of the Federal Reserve System (the Fed).

EC 341 Monetary and Banking Institutions, Boston University Summer 2, 2012 Homework 3 Due date: Tuesday, July 31, 6:00 PM.

Currency: The paper money and coins owned by people and business firms

Bonds and preferred stock. Basic definitions. Preferred(?) stock. Investing in fixed income securities

INVESTMENT DICTIONARY

A STUDY OF TAX-FREE SAVINGS ACCOUNT TAKEUP IN SOUTH AFRICA

PNC is a registered mark of The PNC Financial Services Group, Inc.( PNC ) 2013 The PNC Financial Services Group, Inc. All rights reserved.

Charles Schwab Bank Annual Dodd-Frank Act Stress Test Disclosure

The importance of insurer solvency. January 2013

FIN 683 Financial Institutions Management Liquidity Management and Deposit Insurance

CONFERENCE OF STATE BANK SUPERVISORS AMERICAN ASSOCIATION OF RESIDENTIAL MORTGAGE REGULATORS NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF CONSUMER CREDIT ADMINISTRATORS

Home Equity Lines of Credit

How To Get A Home Equity Line Of Credit

The New Normal of Community Banking: Key Ingredients to Survive and Thrive

CONFERENCE OF STATE BANK SUPERVISORS AMERICAN ASSOCIATION OF RESIDENTIAL MORTGAGE REGULATORS NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF CONSUMER CREDIT ADMINISTRATORS

ABOUT FINANCIAL RATIO ANALYSIS

CANADIAN TIRE BANK. BASEL PILLAR 3 DISCLOSURES December 31, 2014 (unaudited)

It is vital that the most important ratios are learned, and that intelligent comment can be made on the results.

Financial Management

Transcription:

Compensation and Risk Incentives in Banking By Jian Cai, Kent Cherny, and Todd Milbourn Abstract In this Economic Commentary, we review why executive compensation contracts are often structured the way they are, analyze risk incentives stemming from various pay schemes, and examine the unique tendency of the banking industry toward risk-taking. Studying the typical pay structures of banking executives before the financial crisis reveals some problematic practices. These practices may have encouraged short-termism and excessive risk-taking, which are two behaviors banking regulators aim to prevent with their recently issued guidance on incentive compensation. The compensation packages of executives and employees at financial institutions have drawn considerable attention and in some cases, indignation in the wake of the extraordinary interventions of the Federal Reserve and the U.S. Treasury Department since 2008. Prior to the crisis, the financial sector had accounted for 20 percent to 35 percent of domestic profits in the United States for nearly two decades, so perhaps unsurprisingly, workers in this industry were rewarded for such profitability with higher compensation. But following the near collapse of the financial system, bank regulators and the general public are anxious to know whether compensation practices were partially or even largely to blame for the aggressive risk-taking that many institutions engaged in leading up to the crisis. There has been a debate on this question among regulators, practitioners, and academicians. Some studies find no evidence that compensation affected banks performance during the crisis. Others find various links between managerial compensation and banks risk-taking behavior. Recently, the four major federal bank regulatory agencies the Federal Reserve, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), the Office of Thrift Supervision (OTS), and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) jointly issued final guidance on incentive compensation (link to the joint press release website: http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/bcreg/20100621a.htm). The goal of the guidance is to prevent two kinds of behavior by banks: pursuing short-term profits at the expense of the long-term financial health of the organization, and taking imprudent or excessive risks that could jeopardize the safety and soundness of the organization. To help understand the principles laid out in the guidance and establish the link between compensation and risk-taking, this Economic Commentary explains some common practices for

