Prize-linked savings products: An innovative tool for increasing savings among lowincome

Similar documents
Savings and Prize-Linked Savings Accounts

Can Gambling Increase Savings? Empirical Evidence on Prize-linked Savings Accounts

Personal current accounts in the UK

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Individual Retirement Accounts and Saving

Saving whilst Gambling: An Empirical Analysis of U.K. Premium Bonds

Saving whilst Gambling: An Empirical Analysis of U.K. Premium Bonds

Prospect Theory Ayelet Gneezy & Nicholas Epley

A framing effect is usually said to occur when equivalent descriptions of a

Annuity for micro pensions

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

Savings and Prize-Linked Savings Accounts

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MAKING SAVERS WINNERS: AN OVERVIEW OF PRIZE-LINKED SAVINGS PRODUCTS

Insights. Investment strategy design for defined contribution pension plans. An Asset-Liability Risk Management Challenge

The UK Retail Bond Market H Performance Update

Public Debt and Cash Management

First National Bank s MaMa Account: PLS in South Africa. Shawn Cole, Ben Iverson, Peter Tufano D2D PLS Conference 18 Nov 2011

Creating a Secondary Annuity Market: a response by the National Association of Pension Funds

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

Savings and Prize-Linked Savings Accounts

MRS Regulations for Administering Incentives and Free Prize Draws. February 2012

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MAKING SAVERS WINNERS: AN OVERVIEW OF PRIZE-LINKED SAVINGS PRODUCTS

Prize-based Savings Business Plan. A New Savings Opportunity for Credit Unions

Fixed Odds Betting Terminals and the Code of Practice. A report for the Association of British Bookmakers Limited SUMMARY ONLY

Consumer Demand for Prize-Linked Savings: A Preliminary Analysis

Investment Association response to the FCA s Retirement income market study: Interim Report

ETFs for private investors

BBA Consultation on the Future of Savings. Response from The True Potential Centre for the Public Understanding of Finance (PUFin)

Code of Practice. September 2012 Version 4. Queensland Responsible Gambling. Office of Liquor and Gaming Regulation

JACKPOT! HOW YOU CAN WIN THE LOTTERY BY EXERCISING YOUR SAVINGS ACCOUNT

Pension reforms in the UK: what can be learned from other countries?

CASE STORY ON GENDER DIMENSION OF AID FOR TRADE. Banking on Women Pays Off: Creating Opportunities for Women Entrepreneurs

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

OECD PROJECT ON FINANCIAL INCENTIVES AND RETIREMENT SAVINGS Project Outline

FISCAL INCENTIVES AND RETIREMENT SAVINGS Project Outline

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

The Equity Premium in India

Principles and Trade-Offs when Making Issuance Choices in the UK

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Principles for investment success. We believe you will give yourself the best chance of investment success if you focus on what you can control

Are lottery scratchcards a "hard" form of gambling?

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Economic background of the Microsoft/Yahoo! case

Insurance Demand and Prospect Theory. by Ulrich Schmidt

INFORMATION FOR OBSERVERS. Gaming Transactions (Agenda Paper 11(i))

RISK EQUITIES BONDS PROPERTY INCOME SPIN-FREE GUIDE TO BONDS

Guidelines on sales promotion measures when providing gambling

How to... Help your clients use their pensions freedom wisely

Constraining the cumulative amount of revenue recognised

A THEORETICAL ANALYSIS OF THE MECHANISMS OF COMPETITION IN THE GAMBLING MARKET

Code of Practice. Queensland responsible gambling Code of Practice. Section I V

Insurance Design for Developing Countries

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

An Improved Measure of Risk Aversion

Bond Mutual Funds. a guide to. A bond mutual fund is an investment company. that pools money from shareholders and invests

Keynote Speech, EIB/IMF Meeting, 23 October, Brussels

Medicaid Crowd-Out of Long-Term Care Insurance With Endogenous Medicaid Enrollment

CP ON TECHNICAL ADVICE ON CRITERIA AND FACTORS FOR INTERVENTION POWERS CONCERNING STRUCTURED DEPOSITS. Contents

Age and Insurance: Helping older customers find the cover they need. February 2009

4. The minimum amount of owners' equity in a bank mandated by regulators is called a requirement. A) reserve B) margin C) liquidity D) capital

Testimony for the ERISA Advisory Council on Ways to Help Participants Make Better Decisions in Risk-Transfer Transactions

Intelligence on financial inclusion

= = 106.

Defined Contribution Plans for Passive Investors

HMT Discussion paper on non-bank lending

BANK OF UGANDA STATISTICS DEPARTMENT BANK LENDING SURVEY FOR APRIL TO JUNE 2012 (Q4)

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Investment Education Series

PENSIONS POLICY INSTITUTE. Comparison of pension outcomes under EET and TEE tax treatment

Rating Methodology for Domestic Life Insurance Companies

Guidance on Risk Management, Internal Control and Related Financial and Business Reporting

IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET

Hey, low-income people! Here s one retirement savings strategy, while government thinks about how it might help.

Global Client Group The Gateway to AWM

Life Settlements: The Opportunity Continues to Grow

Banking on a Bad Bet: Probability Matching in Risky Choice Is Linked to Expectation Generation

Investment insight. Fixed income the what, when, where, why and how TABLE 1: DIFFERENT TYPES OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES. What is fixed income?

Recent Developments in Interest Rates on Bank Lending

TD Direct Investing A Guide to ISAs

How To Increase Car Insurance Prices On A Price Comparison Website

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Proposed acquisition by Unum Limited of the employee benefits business of Swiss Life (UK) plc

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics THE CURRENCY DENOMINATION OF SOVEREIGN DEBT

Submission by. Tatts Lotteries. to the. Productivity Commission s Inquiry into Australia s Gambling Industries. March 2009

Business. Insights. When cash is king. Investec Editorials

Response by Swedish authorities to the European Commission s public consultation on short selling

Asset allocation A key component of a successful investment strategy

- Short term notes (bonds) Maturities of 1-4 years - Medium-term notes/bonds Maturities of 5-10 years - Long-term bonds Maturities of years

RETIREMENT ACCOUNT SHARE DEALING GUIDE

Credit Card Market Study Interim Report: Annex 4 Switching Analysis

Notes. futures market does not by itself have any effect on the spot market. It affects current price only to the extent that

PROJECTION OF THE FISCAL BALANCE AND PUBLIC DEBT ( ) - SUMMARY

Giving up homeownership: a qualitative study of voluntary possession and selling because of financial difficulties

Pension freedom. Picking out the business winners and losers. 1,200 consumers surveyed. 12bn

largeequityrelease.com EQUITY RELEASE GUIDE Speak to one of our specialists today on

Referred to as the statement of financial position provides a snap shot of a company s assets, liabilities and equity at a particular point in time.