rewarding employees at financial institutions and considers how they encourage or discourage risk-taking. Specifically, we address five questions: What does compensation do? How does compensation affect risk-taking? Are risk incentives stronger in the banking industry? And, finally, are the compensation schemes favored by financial institutions different from those in other industries? If so, have such differences induced higher risk-taking? Compensation and Incentive Alignment All the recent attention on pay packages and risk-taking seems to have created the misperception that companies use compensation packages to control the risk incentives of their managers. This is in fact not what an optimal compensation contract is primarily intended to do. The traditional rationale for designing deliberate compensation schemes is that doing so aligns managerial incentives with those of shareholders. A firm s executives are tasked with executing the policies of its board of directors those who represent the owners of the firm. Although many executives hold large amounts of equity in the firms they manage, they still embody what economists and corporate governance scholars call the principal-agent problem. Because an imperfect match exists between the interests of the owners (principals) and managers (agents), managers may at times run the company in a way that advances their own interests over those of shareholders. They may seek to maximize their own power, influence, indispensability, or perquisites instead of overall profitability. Shareholders use compensation to align managers incentives with the central interest of the shareholders, which is maximizing the value of equity holdings. That is, the right compensation structure ensures that managers will benefit when they act in ways that benefit shareholders. Often, the structure of the compensation package combines rewards for short-term profitability and for long-term growth potential and the stability of earnings. For example, short-term profitability is encouraged with the base salary and a bonus that is tied to the firm s recent performance, whereas long-term growth and stability are encouraged through restricted stocks, stock options, benefit packages, pension plans, and so forth. With well-designed pay schemes, managers are incentivized to boost profits in the near term, and they are also made partial long-term owners in the firm through stock grants and stock options, which provides them with a direct way to benefit from incremental improvements in the value of the firm. Boosting short-term profits at the expense of long-term investments will reduce the value of stocks and stock options, which are potentially more lucrative than a salary plus a bonus. In a balanced executive compensation package, either investments with immediate payouts or payouts too far in the future will reduce the value of an executive s lifetime compensation.

Compensation and Risk Incentives A compensation contract may align shareholder and manager interests, but that does not mean it is designed to prevent every counterproductive behavior that managers might be tempted to engage in. In fact, one byproduct of compensation schemes that are optimal from the viewpoint of shareholders is that they can create an incentive to undertake excessive risk risk so high it can jeopardize the stability of the firm. While certain structures are good at aligning managers with owners, their emphasis on equity can have a negative impact on creditor protection and the firm s stability. In the end, what is good for shareholders may not be good for debtholders such as banks, bondholders, depositors, and deposit insurers. This unfortunate byproduct comes about as a result of differences in who profits in certain scenarios. Shareholders are referred to as residual claimants in the sense that they get whatever money is left over after debtors and suppliers are paid. If a firm cannot pay back all of its debts, shareholders receive nothing. If a firm can pay its debts, any realized firm value that exceeds the debts goes into the shareholders pockets. Thus, the most shareholders can lose is their initial investment, but they have a potentially unlimited upside if the firm performs well. If a firm becomes more risky borrowing to invest in projects that have a high pay-off and a high probability of failing the downside is borne by debtholders, whereas the upside is reaped by shareholders. In fact, the riskier the firm becomes, the greater the potential upside there is. Faced with such an incentive, managers might take on more risks in order to maximize shareholders as well as their own expected payoffs (through both stocks and stock options), possibly at the expense of the debtholders. As a result, the firm s safety and soundness may be sacrificed as the probability of insolvency increases due to more risk-taking. Meanwhile, compensation structures that heavily reward short-term performance (for example, through bonuses) may encourage managers to take opportunities that would boost immediate profitability but risk future financial health. After all, managers do not need to stay with one firm forever. Risk Incentives in Banking Banks are susceptible to the same principal-agent problem and risk-stability trade-off as other types of firms are. However, banks problems with regard to risk are compounded. This is primarily the case because banks employ a comparatively high debt-to-equity ratio (leverage) to execute their primary function financial intermediation efficiently. A majority of financial