Traditionally pension schemes invested in four main asset classes: Shares (Equities or Stocks), Bonds, Property and Cash.

MRS Regulations for Administering Incentives and Free Prize Draws

Reminders, payment method and charitable giving: evidence from an online experiment

Health Insurance & Behavioral Economics

Transcription:

The Public Sphere 2015 Prize-linked savings products: An innovative tool for increasing savings among lowincome households? Julia Kowalski MPA Class of 2014, London School of Economics and Political Science Abstract This article explores the use of lottery elements to encourage saving among low-income households, through the introduction of prize-linked savings (PLS) products. It demonstrates that preferences for lottery elements in savings, and thus the appeal of PLS products, can be motivated using elements of cumulative prospect theory. Further, it reviews existing anecdotal evidence on the effectiveness of prize-linked savings. Based on experiments conducted by previous authors, the article discusses the potential welfare effects stemming from the introduction of prize-linked savings products. It tentatively suggests that positive welfare effects may be incurred in response to offering PLS products, through an increase in the level of total savings and positive externalities arising from increased formal banking. The paper identifies the establishment of systematic evidence on the effectiveness of PLS products, proposing a randomised design to this aim, as well as a revision of the current regulatory environment as next steps in view of policy implementation. 131

INTRODUCTION The Public Sphere 2015 In recent years, insights derived from behavioural economics have been applied to a variety of policy fields. In particular, behavioural policy design has been explored as a tool to increase savings (Benartzi and Thaler, 2004; Choi et al., 2001). Low levels of saving continues to be a policy concern as they can have severe effects on households that, in the face of unexpected income shocks, need to draw on their savings to maintain consumption. This is especially true for low-income households with limited possibilities of drawing on existing wealth or credit. Tufano and Schneider (2005) cite that U.S. financial planners advise households to have sufficient liquid assets to be able to replace at least six months worth of household income in the event of a shock provisions that only an estimated 22 per cent of households make. Similarly, a large majority of individuals report to be saving too little, and standard life cycle theories of savings cannot account for an empirically observed decrease in consumption after retirement, suggesting that consumption largely tracks income (Gruber, 2007). Product design in the area of financial services provision can influence savings levels and the target population as demonstrated, for example, by Ashraf et al. s (2006) study of commitment savings products in the Philippines. This article is concerned with a savings product that has recently received considerable attention, for which, however, no systematic evidence exists at present. Prize-linked savings accounts (PLS) are deposit accounts that, instead of paying out a fixed amount of regular interest, allow deposit holders to enter a prize draw by depositing savings, giving them the chance to win a large sum of money (Guillen and Tschoegl, 2002; Guryan et al. 2010; D2D, 2013). PLS account holders face no risk of losing their principal, which is equivalent to the money deposited in the account. However, they willingly forgo the interest paid on a regular account in favour of the probabilistic allocation of a large coupon. Prize-linked accounts exist in many countries. Two of the most prominent examples are the UK s Premium Bonds and South Africa s First National Bank s (FNB) A-Million-a-Month Account (MaMA). Anecdotal evidence on take-up and savings through prize-linked products is compelling (De Neve et al., 2008; D2D, 2012). However, due to a lack of evidence about their effects on savings, the unambiguous promotion of these products as a policy tool is somewhat difficult. Against this background, I will argue in the following that prize-linked accounts should be introduced in combination with further research as a potentially powerful tool to increase savings. The paper proceeds as follows. After a short overview of prize-linked savings products, I will consider theoretical motivations and review anecdotal empirical evidence. I then go on to discuss the potential effects of introducing prize-linked products on welfare and propose policy recommendations in the form of further research options and changes in the regulatory environment, followed by some concluding remarks. PRIZE-LINKED SAVINGS PRODUCTS: AN OVERVIEW Prize-linked savings accounts introduce a lottery element to savings, as they distribute the pooled interest of all account holders through a raffle, offering a probabilistic return on the money deposited in the account. Prize money is awarded from a prize fund, which may either be determined by the issuer ex-ante or be determined as a function of the amount and volume of deposits made in the period prior to each draw. As such, holding money in a prize-linked account can be thought of as buying a lottery ticket (Guryan et al., 2010). However, the product is different from a lottery ticket by the fact that depositors keep their principal, or deposits. Their 132

deposit is returned to them either at maturity of the product or on demand, which incurs a penalty. Thus, the price of the lottery ticket is not lost. The prize structure of PLS accounts can vary. Interest may be allocated either entirely through the raffle or partly through a lottery element and the pay out of a regular interest (Pfiffelmann and Roger, 2005). Furthermore, as part of the prize structure, the odds of winning, the amount and nature of prizes, and the frequency of prize draws are each determined individually, defining each product s expected return. Finally, prize-linked accounts often have minimum deposit requirements in terms of the money that has to be held, as well as the length that deposits have to be held for in order to qualify for entering the prize draw. Table I outlines the features of the UK Premium Bond as an example of a longstanding prize-linked savings product. Table 1. The UK premium bond as an example of PLS accounts National Savings and Investments (NS&I) Premium Bond 21.5 mn * Issuing institution National Savings and Investments (NS&I) Type of issuing institution Executive agency of the Chancellor of the Exchequer Year in which the product 1956 started Number of premium bond holders Total outstanding balances * 47 bn Minimum holdings 100 Maximum holdings 30,000 Frequency of draws Monthly Maximum prize 1,000,000 Odds per 1 unit 1/26,000 Prize allocation mechanism Electronic Random Number Indicator Equipment ERNIE Determination of prize fund One month s interest on the value of all deposits set by the Treasury Annual prize fund interest 1.30% rate Tax information Tax-free 34 * This is based on the NS&I s official website accessed in March 2014. Data marked with an asterisk stems from the NS&I website and an article published by The Telegraph: http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/personalfinance/ savings/10281655/premium-bond-millionaire-beats-oddswith-2000-punt.html [accessed 25/03/2014]. Historically, prize-linked savings have existed at least since the 1694 government-issued UK bond, The Million Adventure (Guryan et al., 2010). Currently, they continue to be issued by governments, mostly in the form of bonds in countries such as the UK and Sweden. In some countries (particularly in Latin America), private providers, such as commercial banks, issue account-based PLS products that sometimes pay out commodity 34 The discussion of tax reductions as a secondary feature of some PLS accounts has been excluded from the analysis. 133

prizes (Guillen and Tschoegl, 2002). 35 A PLS account provided by a microfinance institution can be found in Indonesia (Murdoch, 1999), and several U.S. states have recently seen experiments with prize-linked savings options offered by credit unions (D2D, 2012; Tufano, 2008). 36 Finally, several commercial banks across Africa offer prize-linked accounts as temporary savings promotions (Kanz, 2013; First Bank of Nigeria 2014). Table II provides an overview of different types of prize-linked accounts and their respective issuers with examples from different countries. Table 2. Example of different forms of prize-linked savings products Type of product Examples Product Prizes Institution Type of Issuer Savings bond United Premium Bonds Cash National Savings Government Kingdom and Investments agency (NS&I) Sweden Lottery Bonds Cash National Debt Office Government Savings account South Africa A-Million-a-Month Account (MaMA) Cash First National Bank Commercial bank Brazil HiperFundo Account Consumer goods Banco Bradesco Commercial bank Indonesia BritAma Account Cash Bank Rakyat Indonesia Microfinance institution Certificate deposit of United States Save to Win Cash Various credit unions in some states Credit union Promotional raffle Nigeria Save and Excel Cash/Consumer goods First Bank of Nigeria Commercial bank Sources: Guillen and Tschoegl 2002; Guryan et al., 200, and individual research conducted by the author. The MaMA account was introduced in 2005 and continued to exist until March 2008 when it was legally banned. 35 Kanz (2013) has argued that the great popularity of prize-linked savings in Latin America may stem from the high inflation rates which make regular savings products unattractive, having led commercial banks to devise prize-linked savings products as an alternative means to raise deposits. 36 This is due to legal obstacles faced by prize-linked accounts, which are discussed later on in the article. 134

C URRENT RESEARCH ON LOTTERY ELEMENTS IN SAVINGS Theoretical motivation: behavioural insights The Public Sphere 2015 Based on the widespread existence of prize-linked accounts (see also Guillen and Tschoegl, 2002) and Guryan et al. (2010) for a list of all PLS products in different countries), in the following I consider theoretical motivations for prize-linked accounts. Subsequently, I review empirical insights into anecdotal evidence on the potential effectiveness of prize-linked savings in encouraging saving. The return on a prize-linked savings account is random in contrast to the fixed interest received on a regular savings account. An individual s utility derived from holding a prize-linked account would conventionally be determined using expected utility theory, which models decision-making under risk and uncertainty. The model assigns each individual a utility function characterising the individual s risk attitudes. The utility function is often assumed to be concave, indicating risk aversion (Pfiffelmann, 2007). Empirically, a number of observed behaviours regarding risk-seeking and risk-aversion, and consequently attitudes towards insurance and gambling in the same individual, have been left unexplained by the theory. Similarly, the prevalence of prizelinked savings products is inconsistent with, and cannot be explained by, rational agent modelling. Even when the expected value of winning of a prize-linked account is set equal to the interest rate an individual would otherwise receive on a regular savings account, the typical risk-averse individual would always prefer the fixed interest over the stochastic return (Pfiffelmann, 2007). Lottery elements in savings can be explained using elements of behavioural economics, and in particular through modelling decision-making under uncertainty using Kahneman and Tversky s (1979; 1992) cumulative prospect theory. In the model presented in Figure I 37, the individual has an evaluation function of an uncertain prospect as defined by gains and losses with respect to a reference point that is framed by the individual, often corresponding to the final asset position an individual expects to reach or the status quo. The value function is concave for gains and convex for losses, which means that individuals are risk-seeking when faced with a choice between a sure loss and the probability of a larger loss and risk-averse for gains. As such, the value function incorporates individuals preferences that may, in some instances, favour gambles over sure outcomes, as observed also with regards to prize-linked savings products. The parameters α and β of the value function indicate that the marginal utility of gains and losses is decreasing, while λ is the degree of loss aversion (Köbberling and Wakker, 2005). It makes the value function steeper for losses than for gains, pointing to losses looming larger than the utility derived from corresponding gains. 37 The presentation of the model follows Pfiffelmann and Roger (2005) with empirically estimated parameter values by Kahneman and Tversky (1992). In presenting the theory in this very concise fashion, I do not claim to be comprehensive. I merely display the theory s main cornerstones that are necessary for understanding how theory may predict an appeal of prize-linked savings to individuals subject to the biases presented by it. 135

The Public Sphere 2015 Figure 1. Decision utility in cumulative prospect theory A general value function translated into subjective probabilities We consider a prospect X defined as follows: = = = (, =, ) with < <. < = 0 < < <. < and an evaluation function defined as = + where = "#(; 0) and = "#(; 0) where = (, ) and = (, ) are weighting functions, such that = ( ) and = ( ) = +... + +... + = +... + +... + with 0 1 and 0 If is the cumulative distribution function of, then ( ) and ( ) are applied to the decumulative and cumulative distribution function of respectively: ( ) ( ) = (1 ) = ( ) Graphical representation of the value and weighting functions =, > 0 ( ), <0 where 0 < < 1 and 0 < < 1 Proposed functional forms of the value and weighting functions* 136 [ + 1 ]/ = [ + 1 ]/ =