institutions profits come from borrowing money from depositors or institutional creditors and then lending it out at a higher rate. Through this mechanism, savers money flows to banks, and then flows to those looking for capital. The trade-off is that the more debt a bank takes on, the more it can intermediate between savers and borrowers; yet more debt and less equity also makes a bank highly susceptible to the conflict between debtholders and shareholders. Therefore, the problem of compensation providing executives with incentives to take on higher risks in the interest of shareholders is worse in the banking world. Government guarantees further complicate incentive structures for managers in the financial sector. For a variety of reasons (such as protecting small savers and eliminating destabilizing bank runs), governments guarantee bank deposits up to a particular dollar threshold. In the absence of deposit insurance, creditors would be more inclined to force banks to hold significantly higher levels of capital and engage in activities with reasonable amounts of risks. With deposit insurance, managers at insured financial institutions are less concerned about bank runs, and they may also have more opportunities to take excessive or imprudent risks since creditors are less incentivized to monitor them. The premiums paid by banks for deposit insurance are meant to counteract the problems that were introduced by the provision of government deposit guarantees, as are mandatory supervision and regulation of bank activities by government agencies but these countermeasures may be only a partial antidote. Access to emergency liquidity facilities such as the Federal Reserve s Discount Window may also encourage bank risk-takers to mismanage portfolio liquidity by relying on shorter-term liabilities (which typically carry lower interest rates) to boost profits. Along these same lines, financial institutions that are exceedingly large or engage in complex transactions (such as derivatives trading[link to Kent/Ben derivatives regulation Commentary]) may even avoid collapse by virtue of being too-big-to-fail (TBTF) or too interconnected to other institutions to fail. In such cases, bank managers would be well-compensated in the event risky activities pay off, but they would not face the discipline of failure if the activities bankrupt the firm. In fact, the reality of TBTF seemingly gives financial executives the incentive to expand the size and complexity of their institutions, as doing so increases the likelihood that downside risks will be externalized to the financial system and taxpayers. Executive Compensation in Banking Having established that managers generally and those at financial institutions specifically can face an incentive to compromise the stability of their firms for shareholders and their own interests, we now look at executive compensation in the banking industry before the financial

crisis. We investigate whether typical compensation schemes might have contributed to risktaking behavior in the banking industry. Note that we will focus on executive pay since this form of compensation is regularly disclosed in shareholder filings, and thus the relevant data are readily available. However, the contracts of all other nonexecutive employees that put a firm s capital at risk such as bankers, traders, and the risk management teams that oversee them must also be considered when a financial institution s compensation scheme is examined. Executives may have blind spots in the oversight of those nonexecutives who make independent investment decisions. This is especially true for large institutions and institutions that engage in a broad range of complex activities. Even though we don t have nonexecutive compensation data, it is still reasonable to say that top executives are the most important agents in setting bank policies and that their compensation really matters. Thus we are able to gain an overview of compensation and its underlying risk incentives in the banking industry based on executive pay. Figure 1 shows that in 2005, executives in banking and finance obviously earned the highest pay, totaling $3.4 million per executive, or about 30 percent to 40 percent higher than executives in other industries. Three things stand out when we examine the main components of executive compensation (base salary, bonuses, restricted stocks, stock options, and long-term incentive plans). First, in the mid-$400,000 range, the base salary in banking and finance was not much different from that in other industries. Second, the banking and finance industry paid significantly higher bonuses and awarded more restricted stock shares. At close to $1 million per person, bonuses to banking executives amounted to more than twice their base salary and 1.5 2.5 times the bonuses paid to executives in other industries. In fact, 2005 was the highest bonus-paying year for banking executives during the past two decades [link to Cai/Milbourn Bank Executive Pay Trends]. Bonuses are often tied to short-term financial performance, typically of the past one to three years. Thus, this compensation structure tends to reward short-term profits and may have encouraged shorttermism at financial institutions. In the meantime, the value of restricted stock grants to bank executives was close to $750,000, which was 1.6 times their base salary and 1.5 2 times the stock value to executives in other industries. More heavily share-compensated bank managers might have a stronger incentive to maximize shareholder wealth, that is, to take on excessive risks at the cost of bank safety and soundness. Third, the value of stock options granted to bank executives was the second lowest among all industries in spite of a significant amount around $750,000 per executive in total option value.