=, > 0 ( ), < 0 where 0 < < 1 and 0 < < 1 The Public Sphere 2015 = [ + 1 ] / = [ + 1 ] / Empirically estimated parameters for the value and weighting functions * = = 0.88 λ = 2.25 = 0.61 = 0.69 While in expected utility theory the utility of an uncertain prospect is determined by the sum of the utilities of the outcomes weighted by their respective probability, Figure I shows how the S-shaped value function in cumulative prospect theory is matched by an inverse S-shaped cumulative weighting function. It translates objective probabilities into subjective probabilities, a key process in understanding prize-linked accounts. As part of the subjective weighting function, individuals overweigh extremely low as well as extremely high probabilities and display greater sensitivity to changes in these as opposed to medium probabilities. A skewed probabilistic prize structure, as found with many prize-linked savings products and conventional lotteries, therefore enhances the decision utility (as inferred from observed choices) of individuals who are subject to the biases incorporated in the theory. According to its predictions, an individual will take up a prize-linked product if the evaluation function and thus the decision utility are positive. 38 In this case, the experienced utility of the prize-linked product is still lower compared to that derived from a product with a certain return equivalent to the expected return of the PLS product. In Table III I calculate the decision utility an individual derives from UK premium bonds under the assumptions made and with the estimated parameters outlined in Figure I as an illustration of the product s appeal. 39 I use prize structure parameters published by the NS&I for March 2014 40 with a p.a. interest rate of 1.30 per cent (or a pm interest rate of 0.11 per cent). The calculations confirm that the prize structure which is set such that = 1.0011 yields a positive decision utility of investing a 1 unit of = 0.13. () represents 38 The decision utility an individual derives from prize-linked savings is used interchangeably with V(X). 39 The specific functional form and parameter values of the value and weighting functions are subject to debate (see, for example, Atalay et al., 2012). Therefore, I perform a sensitivity analysis with different parameter values and find that the evaluation function remains positive using a range of values. However, in my illustrative application of the theory to PLS products I do not claim to state which specific functional form best matches empirical behaviour. 40 These are modelled on calculations done by Pfiffelman and Roger (2005) for February 2006. The interest rate and odds were taken from the official NS&I website (http://www.nsandi.com/savings-premium-bonds, accessed on 25/03/2014), whereas the revised prize structure, valid since August 2013, was informed by http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-23418034 (accessed 25/03/2014). Average prizes as estimated by the NS&I were used to avoid complication by the pari-mutual determination of prize funds. 137

the final wealth level reached with a regular interest received of 1.30 per cent p.a. and is set as the reference point when calculating losses and gains. 41 Table 3. Utility derived from a UK premium bond Prize in Amount of prizes Prize value Probability 0 - - 0.99996153 846 25 1,724,0 14 43,100,3 50 0.00003786 746 50 11,891 594,550 0.00000026 118 100 11,891 1,189,10 0.00000026 0 118 500 2,367 1,183,50 0.00000005 0 199 1,000 789 789,000 0.00000001 733 5,000 58 290,000 0.00000000 127 10,000 30 300,000 0.00000000 066 25,000 11 275,000 0.00000000 024 50,000 6 300,000 0.00000000 013 100,000 3 300,000 0.00000000 007 1,000,0 1 1,000,00 0.00000000 00 0 002 1,751,0 61 49,321,5 00 Final wealth Net final wealth * () () () - 0.005523 48 1 0-0.01 0.998710 68 26 25 16.99 0.001861 22 51 50 31.27 0.000047 37 101 100 57.54 0.000067 98 501 500 237.19 0.000023 89 1,001 1,000 436.52 0.000014 44 5,001 5,000 1,799.26 0.000002 04 10,001 10,000 3,311.31 0.000001 45 25,001 25,000 7,416.30 0.000000 73 50,001 50,000 13,648.7 0.000000 7 55 100,001 100,000 25,118.8 0.000000 6 42 1,000,0 1,000,0 190,546. 0.000000 01 00 07 32 0.031620 51 0.001481 22 0.003911 84 0.005666 95 0.006302 46 0.003677 15 0.004799 82 0.005448 93 0.007501 96 0.010522 75 0.060041 60 1 V(X)= 0.135451 71 The calculations in this table exactly follow the model of deriving decision utility as outlined in Figure 1. Net final wealth equals final wealth net of the reference point. 41 The reference point is crucial for the evaluation function and there has been some debate as to where it should be set. In the calculations for Table III I follow Pfiffelman and Roger (2005) for comparability of results. 138

The Public Sphere 2015 Empirical insights: the popularity of lottery elements in savings products To date, there is no systematic empirical evidence on the effect of prize-linked accounts on total savings of individuals, which is crucial in determining the validity and effectiveness of introducing prize-linked savings products as a policy tool. 42 Authors have only presented indirect evidence with the main focus on potential demand for prize-linked accounts (Guryan et al., 2010). One particular element of the product, the skewness in the prize structure and its empirically observed effect on uptake rates, however, has persistently been emphasised, providing indicative evidence for the biases explored previously. Tufano (2008) finds that the size of the maximum prize for UK Premium Bonds has a strong positive impact on per capita net sales. Rayner (1969) similarly finds a positive effect of a rise in the size of the largest prize in the 1960s on sales. Finally, Hölzl and Lobe (2007) in a time series analysis using monthly net sales of premium bonds between 1969-2006 show that prize skewness is a key drivers of net sales. As part of the indirect empirical evidence provided by the literature in support of the potential demand for prizelinked products, especially among low-income households, PLS products due to their lottery elements have been predicted to mirror empirically observed behaviour towards gambling (Guryan et al., 2010). Gambling has been shown to enjoy popularity across different subpopulations irrespective of sex, race or education and income levels, though lower-income households spend a higher fraction of their income on gambling (Kearney, 2002). Lotteries have further been characterised as one of the few assets that offer lower-income households the chance to make an extremely high return, otherwise unavailable due to their economic and social standing (Guryan et al., 2010; Haisley et al., 2008). A similar appeal of a product where returns are determined by chance has been attributed to prize-linked savings products (Guryan et al., 2010). Support for the argument that lottery elements may encourage lower-income households to save has further been derived from empirical observations related to UK premium bonds (Tufano, 2008; Guryan et al., 2010). The UK Family Resources Survey lists premium bonds as one of the assets owned by households. Based on the survey, Guryan et al. (2010) determine the popularity of premium bonds relative to other assets in different income brackets. This is done by scaling the prevalence of premium bonds among households in different income groups (measured as the fraction of households who own them) by the prevalence of the most widely held asset in that income bracket. This is shown in Figure II, which suggests that relative prevalence is highest among those households that are below the UK median annual income, speaking to the potential popularity of lottery elements in savings among low-income households. 43 42 The Washington-based not-for-profit organisation Doorways to Dreams (D2D) Fund currently runs several prize-linked products with credit unions in the US, aiming to derive systematic evidence, but results are not yet available. 43 The UK Department of Work and Pensions uses 60 per cent of median income as an indicator of relative low income. 139

Figure 2. UK premium bond ownership by weekly household income The Public Sphere 2015 Source: Guryan et al. (2010),,UK Family Resources Survey, reproduced by the author for 2011-2012. Finally, demand for prize-linked accounts has been gauged through surveys. Data from the 2009 Michigan Save to Win initiative, offering prize-linked products through credit unions, finds that 56 per cent of participants reported not to have saved money regularly before the initiative, 39 per cent reported financial assets (excluding home equity) of $5,000 or less, 59 per cent reported lottery spending in the last half year and 68 per cent reported household income of <$60,000 (Guryan et al., 2010). Similarly, in a 2006 survey among Wal-Mart customers in Indiana, De Neve et al. (2008) find that 58 per cent of respondents reported an interest in PLS accounts, of which 61 per cent non-savers. Among survey participants that reported spending >$100 on gambling in the last half year, 75 per cent reported an interest as opposed to 56 per cent among participants with lower lottery expenditures, providing some indication that gambling and prize-linked savings preferences may converge. However, the data cited is neither random nor representative, and due to the hypothetical nature of the question posed to participants and commonly observed tendencies to overstate the wish to save more, the information provided cannot be used as evidence for the demand for PLS accounts. PRIZE-LINKED SAVINGS PRODUCTS: AN EFFECTIVE SAVINGS POLICY TOOL? Potential effects of introducing prize-linked savings on welfare Given the current lack of empirical evidence, I will assess, in the following, the effectiveness of prize-linked savings as a policy tool by discussing potential effects that may be incurred to welfare by introducing prizelinked savings options. This is based on insights into the responsiveness of gambling, saving and consumption behaviour to introducing lottery elements to savings provided by two experiments, data on First National Bank s MaMA account, briefly in existence in South Africa, as well as the evaluation of a savings promotion in Nigeria (Kanz, 2013). The preliminary investigation into the effects of PLS accounts is coupled with policy recommendations which address research options to establish the causal effect of prize-linked accounts on total savings as well as regulatory concerns. 140

Evaluating the effects of different savings policies on welfare has proven extremely difficult and similar problems arise with regards to introducing prize-linked accounts as a savings policy (recent evaluations include Choi et al., 2001; Duflo et al., 2005 and Chetty et al., 2012). 44 This is because determining the effect savings policies have on total savings levels is complicated by crowding out effects of existing savings. Also called the inframarginal response, this effect happens when a new policy rewards existing savers by offering a beneficial alternative savings instrument to which those who are saving already will reallocate their savings (Gruber, 2007). It is therefore important to determine the size of the marginal response, i.e. the extent to which new savings are created by those who previously did not save, in order to assess a savings policy. With regards to prize-linked savings accounts the consumer s decision problem encompasses an allocation of income shares,, and to current consumption (C), regular savings (S), lottery spending (L) and saving through prize-linked accounts (P) such that +++=1 (Atalay et al., 2012). In order to attribute positive welfare effects to PLS accounts, we would like to be responsive to the introduction to PLS accounts, whilst at the same time increasing or keeping S constant and reducing or. This means that we would like funds deposited in prize-linked products to be sourced from consumption or gambling rather than regular savings, the net benefit of which in welfare terms would be negative if we take into account the decrease in experienced utility by saving with an uncertain interest. In addition, we would like the sum of and to be greater than in a world without prize-linked accounts, assessing the extent to which prize-linked products increase total savings. In one of two experiments exploring the effects of offering lottery-linked savings products, Filiz-Özbay et al. (2013) find that among 96 students at the University of Maryland taking part in a laboratory experiment, total savings increase by 4 per cent in the presence of a prize-linked savings option over and above the amount saved through a regular savings option. Similarly, an impact evaluation of Nigerian bank Intercontinental s savings promotion, I Save I Win (Kanz, 2013), finds a 3 percentage point increase in savings balances compared to balances at a bank without the promotion in the short-run; however, it eventually decreases to zero. Atalay et al. (2012), in an online experiment, find an increase in total savings by introducing a lotterysavings option of 25.4 per cent. This result may hold limited external validity due to the experimental setting and is less comparable to the previous results. Overall, offering savings products with a lottery element may, however, increase total savings as suggested by all three studies. Atalay et al. (2012) also look at the portfolio allocation of experiment participants. They find that, with the introduction of PLS accounts, allocation to traditional savings decreases by 9 per cent, whereas lottery and current consumption allocations decrease by approximately 23 per cent. This suggests that some interestbearing savings may be replaced by savings with an uncertain return, a cost that counters some of the benefits of increasing total savings. Both the online and the laboratory experiment reviewed, however, find the likelihood of saving through prize-linked products to be higher among non-savers, pointing to potentially less of a substitution effect by targeting non-savers. Nevertheless, the savings and investment values of PLS accounts 44 The theoretical debate on how to conduct behavioural public economics further complicates the attempt to determine welfare gains to be made from behavioural policy tools (Bernheim and Rangel 2005; 2009). The analysis of PLS accounts in this section is deliberately kept simple and constitutes a thought experiment that is meant to disentangle some of the constituents of a net welfare effect incurred through the introduction of prize-linked savings. 141