The services industry ranked number 1 and paid over $1 million in stock options per executive in 2005, followed by mining, manufacturing, trade, and then banking at some distance. Figure 1. 2005 Executive Compensation by Industry (US$ Thousand) $4,000 $3,500 $3,000 $2,500 $2,000 $1,500 $1,000 $500 $0 $3,365 $245 $753 $737 $985 $176 $306 $58 $34 $817 $387 $494 $490 $806 $432 $667 $472 $459 $1,033 $378 $377 $456 $430 $488 $469 $413 Banking & Finance $2,476 Mining & Manufacturing $2,567 Transportation & Utility $2,439 Trade $2,375 Services Other Compensation LTIP Payouts Option Grant Restricted Stock Grant Other Annual Bonus Salary Data Source: ExecuComp. Figure 2 shows that in 2005 there were wide differences in executive compensation across five different groups of financial institutions commercial banks, nondepository credit institutions (lenders), securities and commodities brokers and dealers, insurance, and real estate. The two highest executive-paying groups were securities and commodities brokers and dealers and nondepository lenders, which paid $7.1 million and $5.8 million per executive, respectively. Insurance companies ranked third with $3.4 million per executive. In fact, these three groups drove the average executive pay in banking and finance higher than that in other industries. Executives at commercial banks and real estate companies, on the contrary, earned compensation no higher than those outside banking and finance. The higher pay to executives working for brokers, dealers, and nondepository lenders mainly came from three channels: bonuses, restricted stocks, and stock options. The amounts were enormous, well exceeding $1 million to $2 million per executive in each channel. This was not the case at insured commercial banks, which appeared much more conservative and similar to nonbanking firms. Thus, the compensation and risk incentive issues seem to point to securities

and commodities brokers and dealers as well as nondepository (and hence uninsured) lenders, as opposed to the entire banking industry. Figure 2. 2005 Executive Compensation in Banking (US$ Thousand) $8,000 $7,000 $6,000 $5,000 $4,000 $3,000 $2,000 $1,000 $0 $71 $1,675 $20 $1,271 $2,145 $1,283 $2,329 $352 $2,060 $971 $167 $507 $2,686 $487 $456 $476 $1,998 $215 $848 $576 $656 $392 $436 $525 $402 $540 $365 Commercial Banks $5,836 Nondepository Lenders $7,064 Brokers & Dealers $3,427 Insurance Real Estate Other Compensation LTIP Payouts Option Grant Restricted Stock Grant Other Annual Bonus Salary Data Source: ExecuComp. Next, we examine the relationship between executive compensation and banks profitability. Based on correlations between a few compensation items and profit measures (shown in figure 3), we find that the pay of bank executives was associated more with the size of a financial institution than its operating efficiency. On one hand, total compensation in 2005, and four of its main components salary, bonuses, restricted stocks, and stock options all had fairly strong, positive correlations (0.3-0.5) with net income and market value, which are driven by the size of a firm. On the other hand, correlations were very low (less than 0.1) between compensation and return on assets and return on equity, which are often used to measure a firm s operating efficiency. This kind of pay structure might have encouraged bank managers to blindly grow the sizes of their banks at the expense of the returns on the capital invested.

Figure 3. Correlation between Executive Compensation and Firm Profitability in Banking in Year 2005 Net Income Market Value Return on Assets Return on Equity Total Compensation 0.44 0.51 0.08 0.09 Salary 0.31 0.46 0.07 0.08 Bonus 0.36 0.39 0.06 0.09 Restricted Stocks 0.39 0.35 0.03 0.03 Stock Options 0.17 0.27 0.07 0.06 Data Source: ExecuComp. Conclusion In this Economic Commentary, we review the purpose of designing managerial compensation contracts, analyze the risk incentives stemming from such compensation schemes, and examine the uniqueness of the banking industry in risk-taking. Studying the pay structures of banking executives before the financial crisis reveals some problematic practices (such as too much bonus and stock-related compensation). These practices might have encouraged short-termism and excessive risk-taking, two behaviors federal bank regulators aim to prevent by recently issuing their joint guidance on incentive compensation.