remain ambiguous (Tufano and Schneider, 2008), which means that some costs to employing lottery elements in savings policies through crowding out other savings can plausibly be assumed to be incurred. There is no evidence on the substitution effect between gambling and saving through prize-linked accounts, other than the experimental insights provided by Atalay et al. (2012). However, most experiments and preliminary demand analyses find that lottery players are more likely to take up PLS accounts than non-lottery players (Atalay et al., 2012; Filiz-Özbay et al., 2013; De Neve et al., 2008; D2D, 2012). While a reduction in gambling in favour of an increase in saving is certainly desirable, costs that counter those benefits may be incurred as lottery revenues decrease, which are a source of government revenue, thus potentially reducing total savings in the economy by decreasing national savings. In sum, existing preliminary empirical insights are indicative of net positive effects of prize-linked savings by an increase in total savings net of negative effects due to potential decreases in regular savings through substitution effects and a reduction in lottery revenues. A significant further benefit may arise through positive externalities. Based on the Nigerian I Save I Win product, Kanz (2013) argues that offering prizes on savings may enhance formal banking interaction and financial capability, i.e. the use of formal financial services in ways which are welfare-enhancing, through increased experience in dealing with formal financial service institutions. He finds that the frequency of transactions by PLS-account holders increases by 1.5 per cent and their use of financial products by 5 per cent a year after the promotional savings raffle. Furthermore, holders of the South African MaMA account were found to be to a significant extent unbanked. 45 Given both the potential for welfare enhancement provided by net increased savings and the externalities discussed, prize-linked products seem worth exploring further especially since, if offered by banks, they are self-financed as opposed to other more costly savings policies. Increasing the evidence base: further research into the causal effects of prize-linked savings Overall, the net welfare effects of introducing prize-linked products may be positive. However, it seems necessary to establish a more profound evidence base on the effects of PLS accounts before univocally promoting them as a policy tool. This is especially true since responses to behavioural designs are often heterogeneous, as evident in the preliminary demand analysis and highlighted by many authors for other behavioural designs (Ashraf et al., 2006; Gruber, 2007). Investigating the causal effects of prize-linked savings lends itself to a randomised field experiment in partnership with an issuing institution that would offer prizelinked accounts to a part of its customer base. Four major advantages of such a research design for studying the effect of introducing PLS products will be outlined. Firstly, the field experiment design could borrow from the well-established literature on commitment savings products, such as Ashraf et al. s (2006) study on the effect of the SEED account. Similar to this study, an investigation into the savings behaviour of individuals faced with prize-linked savings options seeks to establish the intention to treat (ITT) effect, i.e. the effect on individuals savings behaviour when offered the option to receive a prize on savings as opposed to a regular interest in order to determine both take-up and subsequent savings. In a randomised experiment, savings balances of those in a treatment group being offered the product 45 This was established using data on how many customers were exempt from Know Your Customer regulation, as specified by Exception 17 of the 2001 Financial Intelligence Centre Act (FICA). 142

could be compared to balances of those in different control groups who are either informed about savings more generally or do not receive any treatment at all (Ashraf et al., 2006), allowing us to evaluate the effects of PLS accounts on savings against a valid counterfactual. Secondly, identifying the particular behavioural design features to be tested usually a cumbersome process in behavioural policy design (Datta and Mullainathan, 2012) is facilitated for the study of prize-linked savings products by previous studies of the effects of different behavioural features of the lottery. The hypotheses derived from these studies are summarised in Table 4. Table 4. Testing the effects of different design features Hypotheses derived from the literature on gambling Identity salience 46 Haisley et al., 2008; Le Boeuf and Shafir, 2004 Subjective probability weighting Rayner, 1969; Tufano, 2008; Pfiffelmann and Roger, 2005 Availability heuristics 47 Tversky and Kahneman 1974; Kearney, 2002 translated into product design features to be tested in a field experiment. Advertise that everyone can be a winner to play on relative poverty perceptions Make the prize structure extremely skewed, as big prizes are attractive at a low probability Announce the winner regularly, to play on the subjective perception of the frequency of prizes awarded being determined by the recollection of available instances. Illusion of control 48 Clotfelter and Cook, 1989; Langer, 1975; 1978 Allow participants to pick numbers to suggest that the chance event of a prize can be influenced by skill. Thirdly, conducting a baseline survey as part of a field experiment can help elicit the particular behavioural biases to which individuals are subject, thereby testing the hypotheses derived by the theory. This offers empirical insights that could further develop the specific parameterisation of the value and weighting functions of the model. Similarly, it would help to define the target group better. Surveying individuals gambling and 46 This describes a process whereby individuals preferences change with a particular identity being salient in a certain context (LeBoeuf, Shafir 2004) which can also influence gambling preferences (Haisley, Mostafa, Loewenstein 2008). 47 This describes a cognitive bias whereby individuals think about abstract probabilities in terms of the ease with which past instances of the event s occurrence can be brought to mind (Kahneman, Tversky 1974). Accordingly, frequent prize draws can lead individuals to overestimate the probability of winning when faced with a gamble. 48 Lottery players tend to think of skill as an element in gambling (Clotfelter, Cook 1989). This is due to a tendency to deny the operation of chance even in situations that are entirely chance-determined. This illusion of control is heightened when individuals are encouraged to make active choices and encourages risk-taking (Langer 1975; 1978). 143

consumption behaviour as well as observing their savings balances in regular savings accounts could also establish the magnitude of potential substitution effects. Finally, it may be relatively easy to find a partnering bank through which to offer the product as part of a field experiment since banks themselves display an interest in developing innovative means to raise deposits. The South African environment, in which the government incentivised commercial banks to enhance banking relations among the unbanked, was a significant factor in the exploration of prize-linked accounts by First National Bank before the decision to launch MaMA, and the product may therefore similarly spark interest among other banks (Cole et al., 2008). While a randomised field experiment would allow us to investigate the nature of changes in total savings, substitution effects, and externalities of prize-linked savings, some uncertainties would persist beyond the randomised design. As such, this type of experiment does not resolve the question of how long-term the effect on savings will be. The savings effect incurred by the prize element may either wear off as observed with other behavioural effects studied previously. Furthermore, in a repeated context consumers may eventually adjust their probability weighting to remove the bias from their decision making. However, this does not seem to be suggested by continued expenditures on gambling (Filiz-Özbay et al., 2013). Revising the regulatory environment: dealing with legal concerns and political opposition In addition to devoting further research to establishing the causal effects of prize-linked savings, several regulatory concerns need to be addressed before introducing the product. Firstly, if offered by private financial institutions, PLS accounts must be subject to banking regulation in order to prevent private profit-making institutions from exploiting the biases outlined as integral to the appeal of prize-linked products. Pfiffelmann (2007) shows that minimising the issuer s cost, subject to the individuals participation constraint in the form of a positive evaluation function, may yield an optimal expected interest rate below that offered currently in the form of fixed interest by banks. 49 Therefore, appropriate regulatory oversight of the product must prohibit such outcomes for the consumer (Tufano, 2008). In the UK, for example, interest rates set for the determination of the prize fund as well as the odds of winning for Premium Bonds are regularly published online by the NS&I in order to ensure that conditions are transparent and fair. The second regulatory concern is related to national lottery regulation. PLS products can essentially be characterised as private games of chance, and have come under scrutiny by lottery and gambling regulators (Addison and Chowdhury, 2003). Most national lottery laws prohibit private lotteries from operating and confer the legal rights to offering gambles to a single, often government-appointed, agency. As such, lottery laws conventionally define three main components of what constitutes a lottery: offering a prize, the allocation of that prize by chance and consideration, or the advancement of money or value in exchange for the opportunity to win a prize (Guryan et al., 2010). They allow lottery operators to maintain a monopoly over gambling activities and constrain access to the funds raised by revenues from selling lottery tickets for administrative and government use. This is typically grounded in the argument that the lottery extorts money from low-income individuals and as such revenues from gambling should be earmarked for good purposes. However, it has also 49 This is due to the range of possible manipulations of the prize structure, which influences the evaluation function. 144

been argued widely that the lottery essentially constitutes a regressive tax (Wyett, 1991). Given the limited allocation of revenues for programmes that provide most benefit to the typical lottery player, their accountability is questionable. Box 1. Firstrand Bank v. National Lotteries Board, (385/07) [2008] ZASCA 29 (28 March 2008) In a judgment by the South African Supreme Court of Appeal (ZASCA) on the case between Firstrand Bank Limited and the National Lotteries Board, it was decided on 28 March 2008 that the MaMA account was violating the South African Lotteries Act 57 of 1997. The Lotteries Act of 1997 establishes the National Lottery Board s monopoly on collecting money from the general public through games of chance, with its net income being earmarked for worthy causes. Except for minor lotteries or commercial lotteries permitted as promotional competitions, no private games of chance are allowed outside of the National Lottery. A lottery for the purposes of the Lotteries Act is understood as any game, scheme, arrangement, system, plan, promotional competition or device for distributing prizes by a lot or chance. The key to determining an unlawful lottery is a subscription, i.e. the payment or delivery of any money, goods, article, matter or thing, including any ticket, coupon, or entry form, for the right to compete in a lottery. The dispute in the case of the MaMA account was concerned with the payment of money as understood by the Lotteries Act as opposed to Firstrand Bank and thus with whether or not the account included a subscription qualifying it under the Lotteries Act as an unlawful lottery. Firstrand argued that the money deposited in the MaMA account did not constitute a payment because it was returned in full at maturity. However, the court refuted this argument, stating that with deposits made as part of the MaMA account, the right to the money deposited was staked by account holders as the possession of the money was temporarily lost by the depositor and acquired by bank. The stake in return for being considered for the allocation of a prize qualified the account as a lottery. Introducing prize-linked accounts would have to rely on revising the uncertain legal environment in which the issuers of prize-linked savings products currently operate in most countries. The extent to which this affects the supply of prize-linked savings products becomes evident when looking at the case of the South African MaMA account. The product was initially developed by the issuing bank in consultation with the National Lottery Board which qualified the account as a promotional competition, i.e. a private lottery conducted for the purpose of promoting the sale or use of any goods or services, permitted by the South African National Lotteries Act of 1997 (Freakonomics, 2010a; 2010b). Similarly, savings promotions offered by several banks in Nigeria currently operate under this legal definition. However, after the account came into existence in 2005 50 and subsequently became very successful, attracting an estimated 900,000 customers with R1.4bn worth of 50 MaMA was a 32-day notice account with a minimum balance of R100 and 14 monthly prizes ranging from R1,000 to R1,000,000. 145

accounts (or on average R1,600 per account), the National Lottery Board brought the bank to trial on the grounds of a violation of the National Lotteries Act as a result of which the product was banned in March 2008. Information Box I outlines the case and final decision in more detail. The South African case illustrates that introducing prize-linked savings requires a firm stance towards opposition to a weakening of current monopoly structures on the part of lottery operators. Given the potential benefits of prize-linked accounts on savings amongst lower-income households currently disadvantaged by the distributional impacts of lotteries, legislating for gambling that benefits savings can strongly be advocated for as a viable policy alternative. Finally, support for such proposals could further be strengthened by an increased evidence base established through research, which would dispel doubts about the effectiveness of prize-linked savings in positively influencing savings rates. C ONCLUSION In conclusion, based on the discussion of prize-linked savings in this article, introducing lottery elements to savings seems to represent a promising policy tool to encourage savings, in particular among low-income households. If offered through private institutions, prize-linked savings accounts offer a cost-efficient way to promote savings and may generate substantial benefits incurred through an increase in total savings as well as potential externalities arising from enhanced financial capability among those not previously engaged in formal financial services. In order to exploit these benefits, we should strengthen the evidence base on prize-linked savings by establishing robust causal effects of offering PLS products through a randomised field experiment. Such research should also further enable policy makers to address legal and regulatory concerns regarding prize-linked products and their relationship to gambling, as well as face political opposition that may arise in view of policy implementation. R EFERENCES Addison, T. and Chowdhury, A. R. (2003), A global lottery and a global premium bond, WIDER Discussion Papers, World Institute for Development Economics (UNUWIDER), 2003/80. Ashraf, N., Karlan, D. and Yin, W. (2006), Tying Odysseus to the mast: Evidence from a commitment savings product in the Philippines, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2): 635-672, May. Atalay, K., Bakhtiar, F., Cheung, S. and Slonim, R. (2012), Savings and Prize-Linked Savings Accounts, Institute for the Study of Labour (IZA) Discussion Paper 6927, October. BBC, Date, Article Title http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-23418034 [accessed 25/03/2014.] Benartzi, S. and Thaler, R. H. (2004), Save More Tomorrow: Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee Saving, Journal of Political Economy, 112(1): S164-S187, February. Berrnheim, B. D. and Rangel, A. (2005), Behaviour public economics: Welfare and policy-analysis with nonstandard decision makers, NBER Working Paper 11518, July. Bernheim, B. D. and Rangel, A. (2009), Beyond Revealed Preference: Choice-theoretic Foundations for Behavioural Welfare Economics, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(1): 51-104. 146

Chetty, R., Friedman, J. N., Leth-Petersen, S., Nielsen, T. H. and Olsen, R. (2012), Active vs. passive decisions and crowd-out in retirement savings accounts: Evidence from Denmark, NBER Working Paper 18565, November. Choi, J., Laibson, D., Madrian B. and Metrick, A. (2001), For Better or For Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Savings Behaviour, NBER Working Paper 8651, December. Clotfelter, C. T. and Cook, P. J. (1989), On the Economics of State Lotteries, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(4): 105-119, Fall. Cole, S., Collins, D., Schneider, D. and Tufano, P. (2008), First National Bank s Golden Opportunity, Harvard Business School Review, March 13. Datta, S. and Mullainathan, S. (2012), Behavioural Design. A New Approach to Development Policy, CGD Policy Paper 016, November. Doorways to Dreams Fund (2012), Playing the savings game: A prize-linked savings report, http://www.d2dfund.org/files/publications/playingtsg_report_2012_singlepgs.pdf [accessed 10/12/2013]. Doorways to Dreams Fund (2013), A winning proposition : Creating economic opportunities through the state lottery, http://www.d2dfund.org/files/publications/d2d_lottery_whitepaper_revision.pdf [accessed 10/12/2013]. De Neve, J.-E., Maynard, N. Tufano, P. (2008), Prize-linked Savings. A Preliminary Analysis. Working Paper 08-061. Duflo, E., Gale, W., Liebman, J., Orszag, P. and Saez, E. (2005), Saving incentives for low- and middle-income families: Evidence from a field experiment with H&R Block, NBER Working Paper 11680, October. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (2009), Minutes of the Meeting of the FDIC Advisory Committee on Economic Inclusion of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Washington, D.C., July 30. Family Resources Survey 2004-2005, available from the UK Department of Work and Pensions, https://www.gov.uk/government/collections/family-resources-survey--2 [accessed 01/12/2013]. Family Resources Survey 2005-2006, available from the UK Department of Work and Pensions, https://www.gov.uk/government/collections/family-resources-survey--2 [accessed 01/12/2013]. Family Resources Survey 2011-2012, available from the UK Department of Work and Pensions, https://www.gov.uk/government/collections/family-resources-survey--2 [accessed 01/12/2013]. Filiz-Özbay, E., Guryan, J., Hyndman, K., Kearney, M. and Ozbay E. (2013), Do Lottery Payments Induce Savings Behaviour? Evidence from the Lab, NBER Working Paper 19130, June. First National Bank Data (2014), collected in March 2014. Firstbank Nigeria Interview (2014), conducted in March 2014. Firstrand Bank v National Lotteries Board (385/07) [2008] ZASCA 29 (28 March 2008). Freakonomics (2010a), Is America ready for a No Lose Lottery?, Full Interview Transcript of Podcast, 18 November 2010, http://freakonomics.com/2010/11/18/is-america-ready-for-a-no-lose-lottery-full-transcript/ [accessed 25/03/2014]. Freakonomics (2010b), Who could say no to a No Lose Lottery?, Full Interview Transcript of Podcast, 2 December 2010, http://freakonomics.com/2010/12/02/freakonomics-radio-who-could-say-no-to-a-no-loselottery/ [accessed 25/03/2014]. 147

Gruber, J. (2007), Public Finance and Public Policy, Worth Publisher, 2 nd edition. The Public Sphere 2015 Guillen, M. F. and Tschoegl,A. E. (2002), Banking on Gambling: Banks and Lottery-Linked Deposit Accounts, Journal of Financial Services Research 21(3): 219-231. Guryan, J., Hurst, E., Kearney, M. and Tufano, P. (2010), Making Savers Winners: An Overview of Prize-Linked Savings Products, NBER Working Paper 16433, October 2010. Hölzl, A., Lobe, S. (2007), Why are British Premium Bonds So Successful? The Effect of Saving with a Thrill, SSRN 992794, Haisley, E., Mostafa, R. and Loewenstein, G. (2008), Subjective Relative Income and Lottery Ticket Purchases, Journal of Behavioural Decision Making, 21: 283-295. Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1974), Judgement under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, Science, New Series 185(4157): 1124-1131, September. Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1979), Prospect theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk, Econometrica, 47(2): 263-291, March. Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1992), Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5: 297-323. Kanz, M. (2013), Learning by Doing: Can Savings Lotteries Build Financial Capability?, Presentation held at the India-OECD-World Bank Regional Conference on Financial Education, March 4-5, New Delhi, India. Köbberling, V. and Wakker, P. (2005), An Index of Loss Aversion, Journal of Economic Theory, 122(1): 119-131. Kearney, M. (2002), State lotteries and consumer behaviour, NBER Working Paper 9330, November. Langer, E. (1975), The Illusion of Control, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 32(2): 311-328. Langer, E. (1978), The Psychology of Chance, Journal for the Theory of Social Behaviour, 7: 185-207. LeBoeuf, R. A. and Shafir, E. (2004), Alternating Selves and Conflicting Choices: Identity Salience and Preference Inconsistency, Working Paper, Department of Psychology, Princeton University. Morduch, J. (1999), Between the State and the Market: Can Informal Insurance Patch the Safety Net?, World Bank Research Observer 14(2): 187-207. National Savings and Investments (NS&I), Premium Bonds, http://www.nsandi.com/savings-premium-bonds [accessed 25/03/2014]. Pfiffelmann, M. and Roger, P., (2005), Les comptes d épargne associés à des loteries : approche comportementale et études de cas, Banque & Marché, 78, Septembre-Octobre. Pfiffelmann, M. (2007), Which optimal design for lottery linked deposit accounts?, CEB Working Paper 07/010. Rayner, A.C. (1969), Premium bonds The effect of the prize structure, Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Economics & Statistics, 21(4): 303-311, November. Schneider, D. and Tufano, P. (2005), Reinventing Savings Bonds, HBS Finance Working Paper 06-017, September Tufano, P. (2008), Saving whilst Gambling: An Empirical Analysis of UK Premium Bonds, AEA Session: Assets and Credit Among Low-Income Households, 1 September. 148